MATH 1340 Mathematics & Politics

Similar documents
Chapter 4 The Mathematics of Apportionment

The Constitution directs Congress to reapportion seats in the House

In the next few lectures, we consider the problem of dividing indivisible things (say, seats in a legislature) among players (say, states) in

Rounding decimals or fractions to whole numbers might seem to be one of the most boring subjects ever.

Section Apportionment Methods. Copyright 2013, 2010, 2007, Pearson, Education, Inc.

Chapter 4 The Mathematics of Apportionment

Fair Division in Theory and Practice

Note: Article I, section 2, of the Constitution was modified by section 2 of the 14th amendment.

Math of Election APPORTIONMENT

MATH 1340 Mathematics & Politics

A small country consists of four states. There are 100 seats in the legislature. The populations are: A: 44,800 B: 52,200 C: 49,200 D: 53,800

Chapter Four: The Mathematics of Apportionment

MATH 1340 Mathematics & Politics

Lesson 2.3. Apportionment Models

Proportional (Mis)representation: The Mathematics of Apportionment

Name Chapter 14 Apportionment. 1. What was the Great Compromise in 1787? Populations of 15 states in 1790 as in your book on page 506:

Apportionment Problems

The Mathematics of Apportionment

The Mathematics of Apportionment

n(n 1) 2 C = total population total number of seats amount of increase original amount

The Congressional Apportionment Problem Based on the Census : Basic Divisor Methods

Presidential Election Democrat Grover Cleveland versus Benjamin Harrison. ************************************ Difference of 100,456

Lesson 2.4 More Apportionment Models and Paradoxes

STUDY GUIDE FOR TEST 2

Practice TEST: Chapter 14

Apportionment. Seven Roads to Fairness. NCTM Regional Conference. November 13, 2014 Richmond, VA. William L. Bowdish

Chapter 15 Section 4 - Slide 1

Chapter 12: The Math of Democracy 12B,C: Voting Power and Apportionment - SOLUTIONS

MATH 1340 Mathematics & Politics

Apportionment Problems

MATH 1340 Mathematics & Politics

The Mathematics of Apportionment

12B,C: Voting Power and Apportionment

PROPORTIONAL ALLOCATION IN INTEGERS

Voting and Apportionment(Due by Nov. 25)

A comparison between the methods of apportionment using power indices: the case of the U.S. presidential election

The 2000 U.S. presidential election was a

Fair Division in Theory and Practice

Thema Working Paper n Université de Cergy Pontoise, France

CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web

Hamilton s Method. By: Lauren, Lane, Devonte, Sarah, Hannah A, & Katie H

The House of Representatives Apportionment Formula: An Analysis of Proposals for Change and Their Impact on States

Trump s victory like Harrison, not Hayes and Bush

A New Method for Congressional Apportionment (Congress/representation/fair division/u.s. Constitution) M. L. BALINSKI AND H. P.

Voting and Apportionment(Due with Final Exam)

Social choice theory

AP US Government & Politics Summer Assignment 2017

HOW TO APPORTION FAIRLY

Fairness Criteria. Review: Election Methods

CHAPTER 9: Political Parties

MATH4999 Capstone Projects in Mathematics and Economics Topic 3 Voting methods and social choice theory

CRS Report for Congress

Satisfaction Approval Voting

The U.S. Constitution: Who, What, Where, When, Why & How

Guide to 2011 Redistricting

Chapter 13: The Presidency Section 5

10/23/2012. Chapter 13: The Presidency Section 5

Mathematics and Social Choice Theory. Topic 4 Voting methods with more than 2 alternatives. 4.1 Social choice procedures

UNITED STATES DEPARTMENT OF COMMERCE et al. v. MONTANA et al. appeal from the united states district court for the district of montana

Social welfare functions

Regulating Elections: Districts /252 Fall 2008

As Introduced. 132nd General Assembly Regular Session S. J. R. No A J O I N T R E S O L U T I O N

Regulating Elections: Districts /252 Fall 2012

The U.S. Constitution. Ch. 2.4 Ch. 3

Constitutional Convention

Should Politicians Choose Their Voters? League of Women Voters of MI Education Fund

LAST WORDS ON THE APPORTIONMENT PROBLEM

Class Period THE US CONSTITUTION. 2. Compare Article I with Article II. Which article is longer and more detailed? WHY do you suppose it s longer?

