What Should Lawyers Know about Economics

Similar documents
Foundations of the Economic Approach to Law. Edited by AVERY WIENER KATZ

The George Washington University Department of Economics

University of Vermont Department of Economics Course Outline

Syllabus for INSTITUTIONAL ECONOMICS

Understand the basic concepts of European Union Law and differentiate the EU legal order from international and national legal orders.

Law and Economics. The 1 st Meeting Elective in Double Major NSD, Peking University Fall 2010 Instructor: Zhaofeng Xue

: Organizational Economics (CentER) Fall Jens Prüfer Office: K 311,

THE ECONOMICS OF PROPERTY RIGHTS

I assume familiarity with multivariate calculus and intermediate microeconomics.

Book Review [Law's Order: What Economics Has to Do with Law and Why It Matters]

The Coase Theorem Volume I

List of Nobel Memorial Prize laureates in Economics

Public Procurement. Stéphane Saussier Sorbonne Business School IAE de Paris Class 2

University of Zurich Faculty of Law Fall Semester 2012

GLOBAL ANTITRUST INSTITUTE ECONOMICS INSTITUTE FOR COMPETITION ENFORCEMENT OFFICIALS

New institutional economic theories of non-profits and cooperatives: a critique from an evolutionary perspective

GETTYSBURG COLLEGE DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS. ECON 308 Fall 2009 M 01:10-03:40 PM Glatfelter 104

Thinkwell s Homeschool Microeconomics Course Lesson Plan: 31 weeks

On the Irrelevance of Formal General Equilibrium Analysis

May 18, Coase s Education in the Early Years ( )

Invited Reaction Putting Theories of the Firm in Their Place: A Supplemental Digest of the New Institutional Economics

UNTIL RECENTLY, LAW confined the use of economics to antitrust law, regulated industries, Introduction to Law and Economics

OLIVER E. WILLIAMSON University of California, Berkeley

Economic Models of Law

Copyright 2012 Carolina Academic Press, LLC. All rights reserved. FOUNDATIONS OF THE ECONOMIC APPROACH TO LAW

BOUNDED RATIONALITY, THE DOCTRINE OF IMPRACTICABILITY, AND THE GOVERNANCE OF RELATIONAL CONTRACTS

Part 1. Economic Theory and the Economics Profession

WHEN IS THE PREPONDERANCE OF THE EVIDENCE STANDARD OPTIMAL?

Regulation and Regulatory Environment: Case Study of Bhutan

Thinkwell s Homeschool Economics Course Lesson Plan: 36 weeks

Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission.

Curriculum Vitae. A. Mitchell Polinsky

Introduction to Economics

Syllabus for LS 140 Property and Liberty Spring, 2007 Professor Brown

EFFICIENCY OF COMPARATIVE NEGLIGENCE : A GAME THEORETIC ANALYSIS

Basic Microeconomics

University of Georgia Department of Public Administration and Policy DPAP 8670: Public Policy Analysis I Fall 2017 COURSE SYLLABUS

Economics 499 Undergraduate Seminar in Economics: Law & Economics. Instructor: Professor John Garen Fall 2002

Office hours: Tues., 4:30-5:30 p.m.; Thurs., 3:30-4:30 p.m., 6:00-7:00 p.m.; or by appointment. Public Economics

BOSTON UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF LAW

Political Science 200A Week 8. Social Dilemmas

Introduction: Law & The New Institutional Economics

Rethinking the Theory of Legal Rights

Understanding "The Problem of Social Cost"

ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF LAW: AN INQUIRY OF ITS UNDERLYING LOGIC *

PAPER No. : Basic Microeconomics MODULE No. : 1, Introduction of Microeconomics

A Course in Classical Liberal Thought

Debating Law s Irrelevance: Legal Scholarship and the Coase Theorem in the 1960s

Econ 522 Review 3: Tort Law, Criminal Law, and the Legal Process

ECONOMICS AND COMPARATIVE POLITICS FORM IV

CHICAGO PRICE THEORY AND CHICAGO LAW AND ECONOMICS: ISSUES ON THE ROAD TO A HISTORY OF CHICAGO PRICE THEORY * Steven G. Medema ** September 2008

The Coase theorem: coherent, logical, and not disproved

Robert Ackerman Office Hours: 2:00-3:00PM T/Th Office: PA202 October 21, Economics 101

ARE DISAGREEMENTS AMONG MALE AND FEMALE ECONOMISTS MARGINAL AT BEST?: A SURVEY OF AEA MEMBERS AND THEIR VIEWS ON ECONOMICS AND ECONOMIC POLICY

