A Short Review of Generalized Trust

Similar documents
Culture, Social Capital and Development through History

Foundations of social life: trust and trustworthiness

Topics in Trade and Development

EUI Working Papers DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ECO 2010/08 DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS. Civic Capital as the Missing Link

Experimental and Behavioral Economics

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES CIVIC CAPITAL AS THE MISSING LINK. Luigi Guiso Paola Sapienza Luigi Zingales

Asking for More: Support for Redistribution in the Age of Inequality

Trust level matters; correlation of government openness to social trust in high and low trust societies

REVIEW OF FOUNDATIONS OF HUMAN SOCIALITY: ECONOMIC EXPERIMENTS AND ETHNOGRAPHIC EVIDENCE FROM FIFTEEN SMALL-SCALE SOCIETIES

New Institutional Economics, Econ Spring 2016

Forms of Civic Engagement and Corruption

Trust and Social Capital in Immigrant Networks

MORALITY - evolutionary foundations and policy implications

Evaluation: Papers, 30 percent; Research proposal, 30 percent; Class participation, 40 percent.

Do Liberals Play Nice? The Effects of Party and Political Ideology in Public Goods and Trust Games

Immigration and Redistribution Revisited How Different Motivations Can Offset Each Other

Resource Allocations and Disapproval Voting in Unequal Groups

Cultural Change and Business History

Trust, Well-Being and Growth: New Evidence and Policy Implications

Corruption and Social Capital Formation

Trust and International Energy Co-operation

Trust and Trustworthiness of Immigrants and Native-Born Americans *

Syllabus for 260A: Comparative economics. ( ). Instructor : Gérard Roland

Trust and CO 2 Emissions: Cooperation on a Global Scale

Institutional Tension

Trust and CO 2 Emissions: Cooperation on a Global Scale

Undergraduate Programme, Faculty of Economic Sciences, University of Warsaw

: Organizational Economics (CentER) Fall Jens Prüfer Office: K 311,

Family Values and the Regulation of Labor

The Intergenerational Persistence of Attitudes toward Corruption

Immigrant Assimilation, Trust and Social Capital

Textbooks: The course will rely on two required textbooks in addition to the assigned articles and books:

Institutions and Culture

Cooperative membership as a signal of trust and trustworthiness in a low income economic environment: a randomized experiment in the Philippines

RECIPROCITY: WEAK OR STRONG? WHAT PUNISHMENT EXPERIMENTS DO (AND DO NOT) DEMONSTRATE

Testing Political Economy Models of Reform in the Laboratory

Immigrant Assimilation, Trust and Social Capital

The Governance Game. GOVERNANCE and THE LAW BACKGROUND PAPER. Sheheryar Banuri University of East Anglia

Trust, Cooperation and Development Historical Roots. Timur Kuran, Duke University

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE TRANSMISSION OF DEMOCRACY: FROM THE VILLAGE TO THE NATION-STATE. Paola Giuliano Nathan Nunn

ECON 542 DISCUSSION TOPICS FALL 2013

Schooling in Capitalist America Twenty-Five Years Later

Corporate Corruption and the Failure of Business School Education. Herbert Gintis and Rakesh Khurana

Liberté, Egalité, Fraternité!

Evolution of Trust in Impersonal Exchange

Europe and the US: Preferences for Redistribution

Civilizing Society: Virtues, Freedom, and Development

Recent research demonstrates that cultural

The Trust Paradox: A Survey of Economic Inquiries Into the Nature. of Trust and Trustworthiness

Does Democracy Foster Trust? Evidence from the German Reunification

Conditional Clauses in GHG Abatement Legislation

(2000) ] Gehmacher, Ernst, 2002, OECD-conference on SOCIAL CAPITAL: SOCIAL

Cooperation, punishment, emergence of government and the tragedy of authorities

244U/344U: Political Culture Fall 2017

Eric M. Uslaner, Inequality, Trust, and Civic Engagement (1)

How We Can Save Africa

Jan 19 April 13 (No Class on March 2) Evaluation is based on class participation (30%), midterm and final exams (30% and 40% respectively).

Does Corruption Affect the Private Provision of Public Goods?

Introduction. Cambridge University Press Lopez (1976); Persson (1998); Postan (1973); and Pounds (1994).

Trust, Ethnic Diversity, and Personal Contact: Experimental Field Evidence

Centre for Economic Policy Research

From Bounded Rationality to Behavioral Economics: Comment on Amitai Etzioni Statement on Behavioral Economics, SASE, July, 2009

Syllabus for 260A: Comparative economics. ( ). Instructor : Gérard Roland.