Six Big Ideas in the Constitution

Math116Chap1VotingPart2.notebook January 12, Part II. Other Methods of Voting and Other "Fairness Criteria"

Find the winner of the election using majority rule given the results below: Choices (ABC) (ACB) (BAC) (BCA) (CAB) (CBA) Number of Votes

Louis M. Edwards Mathematics Super Bowl Valencia Community College -- April 30, 2004

A New Method of the Single Transferable Vote and its Axiomatic Justification

It s time for more politicians

Measuring the Compliance, Proportionality, and Broadness of a Seat Allocation Method

Redistricting in Michigan

CONGRESSIONAL APPORTIONMENT-PAST, PRESENT, AND FUTURE

This situation where each voter is not equal in the number of votes they control is called:

THE GHOSTS OF CENSUS PAST AND THEIR RELEVANCE FOR 2020

Fall 2016 COP 3223H Program #5: Election Season Nears an End Due date: Please consult WebCourses for your section

Constitution Quest PART I - THE OVERALL STRUCTURE OF THE CONSTITUTION

Topic 4 Reasons For a

CH.10: POLITICAL PARTIES

at New York University School of Law A 50 state guide to redistricting

Why Was Congress Created?

Homework 4 solutions

Who Represents Illegal Aliens?

Due Date: Monday, August 20 th, 2018 (first day of school)

Elections in Haiti October 25 General Elections

The United States Constitution & The Illinois Constitution. Study Guide

The Electoral College

(132nd General Assembly) (Substitute Senate Joint Resolution Number 5) A JOINT RESOLUTION

The mathematics of voting, power, and sharing Part 1

'Wave riding' or 'Owning the issue': How do candidates determine campaign agendas?

Station 1: Analyze the graphic titled The People s House and answer the questions that follow.

THE CONSTITUTION. of the STUDENT ASSEMBLY. of the. COLLEGE OF WILLIAM AND MARY IN VIRGINIA Ratified January

The Mathematics of Voting

VIRGINIA DEMOCRATIC PARTY PLAN 1

Recent Court Decisions about the Census, Adjusting for Census Undercount and the Use of Census Data to Apportion Congress and the Electoral College

Essential Question Section 1: The Colonial Period Section 2: Uniting for Independence Section 3: The Articles of Confederation Section 4: The

Transcription:

MATH 1340 Mathematics & Politics Lecture 13 July 9, 2015 Slides prepared by Iian Smythe for MATH 1340, Summer 2015, at Cornell University 1

Apportionment A survey 2

All legislative Powers herein granted shall be vested in a Congress of the United States, which shall consist of a Senate and House of Representatives. Article 1, Section 1, The Constitution of the United States of America The House of Representatives shall be composed of Members chosen every second Year by the People of the several States Representatives and direct Taxes shall be apportioned among the several States which may be included within this Union, according to their respective Numbers, which shall be determined by adding to the whole Number of free Persons, including those bound to Service for a Term of Years*, and excluding Indians not taxed, three fifths of all other Persons*. The actual Enumeration shall be made within three Years after the first Meeting of the Congress of the United States, and within every subsequent Term of ten Years, in such Manner as they shall by Law direct. The Number of Representatives shall not exceed one for every thirty Thousand, but each State shall have at Least one Representative Article 1, Section 2, The Constitution of the United States of America *removed by Section 2 of 14th Amendment, 1868 3

The Apportionment Problem The US Constitution dictates the members (or seats) of the House of Representatives be distributed to the states according to their respective Numbers, and this carried out every 10 years (upon tallying of the US Census). Since 1959 there have been 50 states in US, and while not mandated by the Constitution, the number of House seats has been fixed at 435 since the 1920s. Problem: How do we distribute these 435 representatives amongst the 50 sates according to their respective Numbers? 4

The Apportionment Problem (cont d) At first, there seems to be an obvious answer: For instance: According to the 2010 US Census, there are 308,143,815 people (citizens and non-citizens) in the 50 US states, and 19,378,102 in the state of New York. New York has a fraction of 19,378,102/308,143,815, or approximately 6.289%, of the US population, so they should get 6.289% of the 435 representatives, which is approximately 27.4. But 27.4 is not a whole number, and we can t split House seats. If we round down to 27, New Yorkers will be slightly underrepresented in Congress. If we round up to 28, they will be slightly overrepresented. 5