Formal Political Theory II: Applications

Introduction to New Institutional Economics: A Report Card

Criminal Law. Summer Professor Sandra Guerra Thompson BLB, office home office

(Revised April 2018)

Book Review (reviewing Lawrence F. Ebb, Regulation and Protection of International Business: Cases, Comments and Materials (1964))

The Interdisciplinary Studies Program (IDS): GLOBAL STUDIES Intro Courses DRAFT COMMENTS

Bureaucracy in America

CURRICULUM VITAE. Jerry M. Evensky. ADDRESS: Office:

A Theory of Status Organizations

Cases and Materials on Remedies

ECO 171S: Hayek and the Austrian Tradition Syllabus

TAKING PRIVATE ORDERING SERIOUSLY

Economic Analysis of Contract Law After Three Decades: Success or Failure? INTRODUCTION

The University of Chicago Law Review VOLUME 46 NUMBER 2 WINTER 1979

Mechanism design: how to implement social goals

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at

Lomonosov Moscow State University (Moscow, Russia)

A NOTE ON MONITORING COSTS AND VOTER FRAUD

KEITH J. CROCKER. Smeal College of Business The Pennsylvania State University University Park PA 16802

LAW AND ECONOMICS RESEARCH PAPER SERIES

Syllabus for Criminal Law, Spring Professor Sandra Guerra Thompson BLB, office

Agendas and Strategic Voting

TWO CULTURE PROBLEMS IN LAW AND ECONOMICS

Expert Mining and Required Disclosure: Appendices

FAITH & ECONOMICS NUMBER 46 FALL Economics of Religion: Debating the Costs and Benefits of a New Field 1 Laurence R.

PSC/PPA 486. Political Economy of Property Rights

Foreword to Reviews (Books on the Law of Contracts)

Steven R. Beckman 6/17/

Does Uncertainty Call for Comparative Negligence?

UNIVERSITY OF GUELPH Department of Food, Agricultural and Resource Economics COURSE OUTLINE FARE 6100 The Methodologies of Economics Winter Semester,

Regulation, Public Service Provision and Contracting

DATE: 1/27/2017. KNW 3399 Democracy, Institutions and Development: Economic and Political Issues

Regulatory Governance of Network Industries: Experience and Prospects

Issues in Law and Economics

The Art of Law and Economics: An Autobiographical Essay

Henry Manne and the Market Measure of Intellectual Influence

The Negligence-Opportunism Tradeoff in Contract Law

The Efficiency and the Efficacy of Title VII

Bachelor of Social Sciences (Honours)

HARVARD NEGATIVE-EXPECTED-VALUE SUITS. Lucian A. Bebchuk and Alon Klement. Discussion Paper No /2009. Harvard Law School Cambridge, MA 02138

Course Title. Professor. Contact Information

CISG Exclusion and Legal Efficiency. Lisa Spagnolo. Wolters Kluwer Law & Business

HENRY G. MANNE PROGRAM IN LAW & ECONOMICS STUDIES

CHAPTER 19 MARKET SYSTEMS AND NORMATIVE CLAIMS Microeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.), 2 nd Edition

Economic Sociology I Fall Kenneth Boulding, The Role of Mathematics in Economics, JPE, 56 (3) 1948: 199

As Joseph Stiglitz sees matters, the euro suffers from a fatal. Book Review. The Euro: How a Common Currency. Journal of FALL 2017

Transcription:

Texas A&M University School of Law Texas A&M Law Scholarship Faculty Scholarship 1998 What Should Lawyers Know about Economics Robert Whaples Andrew P. Morriss Texas A&M University School of Law, amorriss@law.tamu.edu John C. Moorhouse Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.tamu.edu/facscholar Part of the Law Commons Recommended Citation Robert Whaples, Andrew P. Morriss & John C. Moorhouse, What Should Lawyers Know about Economics, 48 J. Legal Educ. 120 (1998). Available at: https://scholarship.law.tamu.edu/facscholar/136 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by Texas A&M Law Scholarship. It has been accepted for inclusion in Faculty Scholarship by an authorized administrator of Texas A&M Law Scholarship. For more information, please contact sphillips64@law.tamu.edu.

