The effects of congressional rules about bill cosponsorship on duplicate bills: Changing incentives for credit claiming*

Similar documents
Determinants of legislative success in House committees*

A Vote Equation and the 2004 Election

A positive correlation between turnout and plurality does not refute the rational voter model

Pavel Yakovlev Duquesne University. Abstract

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach

Party Polarization, Revisited: Explaining the Gender Gap in Political Party Preference

Residential segregation and socioeconomic outcomes When did ghettos go bad?

The Incumbent Spending Puzzle. Christopher S. P. Magee. Abstract. This paper argues that campaign spending by incumbents is primarily useful in

FOREIGN FIRMS AND INDONESIAN MANUFACTURING WAGES: AN ANALYSIS WITH PANEL DATA

Partisan Nation: The Rise of Affective Partisan Polarization in the American Electorate

Aggregate Vote Functions for the US. Presidency, Senate, and House

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation

The Seventeenth Amendment, Senate Ideology, and the Growth of Government

Congressional Agenda Control and the Decline of Bipartisan Cooperation

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants

Skill Classification Does Matter: Estimating the Relationship Between Trade Flows and Wage Inequality

Does Inequality Increase Crime? The Effect of Income Inequality on Crime Rates in California Counties

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

Crime and Corruption: An International Empirical Study

Determinants of Voting Behavior on the Keystone XL Pipeline

Supplementary Materials A: Figures for All 7 Surveys Figure S1-A: Distribution of Predicted Probabilities of Voting in Primary Elections

Honors General Exam PART 3: ECONOMETRICS. Solutions. Harvard University April 2014

IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE EASTERN DISTRICT OF PENNSYLVANIA

Distorting Democracy: How Gerrymandering Skews the Composition of the House of Representatives

The Political Determinants of Federal Expenditure at the State Level

The Textile, Apparel, and Footwear Act of 1990: Determinants of Congressional Voting

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE LABOR MARKET IMPACT OF HIGH-SKILL IMMIGRATION. George J. Borjas. Working Paper

Table XX presents the corrected results of the first regression model reported in Table

Public Perceptions of Immigration in European Union: A Survey Analysis of Eurobarometer 83.3 and 85.2

Female parliamentarians and economic growth: Evidence from a large panel

Unequal Recovery, Labor Market Polarization, Race, and 2016 U.S. Presidential Election. Maoyong Fan and Anita Alves Pena 1

Amy Tenhouse. Incumbency Surge: Examining the 1996 Margin of Victory for U.S. House Incumbents

Lab 3: Logistic regression models

Guns and Butter in U.S. Presidential Elections

Research Note: U.S. Senate Elections and Newspaper Competition

Appendix: Uncovering Patterns Among Latent Variables: Human Rights and De Facto Judicial Independence

A REPLICATION OF THE POLITICAL DETERMINANTS OF FEDERAL EXPENDITURE AT THE STATE LEVEL (PUBLIC CHOICE, 2005) Stratford Douglas* and W.

Schooling and Cohort Size: Evidence from Vietnam, Thailand, Iran and Cambodia. Evangelos M. Falaris University of Delaware. and

Can Politicians Police Themselves? Natural Experimental Evidence from Brazil s Audit Courts Supplementary Appendix

Research Statement. Jeffrey J. Harden. 2 Dissertation Research: The Dimensions of Representation

The Elasticity of Partisanship in Congress: An Analysis of Legislative Bipartisanship

Web Appendix for More a Molehill than a Mountain: The Effects of the Blanket Primary on Elected Officials Behavior in California

Factors influencing Latino immigrant householder s participation in social networks in rural areas of the Midwest

Congressional Agenda Control and the Decline of Bipartisan Cooperation

oductivity Estimates for Alien and Domestic Strawberry Workers and the Number of Farm Workers Required to Harvest the 1988 Strawberry Crop

The Job of President and the Jobs Model Forecast: Obama for '08?

Hungary. Basic facts The development of the quality of democracy in Hungary. The overall quality of democracy

The recent socio-economic development of Latin America presents

Asking about social circles improves election predictions

Forecasting the 2018 Midterm Election using National Polls and District Information

Practice Questions for Exam #2

Brain drain and Human Capital Formation in Developing Countries. Are there Really Winners?

