Rationalization of Tariffs: Some Lessons From International Experience 1

Similar documents
The SADC Trade Protocol: Towards a Resolution of Outstanding Issues on Rules of Origin

The SADC Trade Protocol: Outstanding Issues on Rules of Origin

TRADE POLICY REVIEW OF SOUTH AFRICA 1-2 JUNE GATT Council's Evaluation

PREFERENTIAL TRADE AGREEMENT BETWEEN THE REPUBLIC OF MAURITIUS AND THE ISLAMIC REPUBLIC OF PAKISTAN

Economics of the Trans- Pacific Partnership (TPP)

AFTA as Real Free trade Area

Global Economic Prospects 2004: Realizing the Development Promise of the Doha Agenda

International Business

The EU-ASEAN FTA: Gender Issues and Advocacy. Naty Bernardino International Gender & Trade Network - Asia

INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS, FINANCE AND TRADE Vol. II - Globalization and the Evolution of Trade - Pasquale M. Sgro

Trade theory and regional integration

Non-tariff barriers. Yuliya Chernykh

RULES OF ORIGIN. Chapter 9 1. OVERVIEW OF RULES. Figure 9-1

International Business 7e

CHAPTER 2 TRADE THEORIES AND ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT. a) absolute advantage (X) b) comparative advantage c) relative advantage d) factor endowment

The WTO in the Millennium: What is in Store?

Improving policy efficiency in South Asia - a conceptual approach. Dr Philippa Dee Crawford School of Economics and Government

East Asian Regionalism and the Multilateral Trading System ERIA

World business and the multilateral trading system

Economic integration: an agreement between

Dr. Biswajit Dhar Professor Jawaharlal Nehru University New Delhi

THE AEC PROGRESS, CHALLENGES AND PROSPECTS

The World Trade Organization and the future of multilateralism Note Key principles behind GATT general principle rules based not results based

FREE TRADE AGREEMENT BETWEEN THE ISLAMIC REPUBLIC OF PAKISTAN AND THE DEMOCRATIC SOCIALIST REPUBLIC OF SRI LANKA

Rules of Origin as Tools of Development? Some Lessons from SADC

Session 5: Overview of the process of negotiations and implementation

Seminar on Trade Facilitation in East Asia November 2004, Shanghai, China

Turning Trade Opportunities and Challenges into Trade: Implications for ASEAN Countries

Trans-Pacific Trade and Investment Relations Region Is Key Driver of Global Economic Growth

Summary of key points

Chapter 9. The Political Economy of Trade Policy. Slides prepared by Thomas Bishop

ASEAN: An Economic Pillar of Asia

MORE EMBARGO: TRADE POLICY REVIEW OF ZIMBABWE NOT FOR PUBLICATION BEFORE 1300 HRS GMT 2 DECEMBER November 1994

TRADE FACILITATION: Development Perspectives and Approaches of ASEAN in presented by

PROTOCOL ON THE PREFERENTIAL TARIFF SCHEME FOR TPS-OIC (PRETAS)

The IISD Global Subsidies Initiative Barriers to Reforming Fossil Fuel Subsidies: Lessons Learned from Asia

AGREEMENT ON RULES OF ORIGIN

EU s Rules of Origin. Screening Serbia, Explanatory Meeting, March 26-27, 2014 Brussels

INTERNATIONAL TRADE. To accompany the Georgia International Business Curriculum. CTAE Resource Network, Instructional Resources Office, 2010

Technical Report: SADC Trade Audit: Rules of Origin

CHAPTER ONE INITIAL PROVISIONS AND GENERAL DEFINITIONS. Section A General Definitions. 1. For purposes of this Agreement, unless otherwise specified:

TERMS OF REFERENCE DEVELOP A SADC TRADE DEVELOPMENT AND TRADE PROMOTION FRAMEWORK. November 2017

Submission to the Department of Foreign Affairs and Trade on the Feasibility Study into a possible Free Trade Agreement

What are the potential benefits and pitfalls of a free trade area in the Southern African region

epp european people s party

Mega-regionalism and Developing Countries

OF MULTILATERAL TRADE NEGOTIATIONS

For a Strong and Modern World Trading System

a) keeping money at home b) reducing unemployment c) enhancing national security d) equalizing cost and price e) protecting infant industry (X)

Investing in ASEAN asean

GLOBAL TRADE AND MARKETING

Preferential market access in recent years has been linked to such goals as limiting civil conflict, arms sales, job losses and worker exploitation

NATIONAL TRADE POLICY FOR BOTSWANA MINISTRY OF TRADE AND INDUSTRY

Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web

Understanding AEC : Implication for Thai Business MRS. SRIRAT RASTAPANA

Harnessing Regional Integration for Trade & Growth in Southern Africa How can regional integration be made to work for trade in goods & services?