What Should Lawyers Know About Economics? Robert Whaples, Andrew P. Morriss, and John C. Moorhouse Law and Economics is now part of the curriculum at many American law schools; the current AALS directory lists 159 persons teaching at least one course in the area. Because law schools inexplicably do not generally require a background in economics, such courses usually must teach some principles of economic analysis before applying those principles to legal questions. We wondered what law-and-economics scholars and economists thought lawyers should know about economics' (as opposed to what they should know about the economic analysis of law). The results are important beyond the circle of law-and-economics scholars. Teachers and students of torts, property, and contracts felt the impact of the first wave of law-and-economics scholarship, but every area of law from admiralty to procedure is increasingly subject to economic reasoning. Even those legal educators and lawyers who swore off economics after an encounter with an undergraduate principles course are confronting economic reasoning in scholarly work and judicial opinions. Understanding that reasoning requires some familiarity with economics. The optimal number of economics courses may always be one more (at least in our opinions), but those whose consumption of economics education has somehow fallen short may reasonably substitute the works economists-and particularly economists who think about law-think are important for lawyers. To find out what law-and-economics scholars and economists think lawyers should know about economics, we conducted surveys of random samples of members of the American Law and Economics Association and the American Economic Association. 2 We posed two questions to both groups: At Wake Forest University, Robert Whaples is Associate Professor of Economics, and John C. Moorhouse is Professor of Economics. Andrew P. Morriss is Associate Professor of Law and Associate Professor of Economics at Case Western Reserve University. 1. Perhaps our next project will be to determine what lawyers think law-and-economics scholars should know about law. 2. Between April and August 1996 we sent 402 surveys to members of the ALEA and 199 surveys to members of the ABA. Fourteen of the ALEA surveys and eight of the AEA surveys were returned as undeliverable. We received 63 usable responses from ALEA members (a 16.2% response rate) and 70 from AEA members (a 36.6% response rate). ALEA members were also asked 42 questions on a number of policy issues and factual propositions, something which may explain their lower response rate. Those results appear in Andrew Morriss et al., Where Is There Consensus in the Field of Law and Economics? (unpublished manuscript on file with authors). Journal of Legal Education, Volume 48, Number 1 (March 1998)

What Should Lawyers Know About Economics? What do you think are the five most important economic concepts law students ought to learn in a law-and-economics course? Law-and-economics courses sometimes include economics articles in their reading lists. If you could choose up to five articles for such a course, what would they be? Tables 1 and 2 summarize the answers. 3 Opportunity cost / diminishing returns Externalities / Coase Theorem Marginal analysis Demand & supply / market equilibrium Economic efficiency / Pareto optimality Incentives matters Comparative advantage Public choice theory Economics of property rights Transactions costs Present value / discounting Utility theory / social welfare Market structure / monopoly Uncertainty / risk Competition Optimization / individual rationality Government's impact Game theory concepts Principal-agent theory Antitrust Elasticity Imperfect information Market failure Consumer & producer surplus Public goods Moral hazard & adverse selection Table 1: Concepts Mentioned Percent Mentioning ALEA 57.1 51.6 46.8 46.8 28.6 11.1 3.2 13.5 4.0 15.1 14.3 9.5 3.2 9.5 11.9 0.0 3.2 1.6 As Table 1 shows, four concepts ranked well ahead of the others: opportunity cost, the Coase theorem, marginal analysis, and market equilibrium. Economic efficiency/pareto optimality also ranked fairly high among the ALEA economists, although not so high among members of the AEA. Four of these five concepts are at the heart of the microeconomic core, and the fifth, the Coase Theorem, is the key to much of law and economics generally. Missing from the top tier are concepts at the center of modern microeconomics such as principal-agent theory and property rights economics. Macroeconomic topics are also noticeably absent. This suggests that our respondents (correctly, in our opinion) are satisfied with exposing law students to an abbreviated introductory microeconomics course rather than familiarizing them with recent cutting-edge law-and-economics scholarship. 3. Because we asked open-ended questions, we used somejudgment in grouping responses. For example, "opportunity cost" includes mention of diminishing marginal utility and scarcity. For reasons of space, we listed only concepts and materials identified by at least two respondents; half-point scores reflect a few respondents' listing two concepts as equally important.