The Transmission of Democracy: From the Village to the Nation-State

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES CULTURE AND INSTITUTIONS. Alberto Alesina Paola Giuliano. Working Paper

Culture: Persistence and evolution

What is the Nature and Social Norm within the Context of In-Group Favouritism?

The Olson - Putnam Controversy: Some Empirical Evidence. Abstract

Until recently, economists have been reluctant to rely on culture as a

Introduction to New Institutional Economics: A Report Card

Supporting Information Political Quid Pro Quo Agreements: An Experimental Study

WWS 300 DEMOCRACY. Spring Robertson Hall 428 Robertson Hall Ph: Ph:

Health Consequences of Legal Origin

Who trusts others? Community and individual determinants of social capital in Bangladesh?

Measuring the Effect of Bankruptcy Laws on Entrepreneurship Across Countries

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES DOES CULTURE AFFECT ECONOMIC OUTCOMES? Luigi Guiso Paola Sapienza Luigi Zingales

Does It Matter Where You Came From? Ancestry Composition and Economic Performance of US Counties,

Formal Political Theory II: Applications

I assume familiarity with multivariate calculus and intermediate microeconomics.

The social consequences of economic growth: The relationship between real household income and self-declared tolerance

Fairness as a constraint on trust in reciprocity: earned property rights in a reciprocal exchange experiment

THE TRUSTLAB PROJECT:

Political Science 344U Stanford University Fall Quarter, 2016 Thursdays 10:30AM to 1:20PM. Political Culture

Strong Reciprocity and the Welfare State. Christina M. Fong, Samuel Bowles and Herbert Gintis. July 3, 2004

Vienna Technical University January 26, 2010

Robust Political Economy. Classical Liberalism and the Future of Public Policy

Joep de Hart Paul Dekker Marc Hooghe Michel Huysseune Nonna Mayer Job van der Meer Nadia Molenaers

FAMILY TIES AND POLITICAL PARTICIPATION

Jan Theodor Schikora: Bringing good and bad Whistle-blowers to the Lab

Norms of Distributive Justice in Rural Malawi

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES CULTURE: PERSISTENCE AND EVOLUTION. Francesco Giavazzi Ivan Petkov Fabio Schiantarelli

Chapter 1: What is sociology?

Economics 420 Professor Joel Mokyr Winter The New Economics of History: Syllabus and Readings

WWS 300 DEMOCRACY. Fall 2010, Tu-Th, 10-10:50

On the need for professionalism in the ICT industry

Ethnic Persistence, Assimilation and Risk Proclivity

Cooperation Hidden Frontiers: The Behavioral Foundations of the Italian North-South Divide

ANALYSES OF SUSTAINABLE MANAGEMENT OF COMMON- POOL RESOURCES

INTRODUCTION: CORRUPTION AND RATIONALITY

The Origins of the Modern State

Transcription:

A Short Review of Generalized Trust Prateek Raj University College London I Introduction Trust has become an important area of study in social sciences. Sociologist Edward Banfield wrote his pioneering book Moral Basis of Backward Society in 1958, and described a Hobbesian lack of social trust in southern Italy towards people outside of strict family circles. He attributed the region s present day underdevelopment to the amoral familism, that made people act distrustfully towards non-family members, expecting others to do the same. Contrastingly, Tocqueville in his book Democracy in America (1840) (Tocqueville, 1862) gave a flattering description of civic culture in the United States noting, Each American knows when to sacrifice some of his private interests to save the rest. Emphasizing the importance of civic culture he wrote science of association is the mother of science; the progress of all the rest depends upon the progress it has made. Among economists, Arrow (1969) was among the first to identify the value of trust, and he wrote norms of social behavior, including ethical and moral codes may compensate for market failure and in the absence of trust many opportunities for mutually beneficial cooperation would have to be, foregone. Over the last few decades, a considerable macroeconomic literature has emerged that shows trust has economic significance (Knack and Keefer, 1997; La Porta et al., 1997; Zak and Knack, 2001) and levels of trust are different across groups and regions, which are persistent (Putnam, Leonardi and Nanetti, UCL School of Management, p.raj.12@ucl.ac.uk. 1

