By Harriet Johnson Postgraduate, First Prize

Similar documents
BRIEFING. The Labour Market Effects of Immigration.

CBI s case for an open and controlled immigration system rests on weak arguments

Response to UCL paper on the fiscal effects of immigration to the UK

What are the impacts of an international migration quota? Third Prize 1 st Year Undergraduate Category JOSH MCINTYRE*

The Important Role of Migration for an Ageing Nation

SELECTION CRITERIA FOR IMMIGRANT WORKERS

By Richard M. Hui Second Year, Third Prize

Mobility of health professionals between the Philippines and selected EU member states: A Policy Dialogue

Brexit misperceptions

A Note on Dustmann and Frattini s Estimates of the Fiscal Impact of UK Immigration. Robert Rowthorn. Faculty of Economics, University of Cambridge

20 Bogus Arguments for Mass Immigration

Integrating migration on the agenda of the 21st Century 8 th Global Forum on Migration and Development 2015

Chapter 9. Labour Mobility. Introduction

Brexit: How should we vote? 2017 Manifesto Review

The fiscal impact of immigration to welfare states of the Scandinavian type

Discussion comments on Immigration: trends and macroeconomic implications

3 How might lower EU migration affect the UK economy after Brexit? 1

Should the UK leave the EU?

August 2010 Migration Statistics

European Integration Consortium. IAB, CMR, frdb, GEP, WIFO, wiiw. Labour mobility within the EU in the context of enlargement and the functioning

International Migration and Development: Proposed Work Program. Development Economics. World Bank

SUPPLY AND DEMAND IN THE SYRIAN LABOR MARKET

Labour Mobility Interregional Migration Theories Theoretical Models Competitive model International migration

REPORT. Highly Skilled Migration to the UK : Policy Changes, Financial Crises and a Possible Balloon Effect?

POPULATION STUDIES RESEARCH BRIEF ISSUE Number

IMMIGRATION AND THE UK S PRODUCTIVITY CHALLENGE

What Should a Cautious Immigration Policy Look Like?

The Pull Factors of Female Immigration

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY. Executive Summary

CER INSIGHT: The biggest Brexit boon for Germany? Migration. by Christian Odendahl and John Springford 11 December 2017

The UK and the European Union Insights from ICAEW Employment

SUARTS submission to the All-Parliamentary Group on Migration Inquiry into the closure of the Post Study Work route

From In partnership with. The Nationality of Workers in the UK's Digital Tech Industries

Committee on National Statistics Division of Behavioral and Social Sciences and Education WATER SCIENCE AND TECHNOLOGY BOARD

Immigration and The Economic Crisis: Does recession make a Difference?

Migration Advisory Committee Call for Evidence: EEA-workers in the UK labour market submission by the Sport and Recreation Alliance

The Outlook for Migration to the UK

The Impact of Immigration on Wages of Unskilled Workers

Poverty Profile. Executive Summary. Kingdom of Thailand

The outlook for EU migration if the UK remains subject to the free movement of people

Brexit and immigration: the way forward

Policy Coherence for Migration and Development

A COMPARISON OF ARIZONA TO NATIONS OF COMPARABLE SIZE

Likely consequences of the MAC s proposed immigration policy

Executive summary. Strong records of economic growth in the Asia-Pacific region have benefited many workers.

Chapter 10 Worker Mobility: Migration, Immigration, and Turnover

Does Immigration Reduce Wages?

