How Has Job Polarization Contributed to the Increase in Non-Participation of Prime-Age Men?

Similar documents
Over the past three decades, the share of middle-skill jobs in the

Assessing Differences in Labor Market Outcomes Across Race, Age, and Educational Attainment. Working Paper April 2017

Inequality in Labor Market Outcomes: Contrasting the 1980s and Earlier Decades

Automation Biased Technology and Employment Structures in China: 1990 to 2015

Discussion of. Where Have All the Workers Gone? (Krueger 2017)

Earnings Inequality: Stylized Facts, Underlying Causes, and Policy

Is inequality an unavoidable by-product of skill-biased technical change? No, not necessarily!

Technological Change and Earnings Polarization: Implications for Skill Demand and Economic Growth

Is Technology Raising Demand for Skills, or Are Skills Raising Demand for Technology?

Job Displacement Over the Business Cycle,

International trade has long been a divisive

Recent Job Loss Hits the African- American Middle Class Hard

Losing Middle America:

Government data show that since 2000 all of the net gain in the number of working-age (16 to 65) people

Immigrants are playing an increasingly

What are the effects of job polarization on skills distribution of young workers in developing countries?

Canadian Labour Market and Skills Researcher Network

Inequalities in the Labor Market

Patrick Adler and Chris Tilly Institute for Research on Labor and Employment, UCLA. Ben Zipperer University of Massachusetts, Amherst

Who is poor in the United States? A Hamilton Project

THE ROLE OF THE STATE IN ECONOMIC GROWTH PARIS. Globalization and the Rise of the Robots

Offshoring and U.S. Labor Markets

Globalization and Income Inequality: A European Perspective

Changes in Wage Inequality in Canada: An Interprovincial Perspective

Occupational Concentration, Wages, and Growing Wage Inequality. Elizabeth Weber Handwerker U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics

Inequality in the Labor Market for Native American Women and the Great Recession

Macroeconomic Implications of Shifts in the Relative Demand for Skills

4 The Regional Economist Fourth Quarter 2017 THINKSTOCK / ISTOCK / KINWUN

Explaining the Unexplained: Residual Wage Inequality, Manufacturing Decline, and Low-Skilled Immigration

The Rich, The Poor, and The Changing Gap: An Investigation of the Determinants of Income Inequality from

Commentary: The Distribution of Income in Industrialized Countries

Why Are Fewer Workers Earning Middle Wages and Is It a Bad Thing?

Private Sector Commission

The Employment of Low-Skilled Immigrant Men in the United States

The Impact of Computers and Globalization on U.S. Wage Inequality

What Happened to the U.S. Employment Miracle?

Long-Run Changes in the U.S. Wage Structure: Narrowing, Widening, Polarizing. Claudia Goldin Harvard University and NBER

Low-Skill Jobs A Shrinking Share of the Rural Economy

The Black-White Wage Gap Among Young Women in 1990 vs. 2011: The Role of Selection and Educational Attainment

Characteristics of People. The Latino population has more people under the age of 18 and fewer elderly people than the non-hispanic White population.

Computerization and Immigration: Theory and Evidence from the United States 1

The labour share in the service economy

EPI BRIEFING PAPER. Immigration and Wages Methodological advancements confirm modest gains for native workers. Executive summary

Backgrounder. This report finds that immigrants have been hit somewhat harder by the current recession than have nativeborn

Explaining the Unexplained: Residual Wage Inequality, Manufacturing Decline, and Low-Skilled Immigration. Unfinished Draft Not for Circulation

Earnings Inequality: Stylized Facts, Underlying Causes, and Policy

Labor Market Dropouts and Trends in the Wages of Black and White Men

Wage Inequality in the United States and Europe: A Summary of the major theoretical and empirical explanations in the current debate

Real Wage Trends, 1979 to 2017

The likely scale of underemployment in the UK

Suggested Citation: Howell, David R. and Diallo, Mamadou. (2007)