1994; Uslaner, 2002; Guiso, Sapienza and Zingales, 2008b; Tabellini, 2008a; Durante, 2009; Nunn and Wantchekon, 2011) and only gradually change (Alesina and La Ferrara, 2002; Giavazzi, Petkov and Schiantarelli, 2014). I.1 Theoretical and Empirical literature Drawing upon influential sociological research being conducted on social capital (Granovetter, 1973, 1985; Coleman, 1988), in 1990s two influential sociological works, Putnam, Leonardi and Nanetti (1994) and Fukuyama (1995), emphasized the role of trust on economic development. But, some economists (e.g. Solow (1995)) pointed at the problems in measuring trust as a macroeconomic variable. Some empirical papers (Knack and Keefer, 1997; La Porta et al., 1997; Zak and Knack, 2001) began to measure trust using the international World Values Survey (WVS), that asked respondents Generally speaking, would you say that most people can be trusted, or that you can t be too careful in dealing with people? The greater the proportion of people in a country answering yes to the question, the greater the general trust in the country was considered to be. A country s level of trust was found to be correlated with its economic growth (Knack and Keefer, 1997), and with efficiency in large organizations (La Porta et al., 1997). Zak and Knack (2001) developed a moral hazard model, where ability of trust in an investment broker increased investment and income growth, and showed that trust and factors that could affect trust (like formal and informal institutions and social homogeneity) were correlated with income growth. There were also efforts by theorists to define trust. A large literature in sociology and management (surveyed by Rousseau et al. (1998)) attempted to understand trust between relationships. Mayer, Davis and Schoorman (1995) focused on the aspect of vulnerability that trusting someone entails in social exchanges. Yamagishi and Yamagishi (1994) made the distinction between impersonal vs. relationship based trust, and compared Japan and USA to argue that Japanese society relied more on relationship based trust, while United States had higher levels of generalized trust. Gambetta et al. (2000) considered trust to be 2

a subjective probability and Dasgupta (2000) theorized reputation for honesty as a sought after but fragile commodity. Dasgupta also argued that expectations regarding honest and dishonest conduct could be self-fulfilling affecting trust, while Putnam, Leonardi and Nanetti (1994) found that generalized trust was persistent, and linked high present day generalized trust in North Italy to persistent civic norms that had developed in the region because of existence of medieval city republics. Persistence of trust (Putnam, Leonardi and Nanetti, 1994) sparked the interest of researchers in its origins. Alesina and La Ferrara (2002) using individual level General Social Survey (GSS) data of US localities, found that generalized trust was lower in individuals who had a history of traumatic experience, who belonged to historically discriminated groups, who were economically and educationally unsuccessful, or who were living in neighbourhoods that were racially mixed or had high income inequality. Alesina and La Ferrara (2002) found no significant effect of religion or ethnic origin on trust. Uslaner (2002) argued that trusting others was a persistent moral value in individuals that was passed on by parents and was highly correlated with charity and voluntary work. He argued that trusting attitude was unaffected by personal experience or membership to civic groups (unlike Putnam, Leonardi and Nanetti (1994) who hypothesized that civic groups generated trust). Guiso, Sapienza and Zingales (2006), using GSS data found a strong positive correlation between generalized trust of US immigrants and the level of generalized trust (measured by WVS) in their country of origin, hinting towards persistence. Guiso, Sapienza and Zingales (2008b) found strong empirical evidence of historical persistence of trust attitude, as city republic experience during medieval era in North Italy was strongly and positively correlated to present levels of trust and social capital in the region, as hypothesized by Putnam, Leonardi and Nanetti (1994). Tabellini (2008a) also also found evidence of persistence, with higher levels of trust found in second generation US immigrants originating from countries with more democratic institutions over a century ago. Nunn and Wantchekon (2011) similarly found that experience of slavery 3

had a persistent effect on mistrust in Africa. Durante (2009) similarly showed that annual variability of weather conditions during 1500-1750 stimulated trust in Europe. Tabellini (2008b) developed a theoretical model to explain the persistence and found that impersonal values supporting trust between socially distant individuals could persist by creating a strong incentive for parents to invest in such value education, and by generating institutions that support such values ((Alesina and La Ferrara, 2002) found high social distance to be a barrier to trust). Guiso, Sapienza and Zingales (2008a) developed a model complimentary to the value based model of Tabellini (2008b), showing that beliefs regarding honesty of others could be persistent and transferred between generations. Giavazzi, Petkov and Schiantarelli (2014) using GSS data studied the persistence of trust attitude (and other cultural traits) among US immigrants in detail, and found that trust attitude brought by first generation US immigrants did not persist (unlike some other cultural traits) among fourth generation US immigrants, but second generation US immigrants showed some persistence. So, body of evidence suggests that values and beliefs regarding trust passed down by parents do persist among individuals (Putnam, Leonardi and Nanetti, 1994; Uslaner, 2002; Guiso, Sapienza and Zingales, 2008b; Tabellini, 2008a; Durante, 2009; Nunn and Wantchekon, 2011), but values and beliefs themselves can gradually change depending on individual experiences (Alesina and La Ferrara, 2002; Giavazzi, Petkov and Schiantarelli, 2014). Dohmen et al. (2012) looking at German Socio-Economic Panel (SOEP) data find similar results where risk and trust attitudes of children was affected by attitude of parents as well as prevailing attitude in the region. I.2 Experimental literature During the time a large body of empirical and theoretical literature was emerging, experimental literature was also emerging that highlighted the nature of trust at a micro level. Berg, Dickhaut and McCabe (1995) developed the influential investment game, which 4