The impacts of international migration on poverty in the UK

Tim Krieger: Fertility Rates and Skill Distribution in Razin and Sadka s Migration-Pension Model: A Note

June 2018 I NO: 18 13

Migration: Global challenges, European responses

Economic Impacts of Immigration. Testimony of Harry J. Holzer Visiting Fellow, Urban Institute Professor of Public Policy, Georgetown University

The International Platform on Health Worker Mobility

The Impact of Global Economic Crisis on Migrant Workers in Middle East

CONSULTATION RESPONSE

Royal Society submission to the Migration Advisory Committee s Call for Evidence on EEA workers in the UK labour market

Addressing the situation and aspirations of youth

Weekly Geopolitical Report

Fiscal Impact of EU Migrants in Austria, Germany, the Netherlands and the UK

Migration, Coordination Failures and EU Enlargement

Immigration and property prices: Evidence from England and Wales

Emigration and source countries; Brain drain and brain gain; Remittances.

The Analytics of the Wage Effect of Immigration. George J. Borjas Harvard University September 2009

Jens Thomsen: The global economy in the years ahead

Irish Emigration Patterns and Citizens Abroad

Chapter 8 Economic Integration, Labour Markets and Migration

Immigration - Why It Matters

COMMENTARY. The Variations Enigma: Regional Differences in Support for Reducing Immigration to the UK.

Hungary s Economic Performance Following EU Accession: Lessons for the new EU Members Bulgaria and Romania

Snp Immigration Policy A Back Door To England?

Response to the Department of Home Affairs consultation on Managing Australia's Migrant Intake

TOWARDS A EUROPEAN LABOUR MARKET: COMBATING LONG-TERM UNEMPLOYMENT AND IMPROVING TRADE UNIONS THROUGH INCREASED MIGRATION

IMMIGRATION AND THE LABOUR MARKET

ASSESSING THE IMPACT OF A8 IMMIGRANTS ON UK WAGES

3. Does the economy need immigration?

MIGRATION BETWEEN THE UK AND THE EU

The UK Labour Market EU Workers by Occupation Skill Level

Globalisation and Open Markets

UNISON Scotland consultation response. Westminster - Scottish Affairs Committee Does UK immigration policy meet Scotland s needs?

Labor Market Consequences of Immigration. Econ/Demog C175 Economic Demography Prof. Goldstein Spring 2018, UC Berkeley

Labor Market Challenges in Europe With Respect to the Migrant Crisis

ALMR response to the Migration Advisory Committee s call for evidence on EEA migration and future immigration policy

that Would Enhance the Well-being of New Zealanders

The labour market impact of immigration

The impacts of migrants and migration into Scotland PEOPLE, COMMUNITIES AND PLACES. social. research

Economics Of Migration

10/11/2017. Chapter 6. The graph shows that average hourly earnings for employees (and selfemployed people) doubled since 1960

Royal College of Paediatrics and Child Health response to the Migration Advisory Committee call for evidence: Review of Tier 2

Unemployment and the Immigration Surplus

Chapter 5. Labour Market Equilibrium. McGraw-Hill/Irwin Labor Economics, 4 th edition

Migration and Labor Market Outcomes in Sending and Southern Receiving Countries

Labour market crisis: changes and responses

Postwar Migration in Southern Europe,

Session 6: Economic Impact of Migration on Receiving Countries: Public Finance, Growth and Inequalities

Area of study 2: Dynamic Places

Immigration A nation divided?

DEGREE PLUS DO WE NEED MIGRATION?

TRENDS IN INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION

Economics Summer Term Task

Does Immigration Raise or Lower Taxes?

Transcription:

In a July article published in The Telegraph, David Cameron stated, "We're building an immigration system that puts Britain first." Are cries for a 'clamping down' on immigration justified? By Harriet Johnson Postgraduate, First Prize The UK and Immigration: Invaluable & Inexpensive Type the word immigration into Google and 231 million hits appear in less than half a second: it is one of the most widely and fervently discussed topics in British politics and society today. Are immigrants taking our jobs and sponging off our benefits as is so oft declared, or do they pay their way and help secure and create jobs in the British economy? According to the Office of National Statistics (2015) 624,000 people immigrated to the UK from September 2013-14, but at what cost, and what benefit? David Cameron, in the quoted speech, states that he intends to clamp down on abuses to the system, on making sure that the right people come for the right reasons and that the system puts British people first (Cameron, 2014). The author has interpreted these points as the issue of illegal immigration, the important of attracting skilled workers, and of ensuring that the immigration system does not bear a significant cost to the British people, respectively. This essay does not seek to assess the first issue of illegal immigration for reasons of brevity, assuming that clamping down on illegal immigration is largely justified, nor does this essay attempt to discuss the successes of the UK government in pursuing and policing its immigration policies. It shall, however, attempt to assess the economic reasoning behind having a tighter, or looser, immigration policy, i.e. is justified to clamp down on immigration? The essay proceeds as follows: section one assess the importance of immigration, as predicted by economic theory and how, in the UK, certain types of immigration are more crucial than others for ensuring long term economic growth and stability. For example, the recruiting of talented, geographically mobile workers is more important than that of low-skilled workers. Secondly, this essay shall explore the costs, or lack thereof, of immigration to the UK economy in recent years, both fiscal and to the labour market. Finally, the author concludes that while the tightening up of certain types of immigration is somewhat justified, largely immigration is invaluable and inexpensive for the UK. Is Immigration Invaluable for the UK? Economic theory suggests that immigration can be beneficial for an economy in a number of ways. In his speech, Cameron stresses the importance of the right kind of people, or workers, coming in for the right reasons, reflecting the fact that immigration can be extremely valuable to an economy if targeted correctly. This section does not attempt to discuss the reasons, right or wrong, that people have for coming to the UK,

but to analyse why it is important to have immigration, and which kind of immigrants are right. Firstly, theory suggests that given a supply of domestic labour, S, and demand for labour D, market equilibrium would fall at employment level N, with wages W2. The area under the demand curve, ABN0, is a measure of the national income of the economy. If a country s immigration policies are then relaxed, this increases the supply of workers to S and, assuming wages are not sticky and that all labour is homogenous, the wage then falls to W1, employment level to M, and national income increases to ACM0. CFMN represents wages paid to immigrants, but the triangle BCF is the immigration surplus that is paid to natives as a result of immigration. W2BFW1 is income lost to natives, which returns to employers since wages, and thus costs, are now lower (Borjas, 2013, p181) (See Figure 1). Figure 1: Immigration and the Labour market Wage!( )!! S! S! A! W 2! B! W1! F! C D! N! M!! Employment! Van den Berg expands on this simplified model, suggesting, the simple labour market model of immigration does not recognize that an increase in the quantity of labour employed can also increase income in the destination country, which increases aggregate demand, and hence demand for labour (Van den Berg, 2012, p507). In other words, the more people that are employed in an economy, the higher consumption will be, which will increase aggregate demand. This could, in turn, induce investment in businesses, driving them to hire more workers, which continues the cycle. Therefore, the long-run increase in aggregate demand and supply in the economy could be substantial, suggesting that immigration is important for growth and development of countries. Additionally, there could be benefits to the economy as a result of immigration if the additional workers and consumers cause industries to increase in size. This increase can lead to efficiency savings in industries in which immigrants are employed, due to economies of scale. Furthermore, immigration can increase the size of industries complementary to those directly affected by immigration, such as the use of public transport, housing markets, and education, because of the increase in population. This can be both positive, in terms of increasing employment and efficiency, but also