Raising the Speed Limit on Future Growth

LEGACIES OF THE WAR ON POVERTY

10/11/2017. Chapter 6. The graph shows that average hourly earnings for employees (and selfemployed people) doubled since 1960

Most of the time, we assess an economy s performance using broad

The impact of Chinese import competition on the local structure of employment and wages in France

Job Growth and the Quality of Jobs in the U.S. Economy

The labor market in Brazil,

High Technology Agglomeration and Gender Inequalities

The State of. Working Wisconsin. Update September Center on Wisconsin Strategy

CURRICULUM VITAE DARON ACEMOGLU

CLACLS. A Profile of Latino Citizenship in the United States: Demographic, Educational and Economic Trends between 1990 and 2013

MADE IN THE U.S.A. The U.S. Manufacturing Sector is Poised for Growth

SUPPLY AND DEMAND IN THE SYRIAN LABOR MARKET

The Jordanian Labour Market: Multiple segmentations of labour by nationality, gender, education and occupational classes

The State of Working Wisconsin 2017

Unequal Recovery, Labor Market Polarization, Race, and 2016 U.S. Presidential Election. Maoyong Fan and Anita Alves Pena 1

Macro CH 21 sample questions

European Integration Consortium. IAB, CMR, frdb, GEP, WIFO, wiiw. Labour mobility within the EU in the context of enlargement and the functioning

REPORT. Third Anniversary of the Recovery Shows Job Growth for Women Slowed by Public Sector Job Losses. (July 2012)

Post-Secondary Education, Training and Labour September Profile of the New Brunswick Labour Force

11/2/2010. The Katz-Murphy (1992) formulation. As relative supply increases, relative wage decreases. Katz-Murphy (1992) estimate

Why Are Fewer Workers Earning Middle Wages and Is It a Bad Thing?

engineers, scientists, architects, mathematicians and executives/managers.

RESEARCH BRIEF: The State of Black Workers before the Great Recession By Sylvia Allegretto and Steven Pitts 1

Wage Differentials in the 1990s: Is the Glass Half-full or Half-empty? Kevin M. Murphy. and. Finis Welch

Executive Summary. Figures provided by the U.S. Census Bureau 1 demonstrate that teen employment prospects are dismal:

Geoff Bascand: Inflation pressures through the lens of the labour market

Policy brief ARE WE RECOVERING YET? JOBS AND WAGES IN CALIFORNIA OVER THE PERIOD ARINDRAJIT DUBE, PH.D. Executive Summary AUGUST 31, 2005

The widening income dispersion in Hong Kong :

Trends in the Joblessness and Incarceration of Young Men

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES WHY DON T MORE PUERTO RICAN MEN WORK? THE RICH UNCLE (SAM) HYPOTHESIS. María E. Enchautegui Richard B.

Measuring the American Social Contract

Background Paper Series. Background Paper 2003: 3. Demographics of South African Households 1995

How Do Countries Adapt to Immigration? *

14.64 Spring 2017 Brendan Price

IS THE UNSKILLED WORKER PROBLEM IN DEVELOPED COUNTRIES GOING AWAY?

Distributional Consequences of Trade and Technology

14.64 Spring 2017 Brendan Price

Does Immigration Help or Hurt Less-Educated Americans? Testimony of Harry J. Holzer before the U.S. Senate Judiciary Committee

Labor Supply at the Extensive and Intensive Margins: The EITC, Welfare and Hours Worked

The Demographics of the Jobs Recovery Employment Gains by Race, Ethnicity, Gender and Nativity

Is There a Trade-off between Unemployment and Inequality?

Primary inequality and redistribution through employer Social Security contributions: France

Earnings Inequality, Returns to Education and Immigration into Ireland

Women Work Participation Scenario in North 24-Parganas District, W.B. Ruchira Gupta Abstract Key Words:

Commentary: The Impact of Trade on Inequality in Developing Countries

ASSESSING THE ECONOMIC IMPACT OF FOREIGN WORKERS IN MALTA

Wage inequality in Germany What role does global trade play?

