THE TROUBLING USE OF ANTITRUST TO REGULATE FRAND LICENSING

Similar documents
COMMENT OF UNITED STATES FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSIONER JOSHUA D. WRIGHT AND JUDGE DOUGLAS H

COMMENT ON THE NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT AND REFORM COMMISSION S QUESTIONNAIRE ON INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY MISUSE ANTITRUST GUIDELINES

UNITED STATES INTERNATIONAL TRADE COMMISSION Washington, D.C.

COMMENT ON THE CANADIAN COMPETITION BUREAU S DRAFT UPDATED INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY ENFORCEMENT GUIDELINES

January 3, General Comments

Intellectual Property Rights and Antitrust Liability in the U.S.: The 2016 Landscape. Jonathan Gleklen Yasmine Harik Arnold & Porter LLP

COMMENT OF THE GLOBAL ANTITRUST INSTITUTE, GEORGE MASON UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF LAW, ON THE STATE ADMINISTRATION FOR INDUSTRY

CPI Antitrust Chronicle March 2015 (1)

WHY THE SUPREME COURT WAS CORRECT TO DENY CERTIORARI IN FTC V. RAMBUS

Law in the Global Marketplace: Intellectual Property and Related Issues FRAND Commitments and Obligations for Standards-Essential Patents

PATENT HOLDUP, ANTITRUST, AND INNOVATION: HARNESS

AIPLA Comments on Questionnaire on IP Misuse Antitrust Guidelines

EU Advocate General Opines That Seeking Injunctions On FRAND-Encumbered SEPs May Constitute an Abuse of Dominance

Nos , -1631, -1362, UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE FEDERAL CIRCUIT ERICSSON, INC. and TELEFONAKTIEBOLAGET LM ERICSSON,

August 6, AIPLA Comments on Partial Amendment of Guidelines for the Use of Intellectual Property Under the Antimonopoly Act (Draft)

Injunctive Relief for Standard-Essential Patents

EXTRA-JURISDICTIONAL REMEDIES INVOLVING PATENT LICENSING

District Court Denies Motion to Dismiss FTC Section 5 Complaint Against Qualcomm

UNITED STATES INTERNATIONAL TRADE COMMISSION Washington, D.C. THIRD PARTY UNITED STATES FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION S STATEMENT ON THE PUBLIC INTEREST

the Patent Battleground:

APLI Antitrust & Licensing Issues Panel: SEP Injunctions

FTC Orders Compulsory IP Licensing to Remedy Competitive Concerns in Honeywell/Intermec Transaction

FRAND or Foe: Litigating Standard Essential Patents

NTT DOCOMO Technical Journal. Akimichi Tanabe Takuya Asaoka Katsunori Tsunoda Makoto Kijima. 1. Introduction

Case5:12-cv RMW Document41 Filed10/10/12 Page1 of 10

The New IP Antitrust Licensing Guidelines' Silence On SEPs

THE FUTURE OF STANDARD SETTING

FTC AND DOJ ISSUE JOINT REPORT REGARDING ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT AND INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS

Anne Layne-Farrar Vice President, Adjunct Professor; Koren W. Wong-Ervin Director, Adjunct Professor of Law.

Federal Circuit Provides Guidance on Methodologies for Calculating FRAND Royalty Rates, Vacating the Jury Award in Ericsson v.

Law in the Global Marketplace: Intellectual Property and Related Issues FRAND in Europe: Huawei vs ZTE decision

October 2014 Volume 14 Issue 1

Reasonable Royalties After EBay

ANTITRUST AND THE IEEE S BYLAW AMENDMENTS

Huawei v ZTE No More Need To Look At The Orange Book In SEP Disputes

Google Settles with FTC Over SEPs; FTC Votes to Close Investigation Into Google s Search-Related Practices

Intellectual Property and Antitrust Seminar (Fall 2017)

AIPLA Annual Meeting, Washington DC 23 October Licenses in European Patent Litigation

Antitrust and Intellectual Property

DOJ Issues Favorable BRL on Proposed Revisions to IEEE s Patent Policy

Patent Hold-Up: Down But Not Out

Standard-Setting Policies and the Rule of Reason: When Does the Shield Become a Sword?