Journal of Legal Education Table 2: Articles Recommended Percent Mentioning R. H. Coase, The Problem of Social Cost, 3J.L. & ECON. 1 (1960)... *Guido Calabresi & A. Douglas Melamed, Property Rules, Liability Rules 57.9 and Inalienability: One View of the Cathedra4 85 HAv. L. REv. 1089 (1972)... 11.3 Ronald H. Coase, The Nature of the Firm, 4 ECONOMIcA 386 (1937)... 8.3 Gary Becker, Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach, 76J. POL. ECON. 169 (1968)... 6.0 Benjamin Klein, Robert G. Crawford & Armen A. Alchian, Vertical Integration, Appropriable Rents, and the Competitive Contracting Process, 21J.L. & ECON. 297 (1978)... 5.6 *Harold Demsetz, Toward a Theory of Property Rights, 57 AM. ECON. REv. 347 (1967)... 5.3 Milton Friedman, The Methodology of Positive Economics, in ESSAYS IN Posrriw ECONOMICS 3 (1953)... 4.5 Armen A. Alchian & Harold Demsetz, Production, Information Costs, and Economic Organization, 62 AM. ECON. REv. 777 (1972)... 4.5 George A. Akerlof, The Market for "Lemons": Qualitative Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism, 84 Q.J. ECON. 488 (1970)... 4.5 GeorgeJ. Stigler, The Theory of Economic Regulation, 2 BELLJ. ECON. & M GMr. Sci. 3 (1971)... 3.8 Richard A. Posner, ECONOMIC ANALSIS OF LAw (1972, 5th ed. 1998)... 3.8 *Garret Hardin, The Tragedy of the Commons, 162 SCIENCE 1243 (1968)... 3.4 Richard A. Posner & Andrew M. Rosenfield, Impossibility and Related Doctrines in Contract Law: An Economic Analysis, 6J. LEGAL STUD. 83 (1977)... 3.0 Paul H. Rubin, Why Is the Common Law Efficient? 6J. LEGAL STUD. 51 (1977)... 3.0 *Steven Shavell, Strict Liability Versus Negligence, 9 J. LEGAL STUD. 1 (1980)... 3.0 tr. A. Radford, The Economic Organization of a P.O. W. Camp, 12 ECONOMICA 189 (1945)... 2.3 tgary Becker, THE ECONOMICS OF DISCRIMINATION (1957, 2d ed. 1971)... 2.3 *GeorgeJ. Stigler, The Economics of Information, 69J. POL. ECON. 213 (1961)... 2.3 *Oliver E. Williamson, Transaction-Cost Economics: The Governance of Contractual Relations, 22J.L. & ECON. 233 (1979)... *Michael C. Jensen & William H. Meckling, Theory of the Firm: 2.3 Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs and Ownership Structure, 3J. FIN. ECO N. 305 (1976)...... 1.9 trichard A. Posner, A Theory of Negligence, 1J. LEGA. STUD. 29 (1972)... 1.5 tjohn S. McGee, Predatory Price Cutting: The Standard Oil (N.J.) Case, 1J.L. & EcoN. 137 (1958)... 1.5 tharold Demsetz, Indushy Structure, Market Rivalry, and Public Policy, 16J.L. & ECON. 1 (1973)... 1.5 tstephen N. S. Cheung, Transaction Costs, Risk Aversion, and the Choice of Contractual Arrangements, 12J.L. & ECON. 23 (1969)... 1.5 *Robert Cooter, The Cost of Coase, 11J. LEGAL STUD. 1 (1982)... 1.5 *CarlJ. Dahlman, The Problem of Externality, 22J.L. & ECON. 141 (1979)... 1.5 *Friedrich von Hayek, Competition as Discovery Procedure, in F. A. Hayek, ed., NEw STUDIES IN PHILOSOPHY, PoLmcs, ECONOMICS, AND THE HIsToRY OF IDEAS 179 (1978)... *William M. Landes & Richard A. Posner, THE ECONOMIC STRUCTURE OF 1.5 TORT LAW (1987)... *Franco Modigliani & Merton H. Miller, The Cost of Capita Corporation 1.5 Finance and the Theory of Investment, 48 A. ECON. REv. 261 (1958)... 1.5 *Steven Shavell, ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF ACCIDENT LAw (1987)... 1.5 * mentioned only by ALEA respondents t mentioned only by AEA respondents