If you notice additional errors or discrepancies in the published data, please contact us at

Expressive Voting and Government Redistribution *

ANALYSIS OF THE EFFECT OF REMITTANCES ON ECONOMIC GROWTH USING PATH ANALYSIS ABSTRACT

Family Shelter Entry and Re-entry over the Recession in Hennepin County, MN:

EXPORT, MIGRATION, AND COSTS OF MARKET ENTRY EVIDENCE FROM CENTRAL EUROPEAN FIRMS

EFFECTS OF REMITTANCE AND FDI ON THE ECONOMIC GROWTH OF BANGLADESH

Convergence across EU Members and the Consequences for the Czech Republic

Res Publica 29. Literature Review

Candidate Faces and Election Outcomes: Is the Face-Vote Correlation Caused by Candidate Selection? Corrigendum

When Does Legal Origin Matter? Mohammad Amin * World Bank. Priya Ranjan ** University of California, Irvine. December 2008

Congressional Agenda Control and the Decline of Bipartisan Cooperation

Working Paper Series Department of Economics Alfred Lerner College of Business & Economics University of Delaware

Dependency on Military Base Employment's Effect on Defense Expenditure Voting in Congress: A BRAC Era Test of the Military Industrial Complex Theory

from the SAGE Social Science Collections. All Rights Reserved.

Birth Control Policy and Housing Markets: The Case of China. By Chenxi Zhang (UO )

Appendix: Supplementary Tables for Legislating Stock Prices

I ll marry you if you get me a job Marital assimilation and immigrant employment rates

Corruption and quality of public institutions: evidence from Generalized Method of Moment

A Multivariate Analysis of the Factors that Correlate to the Unemployment Rate. Amit Naik, Tarah Reiter, Amanda Stype

Competition Policy for Elections: Do Campaign Contribution Limits Matter?

The Effect of Foreign Direct Investment, Foreign Aid and International Remittance on Economic Growth in South Asian Countries

Sponsorship and Cosponsorship of Senate Bills

Trade, Technology, and Institutions: How Do They Affect Wage Inequality? Evidence from Indian Manufacturing. Amit Sadhukhan 1.

The interaction effect of economic freedom and democracy on corruption: A panel cross-country analysis

I'll Marry You If You Get Me a Job: Marital Assimilation and Immigrant Employment Rates

Declaration of Charles Stewart III on Excess Undervotes Cast in Sarasota County, Florida for the 13th Congressional District Race

Inter- and Intra-Chamber Differences and the Distribution of Policy Benefits

The Causes of Wage Differentials between Immigrant and Native Physicians

AMERICAN JOURNAL OF UNDERGRADUATE RESEARCH VOL. 3 NO. 4 (2005)

And Yet it Moves: The Effect of Election Platforms on Party. Policy Images

Investigating the Effects of Migration on Economic Growth in Aging OECD Countries from

Are the networks biased? Calling states in the 2000 presidential election

Abdurohman Ali Hussien,,et.al.,Int. J. Eco. Res., 2012, v3i3, 44-51

Supplementary/Online Appendix for:

Follow this and additional works at: Part of the American Politics Commons

Model of Voting. February 15, Abstract. This paper uses United States congressional district level data to identify how incumbency,

A Behavioral Measure of the Enthusiasm Gap in American Elections

Is Corruption Anti Labor?

Congressional Careers: Service Tenure and Patterns of Member Service,

An Analysis of U.S. Congressional Support for the Affordable Care Act

ABSENTEE VOTING, MOBILIZATION, AND PARTICIPATION

Party registration choices as a function of the geographic distribution of partisanship: a model of hidden partisanship and an illustrative test

Staff Tenure in Selected Positions in House Member Offices,

Remittances and Poverty. in Guatemala* Richard H. Adams, Jr. Development Research Group (DECRG) MSN MC World Bank.

Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions. Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University. August 2018

The Threat Continues. Medicaid, the Budget, and Deficit Reduction: The Bottom Line: Our Message on Medicaid and the Super Committee Process

Tsukuba Economics Working Papers No Did the Presence of Immigrants Affect the Vote Outcome in the Brexit Referendum? by Mizuho Asai.