Patents, Standards and Antitrust: An Introduction

STANDARD SETTING AND ANTITRUST: SSOs, SEPs, F/RAND AND THE PATENT HOLDUP. Jeffery M. Cross Freeborn & Peters LLP

The ECJ s Huawei v. ZTE Decision and its Implementation in Practice

The Supreme Court Appears Likely to Place the Burden of Proof in Declaratory-Judgment Actions on the Patentees

Post-EBay: Permanent Injunctions, Future Damages

WHITHER SYMMETRY? ANTITRUST ANALYSIS OF INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS AT THE FTC AND DOJ

Patents and Standards The American Picture. Judge Randall R. Rader U.S. Court of Appeals for the Federal Circuit

Recent Decisions Provide Some Clarity on How Courts and Government Agencies Will Likely Resolve Issues Involving Standard-Essential Patents

Latest Developments On Injunctive Relief For Infringement Of FRAND-Encumbered SEPs

CPI Antitrust Chronicle September 2015 (1)

UNITED STATES INTERNATIONAL TRADE COMMISSION Washington, D.C.

Published by. Yearbook. Building IP value in the 21st century. Standard-essential patent monetisation and enforcement. Vringo, Inc David L Cohen

Clarifying Competition Law: Interface between Intellectual Property Rights and EU/U.S. Competition/Antitrust Law. Robert S. K.

Patent Portfolio Licensing

Speaker and Panelists 7/17/2013. The Honorable James L. Robart. Featured Speaker: Panelists: Moderator:

International Trade Daily Bulletin

THE PROPER ANTITRUST TREATMENT

FTC Approves Final Order in Google SEP Investigation, Responding to Commentators in a Separate Letter

Technology and IP Forum: Current global issues in SEP licensing, enforcement, and disputes December 4, 2018

IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE EASTERN DISTRICT OF TEXAS MARSHALL DIVISION DAUBERT ORDER

AIPLA Comments on the JPO Guide on Licensing Negotiations Involving Standard Essential Patents of March 9, 2018.

RAMBUS, INC. v. FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION Impact on Standards and Antitrust

Antitrust IP Competition Perspectives

Re: In the Matter of Robert Bosch GmbH, FTC File No

Risks of Grant-back Provisions in Licensing Agreements: A Warning to Patent-heavy Companies

Case 1:13-cv RGA Document 17 Filed 02/11/13 Page 1 of 26 PageID #: 227 IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE DISTRICT OF DELAWARE

Dear Secretary Barton:

Standard Essential Patent License under the FRAND Commitment

Rambus Addresses Some Questions, Raises Others

Recent Trends in Patent Damages

Case: 3:11-cv bbc Document #: 487 Filed: 11/02/12 Page 1 of 7

THE USE AND THREAT OF INJUNCTIONS IN THE RAND CONTEXT. James Ratliff & Daniel L. Rubinfeld

CPI Antitrust Chronicle October 2015 (2)

Patent Holdup, Patent Remedies, and Antitrust Responses The Role of Patent Remedies and Antitrust Law in Dealing with Patent Holdups

Non-challenge clauses in the TTBER and beyond: implications for litigation and settlements. Sophie Lawrance, Senior Associate Bristows LLP 8 May 2015

GLOBAL ANTITRUST INSTITUTE ECONOMICS INSTITUTE FOR COMPETITION ENFORCEMENT OFFICIALS

DOJ and USPTO Issue Policy Statement on Remedies for F/RAND-Encumbered SEPs

Case5:12-cv PSG Document471 Filed05/18/14 Page1 of 14

Prathiba M. Singh President, APAA (Indian Group)

Injunctions, Compulsory Licenses, and Other Prospective Relief What the Future Holds for Litigants

UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT WESTERN DISTRICT OF WASHINGTON AT SEATTLE ORDER

C RITERION E CONOMICS

Federal Court Dismisses Claims Against NPE for Allegedly Fraudulently Enforcing Its Patents; Upholds Breach of Contract and Promissory Estoppel Claims

Good-Faith licensing negotiation. March 2018 Masabumi Suzuki RIETI Graduate School of Law, Nagoya University

UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE CENTRAL DISTRICT OF CALIFORNIA, SOUTHERN DIVISION

Business Method Patents on the Chopping Block?

In the Supreme Court of the United States

Challenging Anticompetitive Acquisitions and Enforcement of Patents *

The Changing Face of U.S. Patent Litigation

CPI Antitrust Chronicle December 2013 (1)

Competition law as a defence in patent infringement cases the universal tool for getting off the hook or a paper tiger?