has become a standard in literature as a means to understand and model (Zak and Knack, 2001; Guiso, Sapienza and Zingales, 2008a) trust and honesty (trustworthiness). In the game an investor decides to invest a particular amount with a trustee which gets multiplied and the trustee decides how much of money to return to the investor. An investor that invests a larger amount is considered more trusting, while a trustee that returns a larger amount is considered more honest, where the standard Nash equilibrium outcome is for investor to not invest, and for trustee to not return. The origins of the investment game can be traced to other stage games, like dictator game, ultimatum game, prisoner s dilemma game, trust game (Kreps, 1996), centipede game (Rosenthal, 1981) and exchange game (Fehr, Kirchsteiger and Riedl, 1993) each of which have been used by researchers to understand behavior that does not match the standard rational framework of economics. The experimental literature (starting with Berg, Dickhaut and McCabe (1995)) has found that unlike the standard game theory equilibrium, investors do invest and trustees do return. But, it is not necessarily clear if trusting and honest conduct reflects social preferences such as altruism or a norm of reciprocity (Cox, 2004), and if the social preferences are components of trust or separate from it. So, researchers have explored the preferences that underpin individual behavior to understand trust. Influential set of papers (on inequity aversion by Fehr and Schmidt (1999)); on altruistic punishment by Fehr and Gächter (2000, 2002); on altruism by Fehr and Fischbacher (2003); on betrayal aversion by Bohnet and Zeckhauser (2004); on reciprocity by Falk and Fischbacher (2006)) developed robust theories of fairness, altruism and reciprocity, and explored the behavioral underpinnings of trust. Classic paper by Fehr and Schmidt (1999) argued that inequity aversion could explain cooperation as individuals get motivated to inflict costly punishment to free riders. Exploring biological underpinnings of trust, Kosfeld et al. (2005) found that higher oxytocin increases trusting attitude. Another influential paper Henrich et al. (2001) looked at 15 small scale societies and showed that in the sampled societies individuals showed other regarding preferences and deviated from the standard homo- 5

economicus model. The social preference based framework is important for understanding human behavior, and it poses a question whether surveys like WVS measure trust or other preferences. But, the behavior based theories do not convincingly explain why there exists considerable heterogeneity in trusting behavior across societies and their determinants as measured in WVS surveys or trust games (Johnson and Mislin, 2011). The body of literature (surveyed by Fehr (2009)) has nonetheless convincingly shown that social preferences of individuals (which may or may not be universal) are an important component of what gets observed as trusting or honest conduct, and a narrow focus on economic preferences or beliefs is not enough to understand the topic, but more work needs to be done to understand how heterogeneity emerges in preferences and beliefs across societies and groups. References Alesina, Alberto, and Eliana La Ferrara. 2002. Who trusts others? Journal of public economics, 85(2): 207 234. Arrow, Kenneth J. 1969. The organization of economic activity: issues pertinent to the choice of market versus nonmarket allocation. The analysis and evaluation of public expenditure: the PPB system, 1: 59 73. Berg, Joyce, John Dickhaut, and Kevin McCabe. 1995. Trust, reciprocity, and social history. Games and economic behavior, 10(1): 122 142. Bohnet, Iris, and Richard Zeckhauser. 2004. Trust, risk and betrayal. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 55(4): 467 484. Coleman, James S. 1988. Social capital in the creation of human capital. American journal of sociology, S95 S120. 6