U.S. Workers Diverging Locations: Policy and Inequality Implications

Transcription:

How Has Job Polarization Contributed to the Increase in Non-Participation of Prime-Age Men? Didem Tüzemen and Jonathan L. Willis February 15, 2017 Abstract Non-participation among prime-age men in the U.S. has doubled from 6 percent in 1976 to 12 percent in 2016. Over these four decades, there have also been rapid increases in the employment shares of low- and high-skill jobs, while the employment share of middle-skill jobs has declined in the U.S. labor market. This aggregate shift in the composition of jobs, known as job polarization, may be contributing to the longterm trend of increasing non-participation among prime-age men. To investigate, we first analyze four decades of data from the Current Population Survey to characterize the relationship between job polarization and the decline in labor force participation among prime-age men. Then, we construct a labor-search model with heterogenous sectors and individuals, and occupational choice. In the model, job polarization leads to an increase in the demand for better-educated workers and a decline in the demand for less-educated workers who are employed in middle-skill jobs. Some middle-skill workers transition to high-skill occupations, while others move to low-skill service sector jobs. However, some of the displaced middle-skill workers permanently drop out of the labor force as they are not willing to accept low-wages at service sector jobs. Our aim is to quantify the contribution of job polarization to the long-term increase in nonparticipation among less-educated workers, which is a key element of the long-term decline in the labor force participation rate of prime-age men. In order to stabilize and potentially reverse the trend, labor market policies need to provide incentives and opportunities for workers in middle-skill jobs to obtain the necessary skills to become qualified for high-skill jobs. Keywords: job polarization, labor force participation rate, prime-age men, skills, skillbiased technological change, demand and supply of labor, occupational choice JEL Classification: E24, E32, J21, J24, J62 The views expressed in this paper are solely of the authors, and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, or the Federal Reserve System. Research Department, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City. 1 Memorial Drive, Kansas City, MO 64198. Email: Didem.Tuzemen@kc.frb.org. The Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, 1 Memorial Drive, Kansas City, MO 64198. E-mail address: Jonathan.Willis@kc.frb.org 1

1 Introduction Labor force participation among men ages 25 to 54 in the U.S. has declined dramatically since the 1970s. The share of prime-age men (ages 25 to 54) who are either working or actively looking for work decreased from 94 percent in 1976 to 88 percent in 2016 (Figure 1). The increase in non-participation among prime-age men has been a long-term trend, but it accelerated during the Great Recession with large-scale layoffs in construction and manufacturing. Figure 1: Labor Force Participation Rate of Prime-Age Men Notes: CPS data, authors calculations Prime-age individuals are at their most productive in terms of their working years. Therefore, understanding the reasons behind the decline in their participation rates has implications for not only these individuals earnings and well-being at the micro level, but also for economic growth, productivity, and rise in income inequality at the macro level. Labor force participation trends for prime-age men have varied for different education groups. While participation fell for all education groups, the largest decline was among those with lower educational attainment (Figure 2). The participation rate among prime-age men with a high-school degree fell from 96 percent in 1976 to 85 percent in 2016. Similarly, the participation rate among prime-age men with less than a high-school degree fell from 88 2

percent in 1976 to 79 percent in 2016. For prime-age men with a college degree and more, the decline in participation was modest, falling from 97 percent in 1976 to 94 percent in 2016. Figure 2: Labor Force Participation Rate of Prime-Age Men by Educational Attainment Notes: CPS data, authors calculations What is behind the decline in labor force participation of prime-age men? According to Juhn et al. (1991) and Juhn et al. (2002), the secular decline in real wages of less-skilled men is a major reason for the decline in their participation in the labor force. They argue that there has been a steep decline in the demand for low-skilled workers, which led to high rates of unemployment, labor force withdrawal, and long spells of jobslessness for men with low educational attainment. Using data for 1968-2001, they show that the increase in nonparticipation among prime-age men was due to low levels of real wages and an expansion of the disability benefits. Aguiar and Hurst (2016) document the rise in non-work and non-school time by younger men between ages 21 and 30. Again, men who decreased their work time were those with less than a college degree. They argue that improvements in video game technology raised 3