Regional Integration. Ajitava Raychaudhuri Department of Economics Jadavpur University Kolkata. 9 May, 2016 Yangon

Cancún: Crisis or Catharsis? Bernard Hoekman, World Bank 1. September 20, 2003

International Trade Agreements Spring Semester 2013 January 16 to May 10, 2013

The End of Textiles Quotas: A case study of the impact on Bangladesh

International Trade: Lecture 5

Non-Tariff measures: Currently available evidence and future research agenda

OECD - ERIA Joint Regional Symposium Making Global Value Chains more inclusive for ASEAN

Declining Industries, Mechanisms of Structural Adjustment, and Trade Policy in Pacific Basin Economies. Hugh Patrick. Working Paper No.

FREE TRADE AGREEMENT BETWEEN THE GOVERNMENT OF THE REPUBLIC OF BULGARIA AND THE GOVERNMENT OF THE STATE OF ISRAEL

WTO Obligations and Trade Facilitation: The Role of Information and Communication Technologies

AID FOR TRADE CASE STORY: UK

Lessons from a Meta-evaluation of Aid for Trade

Marc Lee Economist Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives -- BC Office CANADA-U.S. CUSTOMS UNION: A CRITICAL ASSESSMENT

WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION

Dr. Biswajit Dhar Professor Centre for Economic Studies and Planning Jawaharlal Nehru University New Delhi

Trump and Globalization. Joseph E. Stiglitz AEA Meetings Philadelphia January 2018

Improving Trade Flow within EAC

Exchange of views on the Report by the High-Level Panel on Defining the Future of Trade, convened by WTO Director-General Pascal Lamy

Investment Climate Survey in Cambodia

Evaluation of an Appropriate Model for a SADC Customs Union Policy Brief

Voluntary Initiatives and the World Trade Organisation

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY. Shuji Uchikawa

Rose-Hulman Institute of Technology K. Christ GL458, International Trade & Globalization. Selected Week 9 Slides

CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web

Export Growth and Industrial Policy: Lessons from the East Asian Miracle Experience

AGREEMENT BETWEEN THE EFTA STATES AND TURKEY

RULES OF ORIGIN CHAPTER 10 A. OVERVIEW OF RULES 1. BACKGROUND OF RULES. Chapter 10: Rules of Origin

MEGA-REGIONAL FTAS AND CHINA

Preview. Chapter 9. The Cases for Free Trade. The Cases for Free Trade (cont.) The Political Economy of Trade Policy

Session 12. International Political Economy

International Political Economy

GEA and Trade Facilitation

STRATEGIC PLAN OF CUSTOMS DEVELOPMENT : INTEGRATION AND MODERNISATION OF ASEAN CUSTOMS FOR ESTABLISHMENT OF THE ASEAN ECONOMIC COMMUNITY BY

Euromalt position paper on the EU-ASEAN trade negotiations

Response to the EC consultation on the future direction of EU trade policy. 28 July 2010

Lecture 9a: Trade Agreements. Thibault FALLY C181 International Trade Spring 2018

Unified Industrial Development Strategy for the Arab States of the Gulf Cooperation Council (Revised Version)

China and WTO. Negotiation for WTO membership in a changing environment. Dr. Ma Xiaoye Academy for World Watch, Shanghai

PS 0500: International Trade. William Spaniel

Hinrich Foundation Sustainable Trade Index Country overview: Singapore

Bringing EU Trade Policy Up to Date 23 June 2015

MULTILATERAL TRADE NEGOTIATIONS THE URUGUAY ROUND

Introduction to Rules of Origin in the WTO

A Comparative Study of the Rubber Industry Supply Chain in Thailand Malaysia and Indonesia

Transcription:

Draft, January 22, 2001 Rationalization of Tariffs: Some Lessons From International Experience 1 Frank Flatters 2 A remarkable feature of international experience of trade policy reform is the similarities of lessons across countries that differ in many other important respects. This attests to the robustness of some basic economic forces related to the gains from trade and to the incentives facing different vested interests in the process of reform. The SADC countries are certainly not alone or unique in the problems and opportunities they face in integrating with the global economy through rationalization of tariffs and other trade policy reforms. The lessons discussed here are based on the author s experience in trade policy reform and in the design and implementation of tariff-setting mechanisms in a large number of countries in various parts of the world. The particular lessons discussed here are selected on the basis of their likely relevance to SADC Member States. They relate primarily to the benefits of tariff rationalization and to the process of achieving it successfully. Some of the lessons concern the costs of not doing so (i.e. the costs of protection), and others deal more with the process of achieving successful reform. The second part of the presentation discusses a few principal implications for tariff-setting bodies. 1. Lessons About Tariff Rationalization The principal beneficiaries of tariff rationalization are in the domestic economy The main beneficiaries of tariff rationalization in any SADC country are the consumers and producers of that country itself. Thus, the main focus of any tariff rationalization strategy should be on unilateral, selfinterested measures. There is seldom any benefit from trying to use access to any SADC member s own markets as a bargaining chip for others to liberalize. To delay unilateral integration measures as a threat to other countries hurts only the domestic economy. 1 Notes prepared for presentation to USAID-funded SADC Regional Workshop on Tariff Rationalization, Victoria Falls, Zimbabwe, January 22-24, 2001, organized by Zimbabwe Tariff Commission. Views expressed are those of the author alone and should not be attributed to USAID, the US Government or any other agency or individual. 2 Professor of Economics, Queen s University, Canada and consultant to USAID-funded SADC Trade Protocol Project <ff@thai.com>.

Vested interests play a major role in the process of tariff-setting This provides the answer to the puzzling question If protection is so bad, why do all countries engage in it? Interests opposed to integration include producers of protected goods and officials who enforce protective laws and collect taxes and other income from them. Producers and workers in industries and activities that have not developed as a result of poor tariff structures, and workers and users of such goods seldom have a direct voice in decisions about protection. Protection hurts labor-intensive downstream industries Protection on inputs and raw materials provides negative protection to users of these protected goods. Protection of upstream petrochemicals, plastic raw materials and steel in Thailand and Indonesia has imposed high costs on labor-intensive downstream industries; the same thing is now beginning to happen in Vietnam. In the highly protected Indonesian economy of the early 1980s, it was found that the cost of each job created by protection of capital intensive import substitution industries was two to four jobs which were lost in efficient labor-intensive industries. Protection hurts exporters Protection makes it more difficult for exporters to compete because of its direct effects on the cost of raw materials and intermediate inputs, and because of its indirect effects on the cost of labor and the exchange rate. Earning foreign exchange from competitive exports is far more effective than earning it through protection of non-competitive import substituting industries. In Indonesia it was found that investment in competitive export industries earned four times as much foreign exchange as the same investment in high cost import substitution. Insulating exporters from the costs of protection through EPZs, duty drawbacks and special exemptions is a useful, but only partial and temporary solution, with unfortunate negative long-term effects on the development of SMEs and supporting industries. Malaysia has been among the most successful users of special schemes for exporters and yet has failed to develop integrated manufacturing sectors built on successful export activities. NTBs are costly and have many unintended side effects In the early stages of a country s international economic integration, non-tariff barriers to imports and exports (NTBs) are often the most common and pernicious form of protection. NTBs breed arbitrariness and non-transparency. Their administration and compliance 2