Cox, James C. 2004. How to identify trust and reciprocity. Games and economic behavior, 46(2): 260 281. Dasgupta, Partha. 2000. Trust as a commodity. Trust: Making and breaking cooperative relations, 4: 49 72. Dohmen, Thomas, Armin Falk, David Huffman, and Uwe Sunde. 2012. The intergenerational transmission of risk and trust attitudes. The Review of Economic Studies, 79(2): 645 677. Durante, Ruben. 2009. Risk, cooperation and the economic origins of social trust: an empirical investigation. Falk, Armin, and Urs Fischbacher. 2006. A theory of reciprocity. Games and economic behavior, 54(2): 293 315. Fehr, Ernst. 2009. On the economics and biology of trust. Journal of the european economic association, 7(2-3): 235 266. Fehr, Ernst, and Klaus M Schmidt. 1999. A theory of fairness, competition, and cooperation. Quarterly journal of Economics, 817 868. Fehr, Ernst, and Simon Gächter. 2000. Fairness and retaliation: The economics of reciprocity. The journal of economic perspectives, 14(3): 159 181. Fehr, Ernst, and Simon Gächter. 2002. Altruistic punishment in humans. Nature, 415(6868): 137 140. Fehr, Ernst, and Urs Fischbacher. 2003. The nature of human altruism. Nature, 425(6960): 785 791. Fehr, Ernst, Georg Kirchsteiger, and Arno Riedl. 1993. Does fairness prevent market clearing? An experimental investigation. The quarterly journal of economics, 437 459. 7

Fukuyama, Francis. 1995. Trust: The social virtues and the creation of prosperity. JSTOR. Gambetta, Diego, et al. 2000. Can we trust trust. Trust: Making and breaking cooperative relations, 13: 213 237. Giavazzi, Francesco, Ivan Petkov, and Fabio Schiantarelli. 2014. Culture: Persistence and evolution. National Bureau of Economic Research. Granovetter, Mark. 1985. Economic action and social structure: The problem of embeddedness. American journal of sociology, 481 510. Granovetter, Mark S. 1973. The strength of weak ties. American journal of sociology, 1360 1380. Guiso, Luigi, Paola Sapienza, and Luigi Zingales. 2006. Does culture affect economic outcomes? The journal of economic perspectives, 20(2): 23 48. Guiso, Luigi, Paola Sapienza, and Luigi Zingales. 2008a. Alfred marshall lecture social capital as good culture. Journal of the European Economic Association, 6(2-3): 295 320. Guiso, Luigi, Paola Sapienza, and Luigi Zingales. 2008b. Long term persistence. National Bureau of Economic Research. Henrich, Joseph, Robert Boyd, Samuel Bowles, Colin Camerer, Ernst Fehr, Herbert Gintis, and Richard McElreath. 2001. In search of homo economicus: behavioral experiments in 15 small-scale societies. The American Economic Review, 91(2): 73 78. Johnson, Noel D, and Alexandra A Mislin. 2011. Trust games: A meta-analysis. Journal of Economic Psychology, 32(5): 865 889. Knack, Stephen, and Philip Keefer. 1997. Does social capital have an economic payoff? A cross-country investigation. The Quarterly journal of economics, 1251 1288. 8

Kosfeld, Michael, Markus Heinrichs, Paul J Zak, Urs Fischbacher, and Ernst Fehr. 2005. Oxytocin increases trust in humans. Nature, 435(7042): 673 676. Kreps, David M. 1996. Corporate culture and economic theory. Firms, Organizations and Contracts, Oxford University Press, Oxford, 221 275. La Porta, Rafael, Florencio Lopez-de Silanes, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W Vishny. 1997. Trust in Large Organizations. The American Economic Review, 333 338. Mayer, Roger C, James H Davis, and F David Schoorman. 1995. An integrative model of organizational trust. Academy of management review, 20(3): 709 734. Nunn, Nathan, and Leonard Wantchekon. 2011. The slave trade and the origins of mistrust in Africa. The American Economic Review, 101(7): 3221 3252. Putnam, Robert D, Robert Leonardi, and Raffaella Y Nanetti. 1994. Making democracy work: Civic traditions in modern Italy. Princeton university press. Rosenthal, Robert W. 1981. Games of perfect information, predatory pricing and the chain-store paradox. Journal of Economic theory, 25(1): 92 100. Rousseau, Denise M, Sim B Sitkin, Ronald S Burt, and Colin Camerer. 1998. Not so different after all: A cross-discipline view of trust. Academy of management review, 23(3): 393 404. Solow, Robert M. 1995. But verify. The New Republic, 11: 36 39. Tabellini, Guido. 2008a. Presidential address institutions and culture. Journal of the European Economic Association, 6(2-3): 255 294. Tabellini, Guido. 2008b. The scope of cooperation: Values and incentives. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 123(3): 905 950. Tocqueville, Alexis Henri CM Clérel. 1862. Democracy in America, tr. by H. Reeve. 9

Uslaner, Eric M. 2002. The moral foundations of trust. Cambridge University Press. Yamagishi, Toshio, and Midori Yamagishi. 1994. Trust and commitment in the United States and Japan. Motivation and emotion, 18(2): 129 166. Zak, Paul J, and Stephen Knack. 2001. Trust and growth. The economic journal, 111(470): 295 321. 10