the value of leisure for younger men. This led to a decline in their labor supply and a more elastic response to falling real wages. Quantitatively, they find that the change in the value of leisure due to improvements in video game technology accounted for 20 to 45 percent of the observed decline in the work hours of younger and less-educated men. According to Krueger (2016), for many prime-age men who are out of the labor force, physical, mental, and emotional health challenges were a barrier to work. In particular, nearly half of non-participating prime-age men take pain medication on a daily basis, and in nearly two-thirds of cases they take prescription pain medication. As such, disabilities and daily pain were a barrier to regular employment for many prime-age men who are out of the labor force. Also, as in Aguiar and Hurst (2016), he finds that improvements in video game technology increased the enjoyment young men derive from leisure, which in turn, decreased their labor supply. Another explanation for the declining participation among prime-age men can be changes in labor demand in response to advancements in technology. Over the past four decades, there has been a large shift in the composition of jobs in the U.S. labor market. The employment share of middle-skill jobs has fallen significantly, while there have been rapid increases in the employment shares of low- and high-skill jobs. This aggregate shift of employment away from middle-skill jobs, and toward low- and high- skill jobs is called job polarization (Goos and Manning (2007), Autor et al. (2006), Autor (2010), Acemoglu and Autor (2011), Jaimovich and Siu (2012), Foote and Ryan (2012)). In this paper we argue that job polarization has contributed to the decline in the labor force participation rate of prime-age men. As computers and new technology replaced middle-skills jobs, workers in these jobs shifted toward low- and high-skill jobs. However, job polarization affected men and women differently. As documented in Tüzemen and Willis (2013), in response to the decline in the employment share of middle-skill occupations, employment of women has skewed toward high-skill occupations, while employment of men has shifted proportionally toward low- and high-skill occupations. The rising employment share 4

of women in high-skill occupations has been supported by significant increases in educational attainment of women. Educational attainment of men has risen more modestly, in line with the modest shift of male employment toward high-skill jobs. Job polarization led to an increase in the demand for better-educated workers and a decline in the demand for less-educated workers who were employed in middle-skill jobs. Some displaced middle-skill workers were able to transition to high-skill occupations, while others moved to low-skill service sector jobs. However, some of the displaced middle-skill workers permanently dropped out of the labor force as they were not willing to accept lowwages at service sector jobs. We argue that job polarization contributed to an increase in non-participation among less-educated workers, leading to the decline in the labor force participation rate of prime-age men. Aaronson et al. (2014) provide some explanatory empirical evidence supportive of the relationship between job polarization and non-participation. They find that the participation rates among less-educated adults fell more in states with a greater decline in the middle-skill employment shares, and the elasticity is greater for these groups than for the participation rates among better-educated adults. Similar to Aaronson et al. (2014), we first empirically show the relationship between the rise in non-participation among prime-age men and the declining employment share of middle-skill jobs. Then, we present a model to describe how job polarization leads to unemployment and non-participation among the displaced middle-skill workers. Our aim is quantify the contribution of job polarization to the increase in non-participation among prime-age men in the past four decades. Lastly, we discuss how policy can help stabilize and potentially reverse this trend. More specifically, labor market policies need to provide incentives and opportunities for workers in middle-skill jobs to obtain the necessary skills to become qualified for high-skill jobs. 5