Staff Tenure in Selected Positions in Senators Offices,

Transcription:

Public Choice 75: 93-98, 1993. 1993 Ktuwer Academic Publishers. Printed in the Nether/ands. Research note The effects of congressional rules about bill cosponsorship on duplicate bills: Changing incentives for credit claiming* SCOTT THOMAS BERNARD GROFMAN School of Social Sciences, University of CaliJornia, Ir ine, CA 92717 Accepted 27 March I991 Abstract. We generate for the first time a time series that allows us to identify the number of duplicate bills in Congresses operating under different rules about the cosponsorship of bills. We show that changes in the coiagressional rules about bill cosponsorship affected the number of duplicate bills in a way fully consistent with a public choice perspective on legislative "credit claiming." 1. Introduction Before the 96th Congress, the rute for bill cosponsorship in the House of Representatives had been such that no more than 25 congressmen could sign on as cosponsors and that the congressmen had to sign on at the time a bill was introduced. 1 In part as a result of this rule, identical bills were often introduced, causing printing costs to substantially rise and leading to confusion over which bills members wanted their constituents to support (Congressional Record, 10 October 1978: 34930). The rule was changed by H. Resolution 86 (95th Congress) to permit an unlimited number of cosponsors and to permit cosponsors to be added even after a bill was in committee. 2 In the 93rd Congress, House members introduced 7,275 duplicate bills, each with an average of 6.5 sponsors. Indeed, 44.2 7o of all House bills introduced in that Congress were duplicates. By the 97th Congress, the number of duplicate bills had been cut to 472. Data on the number of duplicate bills introduced and cosponsorship is shown in Tables 1 and 2. The focus of this brief research note is to relate these changes to our understanding of congressional "credit claiming" by generating for the first time a time series that identifies the number of duplicate bills in * We are grateful to an anonymous referee for helpful comments. We are also grateful to Wilma Laws and the Staff of the Word Processing Center, School of Social Sciences, UCI for manuscript typing, Dorothy Gormick for bibliographic assistance, and National Economic Research Associates, Inc. for financial support.

94 Table 1. Identical bills a Congress Public bills introduced in House Multiply introduced public bills introduced in House 91st (1969-70) 14,010 3,566 93rd (1973-74) 16,452 7,275 95th (1977-78) 13,117 5,610 97th (1981-82) 6,842 472 a Figures compiled by the authors. Estimated from a sample of one bill in one hundred taken from Digest of Public General Bills and Resolutions. In addition to differences caused by sampling errors, the figures in this table differ from the time-series data in Ornstein, Mann and Malbin (1989: Table 6-I) because, unlike them, we do not include either joint resolutions or private bills. Note: Data source does not indicate whether there were any identical private bills introduced. We are not counting the "original" bill in the last column of our table. This counting practice differs from that in the Digest. Table 2. Bill cosponsorship a Congress Average number Average number Percentage of original multiply of sponsors of sponsors introduced bills containing (public bills) (multiply introduced bills) 25 or more sponsors 91st (1969-70) 2.4 3.2 10 93rd (1973-74) 4.5 6.5 3 95th (1977-78) 5.2 9.2 10 97th (1981-82) 8.3 54.0 0 a All figures compiled by the anthors. Calculated from a sample of one bill in one hundred taken from two sources: Congressional Record Index (which lists the number of sponsors per bill) and Digest of Public General Bills and Resolutions. Note. The sample for the 97th Congress contains one multiply introduced bill, one version of which had 202 sponsors; neither the bill nor any of its duplicates got reported from committee. However, the original version of that multiply introduced bill had only one sponsor. (If the same bill has been introduced a number of times, then the "original" multiply introduced bill refers to the first time the bill was introduced.) congresses and clearly links the number of bills introduced in congress to changes in rules as to cosponsorship. The number of bills introduced in the House increased steadily in the 1950s and sharply after 1964, then began to drop toward the 1970s; but the most striking phenomenon in the data (see Table 3; taken from Ornstein, Mann and Malbin, 1989: Tables 6-I and 6-2) is the sharp drop from the 1977-78 term to the 1979-80 term and subsequently in the House. For the Senate, the number of bills introduced has hovered near 4,000 (although there are signs of a very recent downward trend), and there are no sharp breaks in the Senate series like that observed in the House between the 95th and 96th Congresses.