What Should Lawyers Know About Economics? A similar focus is apparent in the suggested readings of Table 2. Respondents in both groups focus heavily on "classic" texts and articles: all but five of the thirty works mentioned were published before 1980. 4 Not surprisingly, the respondents also concentrate heavily on articles from the Journal of Law and Economics (7 articles receiving 95.5 mentions) and the Journal of Legal Studies (5 articles receiving 16 mentions). Of articles not in law-and-economicsjournals, only one (Calabresi & Melamed) is from a law journal; the others are from economics journals (10 articles receiving 53.5 mentions) or books (6 books receiving 20 mentions). Since we had asked for "economics" articles a law student should read, the absence of law reviews may seem unsurprising. But there are plenty of articles published in law reviews that contain just as much economics (and certainly as much law and economics) as material published elsewhere. Our results suggest that neither law-and-economics scholars nor economists think of law review materials as "economics" articles. For the most part, the readings suggested are relatively nontechnical articles comprehensible to most law students; only a few, such as Akerlof's, might tax most students' abilities. The desire to choose material within the competence of law students may have led to the selection of older articlesarticles written before the mathematization of economics. The most striking response, although not unexpected, was the top ranking-by a wide margin-of Ronald Coase's "The Problem of Social Cost." Clearly this is the key element in the law-and-economics syllabus. More than three-fourths of the respondents gave it a mention; only 15 percent mentioned the second-most-mentioned article. Another Coase article, "The Nature of the Firm," ranked third. The major difference between the two groups surveyed was in their treatment of the Calabresi & Melamed article. Many ALEA members listed it, but the AEA members did not mention it at all. Apparently law-and-economics scholars read law reviews, but economists outside the field do not Table 3: Authors Recommended More than 10 Times Percent Mentioning Ronald Coase 75.9 Richard Posner 19.5 Harold Demsetz 14.3 Armen Alchian 13.2 *Guido Calabresi 12.8 *A. Douglas Melamed 11.3 George Stigler 10.5 tgary Becker 8.3 * mentioned only by ALEA respondents t mentioned only by AEA respondents 4. The AEA and ALEA responses to this question were generally similar, with two exceptions noted below, and so Table 2 combines the results. 5. Another difference lies in the works that relatively few respondents cited: with one exception, every work mentioned by fewer than five persons received mention from members of only one of the two groups.

Journal of Legal Education Another way of interpreting our results is to look for authors mentioned repeatedly. Certainly many law-and-economics scholars have published widely, and some authors' writings lack an obvious focal point like "The Problem of Social Cost." Almost anything by Richard Posner, for example, would be relevant. Table 3 lists authors mentioned ten or more times. Not surprisingly, Coase's name tops the list, although large numbers of respondents mentioned Armen Achian, Gary Becker, Guido Calabresi, Harold Demsetz, Richard Posner, and George Stigler. Teachers might wish to include in their syllabi works by frequently mentioned authors as representative of the field. Teachers can use the suggested articles to introduce students to the concepts identified in Table 1. The non-coase readings come from a variety of areas, from torts to property rights to finance. The wide range of subject areas suggests materials that could be used in substantive courses to provide a lawand-economics perspective, particularly for students who have mastered basic economic principles either in their undergraduate course work or in a lawand-economics course. There are.two major textbooks (Cooter & Ulen 6 and Posner 7 ) and two casebooks for law-and-economics courses (Barnes & Stout 8 and Goetz 9 ). In addition there are some shorter works that provide an introduction to law and economics (Harrison, 10 Malloy," and Polinsky1 2 ). All cover the five concepts that our respondents identified as most important, as well as some additional topics. Cooter & Ulen provide the most thorough introduction to economic reasoning and come closest to replicating the experience of an introductory microeconomics course by more formal presentation. Any of the shorter works could also serve as back-up reading for lectures on these concepts. The textbook format allows for greater topical coverage but at the expense of primary sources. The articles suggested by our respondents offer a source of supplemental readings. The Barnes & Stout casebook includes significant excerpts from Coase; the Goetz casebook does not. If you wish to take our respondents' collective advice, you might structure your law-and-economics course to include a brief overview of basic microeconomic concepts, discussion of Coase's "The Problem of Social Cost," discussion of Calabresi & Melamed's "Cathedral" article, and selections from one or more of the frequently mentioned writers: Alchian, Becker, Demsetz, Posner, and Stigler. 6. Robert Cooter & Thomas Ulen, Law and Economics, 2d ed. (Reading, Mass., 1997). 7. Richard A. Posner, Economic Analysis of Law, 5th ed. (NewYork, 1998). 8. David W. Barnes & Lynn A. Stout, Cases and Materials on Law and Economics (St. Paul, 1992). This book is also available as a series of short paperbacks focused on individual subjects for use as supplemental material. 9. CharlesJ. Goetz, Cases and Materials on Law and Economics (St. Paul, 1984). 10. Jeffrey L Harrison, Law and Economics in a Nutshell (St. Paul, 1995). 11. Robin Paul Malloy, Law and Economics: A Comparative Approach to Theory and Practice (St. Paul, 1990). 12. A. Mitchell Polinsky, An Introduction to Law and Economics, 2d ed. (Boston, 1989).