2 Job Polarization Businesses have fundamentally changed the way they operate and the types of workers they require with the adoption of computers and associated technologies. Technological advances help explain why the employment share of middle-skill occupations has fallen so sharply. Workers in middle-skill occupations typically perform routine tasks that are procedural and rule-based. Therefore, these occupations are classified as routine occupations. These routine tasks have become automated by computers and machines (Autor et al. (1998), Autor et al. (2003), Acemoglu and Autor (2011)). In contrast, tasks performed in high-skill occupations cannot be automated, making them non-routine occupations. New technologies have increased the relative productivity of workers in high-skill jobs, complementing their skill sets. Workers suitable for these positions are typically highly educated and can perform tasks requiring analytical ability, problem solving and creativity. They work at managerial, professional and technical occupations, such as engineering, finance, management and medicine. As a result of technological advancements, more high-skill jobs have been created (Acemoglu (1998) and Acemoglu (2002)). More precisely, the employment share of workers in high-skill jobs increased by 14 percentage points, rising from 29 percent in 1976 to 43 percent in 2016 (Figure 3). Similarly, tasks performed in low-skill occupations cannot be automated, and the demand for workers to fill low-skill jobs increased. Workers in these jobs typically have no formal education beyond high school. They work in occupations that are physically demanding and cannot be automated. Many of these occupations are service oriented, such as food preparation, cleaning, and security and protective services. The employment share of lowskill jobs rose from 14 percent in 1976 to 19 percent in 2016. 6

Figure 3: Employment Shares by Skill-Level Notes: CPS data, authors calculations While the employment shares have increased for low- and high-skill jobs, the employment share has declined for middle-skill jobs. These middle-skill jobs include occupations, such as sales, office and administrative support, production, construction and extraction, installation, maintenance and repair, transportation and material moving. The technical change that boosted the demand for high-skill jobs also contributed to a big fall in the demand for middle-skill jobs, as computers and machines became cost-effective substitutes for workers in middle-skill jobs. The employment share of middle-skill occupations dropped by 19 percentage points, from 57 percent in 1976 to 38 percent in 2016. International trade and weakening of unions have also contributed to the decline in middle-skill occupations. Many jobs in this category, particularly those in manufacturing, have been off-shored to countries where workers can perform similar tasks for lower wages (Goos et al. (2011), Oldenski (2012)). In addition, some firms have been contracting out portions of their businesses to workers in foreign countries, a phenomenon known as outsourcing. De-unionizaton has also potentially contributed to the decline in the employment 7

share of middle-skill jobs (Autor (2010)). 3 Data The main data used in this study are from the Current Population Survey (CPS), also known as the household survey. The CPS is the primary source of labor force statistics and demographic data for the population of the United States. The data contain detailed demographic information on workers, as well as information on employment by industry and occupation. The U.S. Census Bureau collects survey data at a monthly frequency from approximately 60,000 households. The survey has a response rate ranging between 91 to 93 percent, which is one of the highest response rates among government surveys. The historical data are available through several public resources, and new micro-data files are published online frequently. For the statistics related to job polarization, the data are restricted to workers between ages 16 and 64 who are not self-employed and are not employed in military or agricultural occupations. For the statistics related to prime-age men, the data are for men ages 25 to 54. The analyses are based on annual data from 1976 to 2016. To construct annual series monthly observations are averaged for each year. 4 Model We construct a labor-search model with heterogenous sectors and individuals, and occupational choice. We follow the search-and-matching framework of Diamond (1982), Mortensen (1982), and Pissarides (1985). Individuals differ in their educational attainment (with a college degree and without a college degree) and their disutility of work. An individual can be employed and working, unemployed and searching for a job, or not participate in the labor force. Sectors differ in the occupations they offer which demand different tasks: non-routine cognitive occupations (high-skill), routine occupations (middle-skill), non-routine manual occupations (low-skill). Search is directed. Better-educated individuals (with a college degree) 8