negative, increasing waiting times, congestion, or bidding up prices. There appears to be little quantifiable evidence in the literature discussing this, but it does seem clear that economic theory largely predicts immigration to be beneficial and important for an economy. This being said, it was assumed in the model that the supply of both native and nonnative workers was homogenous, in that they would both have the same level of skill and be competing for similar jobs, which drives the wage rate down. This is not representative as there are both skilled, and non-skilled natives and immigrants in a dynamic economy. Making a distinction between different kinds of immigrants is important for analysis because they can have very different impacts on the economy. Leading on from this idea, Oxford Economics (2012) estimated that in the next decade the UK would develop the 10 th most pronounced talent deficit in the developed and emerging world, where a talent deficit is the difference between the supply and demand of talented, skilled labour. In the same report, they highlighted that the projected Japanese talent deficit would become the 2 nd largest, after Taiwan, and attributed this to its economy being largely closed to immigration of large numbers of skilled managers and technicians (ibid, p202). This example underlines the importance of keeping the UK economy open and attractive to skilled and talented workers, or risk further worsening the talent deficit. Such a deficit is worrisome for the future as it limits the productive and growth capabilities of the economy. In this way, not only does economic theory suggest that immigration should induce growth in the economy, but there is evidence that the absence of it could actively obstruct growth. Moreover, it is not the influx of all immigrants that can alleviate the problem, but of skilled workers specifically. Alternatively, Rowthorn (2012), writing for Civitas, comments that immigration is important for rejuvenating the population of the UK. The benefit from this can manifest in different ways. Firstly, it can increase the productive work force of the country, filling any aforementioned talent deficits and helping the economy grow as theory suggests it will. Secondly, some have argued that immigration is valuable for the population demographic of the UK. For example, The Home Office (2007) comment that although little research has been done on the impact of immigration on the pension shortfall for the UK s rapidly ageing population, theoretical arguments suggest it could be beneficial. Thirdly, immigrants tend to be more mobile: willing to take jobs in, and relocate to, different cities (Rowthorn, 2012, p18). This would be helpful in order to shift industry, production and jobs elsewhere in the country. The Centre for Cities (2014) reported that London accounted for almost 80% of job growth in the private sector between 2010 and 2012. London sucks in talent nationwide, and thus arguably grows at the expense of other cities in the country. If mobile immigrants can help other cities grow, develop and prosper, this could be extremely beneficial to the future of the UK, helping to alleviate some of the north-south income inequality, and making the UK economy stronger, among other things. This being said, there is little qualitative data available to prove that this is the case, but common sense suggests that it is more than plausible. On the other hand, if immigrants are not geographically mobile and stay in London or

the South-East upon arrival, where booming industries are already established, this could place too much strain on the infrastructure and environment in those areas (Rowthorn, 2012, p67). This is troublesome because there is no way to distinguish between people who plan to stay in London, or those willing to move, so there is no way immigration policy can control for this. In this way, although economic theory suggests that immigration is valuable for an economy, it would seem that specific types are certainly more beneficial than others, namely that of highly-skilled, mobile workers. This section suggests that a clamping down of such workers seems hardly justifiable, as they play an important role in the growth, and future, of the UK economy. This section has not attempted to prove, beyond all reasonable doubt, that the clamping down of unskilled immigration is warranted, but it does highlight that it is arguably less important for the UK economy. 2. Is Immigration Inexpensive for the UK? There is much debate in the literature regarding the costs of immigration, both to the labour market, and the economy as a whole. David Cameron suggests that the UK s immigration policy should not cost the British public (Cameron, 2014). This is to say, that immigration should not occur at a cost to native employees, or taxpayers, regardless of its overall effect on the sum-total utility of the global economy. Firstly, the fiscal cost of immigration depends on the amount that people contribute to, and draw from, the government, which can be determined by several different things. The fiscal profile of an individual is largely determined by their age. Young people, in state education, are largely a draw on the state; working adults pay taxes into the state; and retirees take state pensions (Home Office, 2007). It is expected that, on average, people have a net fiscal impact of zero over their lifetime. Similarly, the OECD (2013) comments that immigrants age at arrival is an important factor in determining the net present value of their discounted future net direct fiscal contributions, as it determines how valuable, or costly, they are likely to be for the economy. Arguably, if an immigrant has not been educated in the UK, nor plans to retire here, their net fiscal contributions are likely to be higher than those of a native who resides in the country for all three stages of their fiscal lifecycle. Dustmann and Frattini (2014) also found that immigrants of comparable age, gender, education, and skill level were 21% less likely to claim any benefits that natives. Given this, is it highly questionable that immigrants are as the drain on the state that they are often vilified as being. This being said, there is much disagreement surrounding the total fiscal impact of immigration on the UK economy. For example, the OECD (2013) estimated that impact of immigrants is generally small, not exceeding plus or minus 0.5% of GDP; Dustmann and Frattini (2014) found that between 1995-2011, immigrants from the European Economic Area (EEA) made a positive fiscal contribution; the Home Office (2007) found that between 1999-2000, immigrants net fiscal benefit was 2.5bn; yet Migration Watch UK (2012) concluded that there have been no positive fiscal impacts from migrants in any year. Given the difficulty in assessing the outright fiscal cost of