The Apportionment Problem (cont d) It gets worse. If we try and round the ideal amount of representatives for each state in the usual way, the total number of representatives will not add up to 435 (it adds up to 431 with 2010 data). If we try a generous approach and round every state up, we get 462 representatives. If we decided that 462 is a reasonable total, we would have to start over again with new ideal amounts, and have the possibility of an ever increasing total number. 6

The Apportionment Problem (cont d) Ideally, each congressional district should have a population of 308,143,815/435, or about 708,377. For some states, the stakes of congressional representation are very high: Montana has a population of 989,415, or 0.321% of the total US population. Montana s ideal representation is 0.321% of 435, or about 1.4, but with only 1 representative, they d have much less representation in Congress than the ideal district, and with 2 representatives, they d have much more. 7

The Electoral College This apportionment also affects the method by which the US elects its President: Each state is assigned electors in the Electoral College equal to the total number of representatives and senators they have in Congress (i.e., number of House seats + 2), with DC getting the same as the smallest state (3). (Roughly) The plurality winner of the Presidential election in each state determines who the electors of the state will vote for (as a block), and the plurality winner of the electors votes becomes the President. 8

Current (2010 Census) apportionment From wikipedia 9

Apportionment problems In general, an apportionment problem occurs when we wish to distribute a collection of identical, discrete objects (e.g., House seats) to various stakeholders (e.g., states) with differing claims to those objects (e.g., due to their populations). We will focus on apportioning US House seats, but there are many other applications. More precisely, associated to such a problem we have: some whole number n>1 of states, numbered 1 through n, state 1 has population p 1, state 2 has population p 2, and so on, so that the total population is p = p 1 +p 2 + +p n, and some whole number h>0 of the discrete objects we wish to distribute. 10

Apportionment methods Much like with voting, apportionment methods are kinds of functions: An apportionment method is a function which takes as input the values h, n, p 1, p 2,, p n, where h and n are positive integers, p k s are positive numbers, and whose output is a sequence of nonnegative integers a 1, a 2,, a n such that h = a 1 +a 2 + +a n. The interpretation is that given h objects, and n states with populations p 1, p 2,, p n, the method distributes a k objects to the k th state. 11

Apportionment methods (cont d) For congressional apportionment: h = 435 (number of seats in the House), n = 50 (number of states), and we may order the states alphabetically so that pk is the population of the k th state in alphabetical order. The output of an apportionment method will consist of how many seats each state is to be given. For instance: In alphabetical order, New York is the 32nd state, so p32 = 19,378,102. 12

Quotas The quantity q k = h(p k /p) is the standard quota for the k th state. It is the ideal amount to be distributed to this state if we could divide the objects arbitrarily. In the case of New York, we have seen that this quantity is q 32 = 435(19,378,102/308,143,815) 27.4. Since a k must be a whole number, there are two natural candidates given by rounding down q k, called the lower quota, and rounding up q k, called the upper quota. For New York, the lower quota is 27, the upper quota is 28. 13

Standard divisor We can re-write qk = h(pk/p) = pk/(p/h). The quantity s = p/h is called the standard divisor, it is the ideal amount of the population entitled to each object. In congressional apportiontment, this quantity represents the size of an ideal congressional district. As of 2010, s = 308,143,815/435 708,377. 14

Hamilton s method The Constitution explicitly specified the initial apportionment to the States, but it became an issue for Congress in 1791. Alexander Hamilton (founding father and Secretary of the Treasury) proposed what we now call Hamilton s method: Alexander Hamilton 1757(?)-1804 First, assign to each state its lower quota of seats (there will likely be extra seats remaining). Then, assign the remaining seats to the states, at most one per state, in decreasing order of the fractional parts of their standard quotas (e.g., if the standard quota is 3.14159, the fractional part is 0.14159). 15