95 Table 3. Bills introduced and bills passed in the House and Senate, 80th - 100th Congress, 1947-1988 Congress House Senate Bills Bills Ratio of Bills Bills Ratio of introduced passed bills passed to introduced passed bills passed to bills introduced bills introduced 80th (1947-48) 7,611 1,739.228 3.186 1,670.524 81st (1949-50) 10,502 2,482.236 4,486 2,362.527 82nd (1951-52) 9,065 2,008.222 3,665 1,849.505 83rd (1953-54) 10,875 2,129.196 4,077 2,231.547 84th (1955-56) 13,169 2,360.179 4,518 2,550.564 85th (1957-58) 14,580 2,064.142 4,532 2,202.486 86th (1959-60) 14,112 1,636.116 4,149 1,680.405 87th (1961-62) 14,328 1,927.134 4,048 1,953.482 88th (1963-64) 14,022 1,267.090 3,457 1,341.388 89th (1965-66) 19,874 1,565.079 4,129 1,636.396 90th (1967-68) 22,060 1,213.055 4,400 1,376.313 91st (1969-70) 21,436 1,t30.053 4,867 1,271.261 92nd (1971-72) 18,561 970.052 4,408 1,035.235 93rd (1973-74) 18,~72 923.049 4,524 1,115,246 94th (1975-76) 16,982 968.057 4,114 1,038.252 95th (1977-78) 15,587 1,027.066 3,800 1,070.282 96th (1979-80) 9,103 929.102 3,480 977.281 97th (1981-82) 8,094 704.087 3,396 803.236 98th (1983-84) 7,105 978.137 3,454 936.27i 99th (1985-86) 6,499 973.150 3,386 940.278 100th (1987-88) 6,263 1,061.169 3,325 1,002.310 Source: Ornstein, Mann and Malbin (1989: Tables 6-1, and 6-2). Ornstein, Mann and Malbin (1989: 159) state in their invaluable compendium of congressional statistics that the drop in the number of House bills is due to the rule change regarding cosponsorship: "(I)n part because of changes in the rules regarding cosponsorship, which reduced the need to introduce multiple numbers of an identical bill, the numbers (of bills introduced) dropped dramatically in the 96th Congress - by 42 percent - and have continued to decline." To test their hypothesis we estimated the following equations: HBILLS = a I + b11trend + b12rule + b13sbills + e 1 and SBILLS = a 2 + b2~trend + b2:rule + b23hbills + e2, where

96 HBILLS is the number of bills introduced in the House; SBILLS is the number of bills introduced in the Senate; TREND is a time trend variable (80th Congress equals 1); RULE is the rule change variable (1 if the bills introduced after the 95th Congress, 0 otherwise); ai's are the intercepts; bij's are the regression coefficients; ei's are the stochastic disturbance terms. Our statistical test involves two equations to control for the possibility that some outside factor, and not the rule change regarding cosponsorship, caused the reduction in the number of bills introduced. If some outside factor caused the reduction, the estimated regression coefficient for RULE should be negative and statistically significant in both equations. On the other hand, if the rule change caused the reduction, the estimated regression coefficient for RULE should be negative and statistically significant in the House equation but insignificant in the Senate equation. We have included the dependent variable for each equation as an explanatory variable in the other equation since a large number of bills, with the same text, are simultaneously introduced in each chamber. 3 For example, in the 95th Congress, House and Senate members simultaneously introduced 926 bills. The two stage least squares results are listed in Table 4. We used TREND, RULE, and the lagged value for HBILLS (lagged one Congress) as the instruments for the Senate equation. 4 We also tried to use TREND, RULE, and the lagged value of SBILLS for the House equation; but, unfortunately the lagged value of SBILLS was not statistically significant in the reduced form equation - implying that this variable is not a good instrument. The instruments we finally used for the House equation are TREND, RULE, the number of Democrats divided by the number of Republicans in the Senate, and the mean years of service in the Senate. 5 The results in Table 4 show that the estimated regression coefficient for RULE is negative and significant at the 1 percent level in the House equation but insignificant in the Senate equation. The results also show that the estimated regression coefficient for the endogenous explanatory is positive and significant at the 5 percent level in both equations. These results support the conclusion that the rule change caused the reduction in bills in the House, and that the reduction of bills in the House caused the reduction of bills in the Senate. 6 2. Discussion Why would members wish to introduce duplicate bills or to cosponsor bills? One answer is that this creates a sense of momentum for a bill which may make