search for middle-skill and high-skill occupations, while less-educated individuals (without a college degree) search for low-skill and middle-skill occupations. Over time, job polarization leads to an increase in the demand for better-educated workers and a decline in the demand for less-educated workers who were employed in middle-skill jobs. As a result, some better-educated middle-skill workers transition to high-skill occupations, while some less-educated move to low-skill service sector jobs. However, some of the lesseducated middle-skill workers drop out of the labor force as they are not willing to accept low-wages at low-skill jobs. Our aim is to quantify the contribution of job polarization to the increase in non-participation among less-educated workers, leading to the decline in the labor force participation rate of prime-age men. References Aaronson, Stephanie, Tomaz Cajner, Bruce Fallick, Felix Galbis-Reig, Christopher Smith, and William Wascher, Labor Force Participation: Recent Developments and Future Prospects, 2014, 2014 (2), 197 275. Acemoglu, Daron, Why Do New Technologies Complement Skills? Directed Technical Change and Wage Inequality, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 1998, 113 (4), 1055 1089., Technical Change, Inequality and the Labor Market, Journal of Economic Literature, 2002, 40 (1), 7 72. and David H. Autor, Skills, Tasks and Technologies: Implications for Employment and Earnings, Handbook of Labor Economics, 2011, 4, 1043 1171. Aguiar, Mark and Erik Hurst, The Macroeconomics of Time Allocation, Handbook of Macroeconomics, 2016, 2, 203 253. 9

Autor, David H., The Polarization of Job Opportunities in the US Labor Market: Implications for Employment and Earnings, Center for American Progress and Hamilton Project of the Brookings Institution, 2010., Frank Levy, and Richard J. Murnane, The Skill Content of Recent Technological Change: An Empirical Exploration, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2003, 118 (4), 1279 1333., Lawrence F. Katz, and Alan B. Krueger, Computing Inequality: Have Computers Changed the Labor Market?, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 1998, 113 (4), 1169 1213.,, and Melissa S. Kearney, The Polarization of the US Labor Market, American Economic Review, 2006, 96 (2), 189 194. Diamond, Peter A, Wage Determination and Efficiency in Search Equilibrium, The Review of Economic Studies, 1982, 49 (2), 217 227. Foote, Christopher L. and Richard W. Ryan, Labor-Market Polarization Over the Business Cycle, 2012. Federal Reserve Bank of Boston Public Policy Discussion Papers #12-8. Goos, Maarteen, Alan Manning, and Anna Salomons, Explaining Job Polarization: The Roles of Technology, Offshoring and Institutions, 2011, pp. 1 35. Goos, Maarten and Alan Manning, Lousy and Lovely Jobs: The Rising Polarization of Work in Britain, The Review of Economics and Statistics, 2007, 89 (1), 118 133. Jaimovich, Nir and Henry E. Siu, The Trend is the Cycle: Job Polarization and Jobless Recoveries, 2012. NBER Working Paper Series #18334. 10

Juhn, Chinhui, Kevin M Murphy, and Robert H Topel, Current Unemployment, Historically Contemplated, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2002, 2002 (1), 79 116.,,, Janet L Yellen, and Martin Neil Baily, Why has the Natural Rate of Unemployment Increased Over Time?, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1991, 1991 (2), 75 142. Krueger, Alan B, Where Have All the Workers Gone?, 2016. Mortensen, Dale T, The Matching Process as a Noncooperative Bargaining Game, 1982, pp. 233 258. Oldenski, Lindsay, Offshoring and the Polarization of the US Labor Market, 2012. Pissarides, Christopher A, Short-Run Equilibrium Dynamics of Unemployment, Vacancies, and Real Wages, The American Economic Review, 1985, 75 (4), 676 690. Tüzemen, Didem and Jonathan L Willis, The Vanishing Middle: Job Polarization and Workers Response to the Decline in Middle-Skill Jobs, The Economic Review, 2013, pp. 5 32. 11