13 A Comparative Appraisal of Patent Invalidation Processes in Japan (*1) Jay P. Kesan ( * )

The Antitrust Division s Devaluation of Standard-Essential Patents

A Review of Korean Competition Law and Guidelines for Exercise of Standardrelated

Assistant Attorney General Makan Delrahim Signals Shift in Antitrust/IP Focus

Patent Portfolio Management and Technical Standard Setting: How to Avoid Loss of Patent Rights. Bruce D. Sunstein 1 Bromberg & Sunstein LLP

Court Dismisses NPE s Group Boycott Claims Against RPX, Motorola, Samsung, and Others

Respecting Patent Rights: Model Behavior for Patent Owners

Transcription:

THE TROUBLING USE OF ANTITRUST TO REGULATE FRAND LICENSING Douglas H. Ginsburg George Mason University School of Law Koren W. Wong-Ervin George Mason University School of Law Joshua D. Wright George Mason University School of Law CPI Antitrust Chronicle, Vol. 10, No. 1, pp. 2-8, 2015 George Mason University Legal Studies Research Paper Series LS 15-37 George Mason University Law & Economics Research Paper Series 15-46 This paper is available on the Social Science Research Network at ssrn.com/abstract=2674759

CPI Antitrust Chronicle October 2015 (1) The Troubling Use of Antitrust to Regulate FRAND Licensing Douglas H. Ginsburg, Koren W. Wong-Ervin, & Joshua D. Wright George Mason University School of Law www.competitionpolicyinternational.com Competition Policy International, Inc. 2015 Copying, reprinting, or distributing this article is forbidden by anyone other than the publisher or author.

The Troubling Use of Antitrust to Regulate FRAND Licensing Judge Douglas H. Ginsburg, Koren W. Wong-Ervin, & Joshua D. Wright 1 I. INTRODUCTION In the last year, we have seen a growing and troubling trend as courts and competition agencies around the globe propose and impose antitrust sanctions on holders of standardessential patents ( SEPs ) for seeking injunctive relief against alleged infringers and for reneging on their commitment to license their patents on fair, reasonable, and non-discriminatory ( FRAND ) terms. These new rules, recently adopted in the European Union and in Korea, proposed in Canada and Japan, and favored by some government officials in the United States, are premised upon the erroneous beliefs that (1) patent holdup is a widespread problem that results in significantly adverse consequences for competition and innovation and (2) whatever the magnitude of the problem, it requires an antitrust remedy. Patent holdup occurs when an SEP holder that has made a commitment to license its patents on FRAND terms instead uses the essential nature of its patent ( standard-lock-in ) to charge an unjustifiably higher royalty than would have been possible before its patent was included in the standard. Proponents of the new rules suggest the risk that ex post royalty rates will be higher than the ex ante rate was or would have been reflects a market failure requiring an antitrust response rather than a problem that could be resolved readily by standard-setting organizations ( SSOs ) themselves or by ordinary remedies for breach of contract. In other words, the underlying assumption is that the SSO process in general, and FRAND licensing in particular, is broken and in need of fixing. The assumption is wrong and the proposed antitrust remedy is likely to do more harm than good. First, as to the assumption, there simply is no empirical evidence to substantiate the claim that patent holdup is a systemic problem for competition and consumers. In fact, evidence from the smartphone market, which may be the most patent- and standard-intensive market, shows no signs of diminished competition or adverse effects upon consumers. In fact, it shows wireless service prices declining, output growing exponentially, innovation continuing at a rapid pace, vigorous dynamic competition among mobile device manufacturers with meaningful entry over time, and diminishing market concentration. In other words, the empirical evidence does not support the notion that FRAND licensing is somehow broken and in need of fixing. Instead, the thriving nature of the wireless market suggests caution prior to disrupting the carefully balanced 1 Judge Douglas H. Ginsburg is a Judge on the U.S. Court of Appeals for the District of Columbia, Professor of Law at George Mason University School of Law, and Chairman of the International Advisory Committee of the Global Antitrust Institute. At the time this article was written, Koren W. Wong-Ervin was an Attorney Advisor to then-federal Trade Commissioner Joshua D. Wright. Joshua D. Wright is a Professor of Law at George Mason University School of Law and the Director of the Global Antitrust Institute. The views expressed here are those of the authors alone and do not necessarily represent the views of the U.S. Federal Trade Commission or any of its Commissioners. 2