costs are high, especially after taking account of the processes of negotiation over the setting and allocation of importing rights. They do not generate government revenues (although they might create substantial hidden incomes for some officials). For all of these reasons they are one of the primary sources of corruption in trade policy regimes. The varieties and types of NTBs are almost endless. Rules of origin are an especially pernicious and often unrecognized form of NTB that is part of all preferential regional trade arrangements, including SADC. The incentive effects of such measures are often very large but are seldom, if ever recognized or quantified. Rules are better than discretion in programs to remove NTBs and reduce tariffs Clear rules for the process of NTB removal eliminate uncertainty and are less likely to create opportunities for continuation of rent-seeking. For example, if it necessary to provide temporary additional tariff protection to compensate for loss of NTB protection, it is preferable to use a simple rule such as: all sectors with tariff protection above x percent will get no additional tariff protection; those with tariffs below x percent will get a temporary import tariff surcharge of y percent, which will be phased down to one-half of y after one year and zero after two years. Indonesia made the mistake of trying to compensate on a case-by-case basis for losses of NTB protection, on the basis of each industry s need. This led to large and unnecessary delays in reform, and diverted entrepreneurial energies from increasing the competitiveness of their business practices to lobbying officials for protection. The same lesson applies to rules for tariff reduction rather than made-to-measure reductions. Complex tariff structures breed corruption Complex tariff schedules (especially when combined with high average rates) increase both the discretionary authority of customs administrators and the benefits from importers from manipulation of import classifications. They also provide perverse economic incentives to investors. Sources of costly and unnecessary complexity include: wide ranges of tariff rates; complex HS classification schemes; classification of imports for tariff rate or exemption purposes based on end users, end uses, etc. While, in a perverse way, corruption might achieve a certain degree of de facto rationalization in a highly protected environment, it is a) very costly (illustrated by the experience of port and customs reform in Indonesia), and b) a major obstacle to measures aimed at reducing protection and increasing transparency. Increasing protection does not stop smuggling Protection is a subsidy to smugglers. Thus increases in protection increase the incentive to smuggle. 3

Replacing NTBs with tariffs and lowering tariffs to reasonable levels reduces smuggling, puts competitive pressure on producers, helps users of imported goods, and enhances state revenues. Partial trade liberalization for particular users or uses can have perverse and unintended effects The governments of Thailand and Laos have made agreements to relax quotas and tariffs on a selective basis on certain Lao agricultural products to be used in Thai processing industries. Contrary to what would have been the effect of general liberalization of Lao- Thai trade in these products, there have been no benefits to Lao farmers or Thai food consumers. All of the rents from this special free trade arrangement have accrued to large Thai food processing producers and their well-connected agents in Laos. Regional trade liberalization and associated rules of origin can have a wide range of similar perverse and unintended effects. Anti-dumping is a dangerous game Vested interests who are opposed to increased integration often argue that anti-dumping procedures are necessary in order to protect liberalized domestic industry from unfair foreign competition. In developing country markets, almost all claims of dumping are actually statements about a firm s inability to compete rather than about the behavior of an external competitor. Furthermore, in practice, the existence of dumping is costly and almost impossible to determine. This is in large part because dumping is very rare in international markets, and especially in very small markets such as SADC. Therefore anti-dumping procedures should not be developed unless to clarify the difficulty and unlikelihood of a petitioner s succeeding with a claim. At the same time, a small country might be well advised to develop the expertise and resources to help deal with anti-dumping charges levied on its own producers by foreign countries. This would include mobilizing the support of international investors engaging in local production for export. 2. Some Implications for Tariff Boards Recognize and understand the national interest in tariff rationalization Rationalization of tariffs is an essential element in a strategy to promote sustainable and equitable development. It is open economies that have been the most successful in taking advantage of the opportunities provided by globalization, and this is especially true among developing countries. Tariff rationalization is especially important in promoting the competitiveness of domestic industries. 4

Recognition of the national interest in tariff reform is critical in order to avoid the folly of entering multilateral, regional and bilateral trade negotiations with the false view of tariff reductions as concessions to other countries. Do not confuse the national interest with the exaggerated pleas of narrow vested interests Consideration of the effects of tariff changes on all relevant national stakeholders, including consumers and industrial users of protected goods is necessary to make informed tariff rationalization decisions. Aim for simplicity and transparency in the design and implementation of tariff reform Keep tariff schedules simple and rates reasonable. Do not allow exceptions based on end uses or users. Eliminate deep-seated sources of corruption in import administration. Simplicity and transparency of rules will help. But more might be necessary. Indonesia removed its customs service from almost all aspects of import administration for 10 years in order to reduce the costs of international trade. Rely on general rules and clear timetables for tariff and more general trade policy reform Make rules applicable to all sectors and all activities. Otherwise the system will be overwhelmed by pleas for special treatment, and reform will be frustrated Plan for the obsolescence of all tariff boards When a simple and uniform tariff structure has been achieved, there should be no need for a tariff board. Petitioners for special protection should be directed to a telephone number, a web site or an office door with a very simple message: No. 5