97 Table 4. Coefficients/(t-statistics) Dependent variable Explanatory variables HBILLS SBILLS Constant - 5573.88 3444.15 (- 0.55) (8.12) TREND 498.02-42.21 (3.16) ( - 1.44) RULE - 10232.0 220.50 ( - 3.94) (0.37) SBILLS 4.04 - (I.74) HBILLS - 0.07 (1.89) R 2 0.84 0.68 F-statistic 24.97 11.30 Observations 18 20 it difficult to oppose it. Indeed, we observe representatives who plan on introducing a bill soliciting others to join on as cosponsors (Campbell, 1982). Another answer is that it allows credit-claiming (Campbell, 1982). The latter argument seems the stronger, because otherwise we would not see so many members go to the seemingly ridiculous extreme of introducing identical bills under their own names. For example, H.R. 309 in the 95th Congress (liberalizing the eligibility of blind persons to receive disability benefits under social security) was introduced into the House 52 times; i.e., there were 51 identical bills. The observed post-95th Congress effect of change in the House cosponsorship rules, namely, a reduction in the number of bills introduced, is exactly what would be predicted by a public choice model of legislators as rational actors. 7 It was no longer necessary to sponsor a duplicate bill because the deadline for adding your name to an existing bill had passed. However, even after 1979, members still introduced duplicate bills. It must have been a reason other than "no room for more cosponsors" that led individuals to introduce an identical bill under their own names. 8 One answer, suggested by public choice theory, is that being able to claim a bill as "one's own" is a stronger credit to be claimed than mere cosponsorship. Another answer is that the original bill may have stalled in the legislative process.

- creating 98 Notes 1. We should also note that, prior to the 91st Congress, cosponsorship of bills was not allowed the necessity of duplicate bills for representatives concerned with credit-claiming. 2. Cosponsors can be added up to the day on which the last committee to which the bill has been referred orders the measure reported to the House. 3. Although the number of House and Senate bills that is simultaneously introduced is large, the percentage of House and Senate bills simultaneously introduced is not large. This means any bias caused by estimating our equations using ordinary least squares should be small. 4. The lagged value of the endogenous explanatory variable is the most popular instrumental variable in a time series setting (Kennedy 1984; Kmenta 1986); 5. The data for the new variables comes from Vital Statistics on Congress 1989-1990. Since the data for mean years of service begins in the 83rd Congress, our House equation has two less observations than our Senate equation. We also estimated our Senate equation using TREND, RULE, the number of Democrats divided by the number of Republicans in the House, and mean years of service in the House. The only difference between these results (not included in this paper) and the results in Table 4 is that the t-statistic for the estimated regression coefficient for HBILLS is not significant, although it is still greater than one. 6. The equations in Table 4 were reestimated using ordinary least squares. The signs, magnitudes, and t-statistics of the new estimated regression coefficients are almost identical to those in Table 4. 7. Our problem is not a standard public goods problem. The standard problem predicts that if the cost of excluding free riders increases, less of the public good will be produced. In our problem the cost of excluding free riders has not changed: the first sponsor can still deny other representatives the right to add their names to the bill as cosponsors and other representatives can still introduce identical bills. In addition, the number of original bills introduced in the House has remained about the same: House members introduced 7,507 original bills in the 95th Congress and 6,367 original bills in the 97th Congress (see Table 1 for details). 8. However, even with sponsorship rules held constant, constituency-oriented credit claiming appears to have been increasing prior to 1979 (see Table t) leading to a higher proportion of duplicate bills in the 93rd and 95th Congresses as compared to the 91st, and thus creating an essentially imaginary growth in the number of bills introduced. References Campbell, J.E, (1982). Co-sponsoring legislation in the U.S. Congress. Legislative Studies Quarterly 7: 415-422. Kennedy, P. (t984). A guide to econometrics. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Kmenta, J. (1986). Elements of econometrics, 2nd ed. New York: Macmillan. Ornstein, N., Mann, T. and Malbin, M. (1989). Vital statistics on Congress. 1989-1990. Washington, DC: American Enterprise Institute.