Hamilton s method (cont d) For example (p. 137-8 in R&U), use Hamilton s method apportion h = 10 seats to n = 3 states, with populations p1 = 1,450,000, p2 = 3,400,00, and p3 = 5,150,000. k pk standard quota lower quota upper quota Hamliton apportio- ment 1 1,450,000 1.45 1 2 2 2 3,400,000 3.40 3 4 3 3 5,150,000 5.15 5 6 5 16

Quota rule An apportionment method satisfies the quota rule (or is a quota method) if each state is always assigned either its upper quota or lower quota. Proposition: Hamilton s method is a quota method. Why? Each state gets at least their lower quota, and since we add at most one additional seat to each state, they cannot get more than their upper quota. In the (extremely rare) case that the standard quota of a state is exactly an integer (and is thus equal to both upper and lower quotas), the fractional part will be exactly 0, so they will be last on a list of states in decreasing order of fractional parts. Then, all of the remaining states will have been distributed to the other states before we get to this state. 17

Paradoxes Despite its simplicity, Hamilton s method has some strange properties, particularly when the input variables (h, n, the p k ) start to change. For example: Consider again the case of apportioning seats to n=3 states, with populations p 1 = 1,450,000, p 2 = 3,400,000, and p 3 = 5,150,000. With h = 10 seats, Hamilton s method apportions 2, 3, and 5 seats respectively. What happens if we change to h = 11 seats? k pk standard quota lower quota Hamliton apportio- ment 1 1,450,000 1.595 1 1 2 3,400,000 3.740 3 4 3 5,150,000 5.665 5 6 States 2 and 3 have gained a seat, while state 1 has lost a seat (!) despite no change in their populations. 18

Paradoxes (cont d) This phenomena, when a state loses a seat when the size of the House is increased and all other parameters (number of states, populations) are fixed, is called the Alabama paradox, named for the state it affected in the 1880 re-apportionment. An apportionment method is house monotone if it avoids this paradox, i.e., if an increase in h, with all others parameters fixed, can never result in a decrease in any of the apportioned amounts ak. 19

Paradoxes (cont d) Now consider the case of apportioning h = 10 seats to n = 3 states, with populations p 1 = 1,470,000, p 2 = 3,380,000, and p 3 = 4,650,000. k pk standard quota lower quota Hamliton apportionment 1 1,470,000 1.55 1 1 2 3,380,000 3.56 3 4 3 4,650,000 4.89 5 5 The population of state 1 increased, while the others decreased, yet state 1 lost a seat! This is called the population paradox; one state gains (or remains the same) in population while another loses (or remains the same), yet it is the first state that loses a seat, while the other gains a seat. Methods that avoid this are said to be population monotone. 20

Paradoxes (cont d) Consider again the case of apportioning seats to states with populations p 1 = 1,450,000, p 2 = 3,400,00, and p 3 = 5,150,000, with the addition of a fourth state, having population p 4 = 2,600,000. Suppose that we wish to apportion h = 13 seats, since it seems appropriate to give the new state 3 seats. k pk standard quota lower quota Hamliton apportio- ment 1 1,450,000 1.50 1 1 2 3,400,000 3.51 3 4 3 5,150,000 5.31 5 5 4 2,600,000 2.68 2 3 Again, state 1 has lost a seat to state 3, despite all of the new seats going to state 4, and their populations remaining unchanged. 21

Paradoxes (cont d) This phenomena, when the addition of a new state causes one old state to lose a seat to another old state without a change in their populations, is called the new states paradox. This is sometimes called the Oklahoma paradox, since when Oklahoma became a state in 1907, and was awarded 5 new seats, Hamilton s method would have removed a seat from New York and given it to Maine, without their population information changing. It can be seen as a special kind of population paradox. 22

Hamilton s method Despite these issues, Hamilton s method has been used for apportionment in the US, after the 1850, 1880 and 1890 censuses. It was not used when it was originally introduced in 1791. In fact, though Congress passed a bill supporting its use, it was vetoed (the first Presidential veto) by President George Washington, at the urging of Thomas Jefferson, on the grounds that it gave more than 1 seat per 30,000 people in some states (though not overall). Perhaps not coincidentally, Hamilton s method favored New York (his state), while harming Virginia (Jefferson s state). 23

Recommended reading: Ch. 7 in R&U Solutions to Test 1 have been posted on the course website. 24