immigration, it seems logical to attempt to break the problem down by assessing the costs attributing to different types of workers in the UK labour market. Unsurprisingly, the evidence here is similarly confusing and contradictory: Dustmann et al (2008) conclude that there is, at best, mixed evidence that immigration does not lead to negative employment effects for the destination county; the Migration Advisory Committee (2012) suggests that a one-off increase of 100 non-eu workers is associated with a reduction in native employment of 23 between 1995 and 2010; Ehrenberh and Smith suggest that some groups of workers will be clear winners, whereas some will be losers as a direct result of immigration (Ehrenberg and Smith, 2009, p344). Many authors suggest that the labour market costs of immigration depend on the skill set of migrants relative to those of natives, and the aggregate picture is not meaningful (Dustmann et al, 2008; MAC 2012). For the sake of simplicity, it is assumed that the wage rate is a suitable proxy for skill level, in that the higher the wage, the higher one s skills set is assumed to be, and vice-versa 1. The Migration Advisory Committee (2012) found that migrants increase wages at the top of the UK distribution, and lower them at the bottom. Similarly, the Home Office concluded relevant literature is reasonably consistent in suggesting that any displacement effect is likely to be greatest for the low skilled (Home Office, 2014, p7). It seems reasonably clear that while immigration may invigorate high skilled, well-paid industries, high levels of immigration of low-skilled workers can come at a cost to British society, precisely what Cameron wished to avoid. However, concluding this does not immediately suggest a clamping down on un-skilled worker immigration is necessary. Arguably, it is justifiable, but it is also certainly not the only option the government faces. One could argue that increasing education and training programmes in the UK would better equip native workers to compete for jobs. On the other hand, given the immigration of low-skilled workers does come at a cost to British society, and that it wasn t a crucial group for the economy, the clamping down of such immigration could be argued for. There is a plethora of contradictory, conflicting and confusing data available regarding the cost of immigration to the UK economy and labour market. On balance it would appear as though there are low, if any, fiscal costs to immigration, given that on average they claim fewer benefits and are generally here for productive, rather than dependent, periods of their life. Additionally, it seems that there are few employment costs to the labour market, except for affecting wages and job displacement for lower-skilled workers, which could be addressed with increased training and education programmes, or with a slightly tighter immigration policy. Conclusion This essay has made no attempts to show that immigration, on the whole, should be tightened. It has shown that immigration is important for the UK economy, in theory and in practise: it is vital that the UK can still attract talented, mobile workers from the 1 The Author acknowledges that there is an issue with often over-qualified immigrants working low paid jobs, but this essay is not the pace for such a discussion. See Altorjai (2013) for more.

global labour market in order to grow and prosper. Secondly, section two discussed the costs of high levels of immigration, both fiscally, and for the labour market, concluding that despite disagreements about overall costs, it would appear that immigration largely is not the drain on the state that people often are led to believe. This being said, there is evidence of some job displacement for low skilled workers. The costs of this, coupled with the fact that the immigration of lower skilled workers is less valuable to the economy, means that a clamping down on their immigration could be justified. In short, although there is room to tighten immigration policy to slow the influx of unskilled workers, there appears little evidence to justify a clamping down of immigration policy generally as it is invaluable and inexpensive for the UK.

References Altorjai, S. "Over-qualification of immigrants in the UK." Institute For Social and Economi Research (ISER Working Paper Series ), 2013: 1-53. Bhagwait, J, and G Hanson. Skilled Immigration Today: Prospects, Problems and Policies. Oxford : Oxford University Press, 2009. Borjas, G. Labour Economics. 6th Edition;. New York : McGraw Hill Education, 2013. Centre for Cities. Cities Outlook 2014. January 27, 2014. http://www.centreforcities.org/publication/cities-outlook-2014/ (accessed March 11, 2015). Dustmann, C, A Glitz, and T Frattini. "The Labour Market Impact of Immigartion." Oxford REview of Economic Policy, 2008 : 477-494. Dustmann, C, and I Preston. "Is Immigration Good or Bad for the Economy? Analysis of Attitudinal Responses." CReAM Discussion Paper Series CReAM Discussion Paper No 06/04 (2004). Dustmann, C, and T Frattini. "The Fiscal Effects of Immigration to the UK." The Economic Journal, 2014. Ehrenbern, R G, and R Smith. Modern Labour Economics. London : Pearson Eduction, 2009. Home Office. The Economic and Fiscal Impact of Immigration: A Cross-Departmental Submission to the House of Lords Select Committee on Economi Affairs. London : The Staionary Office, 2007. Home Office; Department for Business Innovation & Skills. Impacts of migration on UK native employment: An analytical review of the evidence. Occasional Paper 109, London : Home Office & Department for Business Innovation and Skills, 2014. Home Office. Employment and occupational skill levels among UK and foreign nationals. Occasional Paper 108, London : The Home Office, 2014. Husted, S, and M Melvin. International Economics. Eighth Edition. Boston : Pearson, 2010. IMF. "The Globalisation of Labor." In World Economic Outlook: Spillovers and Cycles in the Global Economy, by IMF. New York : Available online at: http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2007/01/index.htm, 2007. Ipsos MORI. "Perceotion and Reality: 10 Things we Should Know About Attitudes to Immingration in the UK." Ipsos MORI. January 2014. https://www.ipsos-

mori.com/assets/docs/publications/sri-perceptions-and-reality-immigration-reportsummary-2013.pdf (accessed March 11, 2015). Kellner, P. "What we Believe About Immigration." YouGov. November 25, 2013. https://yougov.co.uk/news/2013/11/25/what-we-believe-about-immigration/ (accessed March 7, 2015). Migration Advisory Committee. Analysis of the Impacts of Migration. London : Migration Advisory Comittee, 2012. Migration Observatoy. "UK Public Opinion toward Immigration: Overall Attitudes and Level of." Migration Observatory. July 3, 2014. http://www.migrationobservatory.ox.ac.uk/briefings/uk-public-opinion-towardimmigration-overall-attitudes-and-level-concern#kp4 (accessed March 10, 2015). Migration Watch UK. An Assessment of the Fiscal Effects of Immigration to the UK. Migration Watch UK, 2014. OECD. "Interntinal Migration Outlook." OECD ilibrary. June 13, 2013. http://www.oecd-ilibrary.org/social-issues-migration-health/international-migrationoutlook-2013_migr_outlook-2013-en (accessed March 7, 2015). Office for National Statistics. Migration Statistics Quarterly Report, February 2015. London : Office for National Statistics, 2015. Oxford Economics. Global Talent 2021: How the New Geography of Talent will Transform Human Resource Strategies. Oxford: Oxford Economics, 2012. Rowthorn, R. Large Scale Immigration: It's Economic and demographic Consequences for the UK. London: Civitas: Institute for the Study of Civil Society, 2014. Van den Berg, H. International Economics: A Heterdox Approach. New York: M. E. Sharpe, 2012.