FRAND ecosystem. Second, as for the remedy, imposing antitrust liability for patent holdup and a patent holder s refusals to issue a license on FRAND terms is not only unnecessary, given that the law of contracts is sufficient to provide optimal deterrence, it is likely to be harmful to both competition and consumers by diminishing the value of patents and hence reducing incentives to innovate and to participate in standard setting. 2 II. THE NEW ANTITRUST RULES FOR SEP HOLDERS Within the last year, several jurisdictions have issued final or draft guidelines on SEP issues. For example, in December 2014, the Korea Fair Trade Commission (without providing an opportunity for public comment) issued final guidelines, which are scheduled to be revised in late 2015 or early 2016. In June 2015, the Canadian Bureau of Competition released its revised intellectual property ( IP ) guidelines for public comment and the next month the Japan Fair Trade Commission released its draft IP guidelines for public comment. These new antitrust rules would impose an antitrust sanction on SEP holders who either (1) seek an injunction to stop an infringing manufacturer from selling their standardized product, or (2) engage in ex-post contractual opportunism by attempting to renegotiate or deviate from the original FRAND commitment in order to obtain higher royalty rates. Also in July 2015, the European Court of Justice ( ECJ ) held that seeking injunctive relief with respect to a FRAND-encumbered SEP may constitute a violation of the European Union s competition law, specifically Article 102 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union. 3 The court created a safe harbor from Article 102 liability, however, for a SEP holder that (1) prior to initiating an infringement action, alerts the alleged infringer of the claimed infringement and specifies the way in which the patent has been infringed; and (2) after the alleged infringer has expressed its willingness to conclude a license agreement on FRAND terms, presents to the alleged infringer a specific, written offer for a license, specifying the royalty and calculation methodology. The ECJ then put the burden on the alleged infringer to diligently respond to that offer in accordance with recognised commercial practices in the field and in good faith, by promptly providing a specific written counter-offer that corresponds to FRAND terms, and by providing appropriate security (e.g., a bond or funds in escrow) from the time at which the counter-offer is rejected and prior to using the teachings of the SEP. 4 These new rules are premised upon the mistaken belief that holdup is both frequent and results in significant consumer harm. For example, Japan s Draft Amendment to its IP Guidelines concludes that a SEP s holder seeking injunctive relief generally makes it difficult to research & develop... products adopting the standards, which in turn deters widespread adoption of 2 See, e.g., Bruce H. Kobayashi & Joshua D. Wright, The Limits of Antitrust and Patent Holdup: A Reply to Cary, et al., 78 ANTITRUST L.J. 505 (2012). 3 Case C-170/13, Huawei Technologies Co. v. ZTE Corp. (July 16, 2015), available at http://curia.europa.eu/juris/document/document.jsf?text=&docid=165911&pageindex=0&doclang=en&mode=lst& dir=&occ=first&part=1&cid=603775. 4 Id. 65-67. 3

standards. 5 This assertion notwithstanding, the empirical evidence does not suggest patent holdup is a frequent or systemic problem and, even if it were, there are substantial weaknesses in the argument that antitrust is the right tool to fine-tune any problems with SEP licensing negotiations or SSOs. III. NO EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE SUGGESTS A SYSTEMIC PROBLEM WITH HOLDUP Although there is serious and important scholarly work exploring the theoretical conditions under which patent holdup might occur, this literature merely demonstrates the possibility that an injunction (or the threat of an injunction) against infringement of a patent can in certain circumstances be profitable for the licensor and potentially harmful to consumers. This same theoretical literature has also recognized, with respect both to intellectual and to tangible property, the threat of both reverse holdup and holdout. Holdup requires lock-in, and standardimplementing companies with asset-specific investments can be locked in to the technologies defining the standard. On the other hand, innovators that are contributing to an SSO can also be locked-in, and hence susceptible to holdup, if their technologies have a market only within the standard. Thus, incentives to engage in holdup run in both directions. There is also the possibility of holdout by an implementer. While reverse holdup refers to the situation in which a licensee uses its leverage to obtain rates and terms below FRAND, holdout refers to a licensee either refusing to take a FRAND license or delaying doing so. It is important to distinguish the hypotheses generated in the theoretical literature on patent holdup from such empirical evidence as would substantiate those hypotheses. The existing empirical evidence is not consistent with the view that holdup is a prevalent or systemic problem and is causing harm to consumers. 6 The evidence required to support the new antitrust rules requires that there be a probability, not a mere possibility, of higher prices, reduced output, and lower rates of innovation. In fact, as mentioned above, evidence from the smartphone market is to the contrary: Output has grown exponentially, while market concentration has fallen, and wireless service prices have dropped relative to the overall consumer price index ( CPI ). 7 More generally, prices 5 Guidelines for the Use of Intellectual Property Under the Antimonopoly Act, Draft Amendment Parts 3(1)(e) and 4(2)(iv), available at http://www.jftc.go.jp/en/pressreleases/yearly-2015/july/150708.files/attachment1.pdf. 6 See, e.g., J. Gregory Sidak, The Antitrust Division s Devaluation of Standard-Essential Patents, 104 GEO. L.J. ONLINE 48, 61 (2015) (collecting studies at n.49) ( By early 2015, more than two dozen economists and lawyers had disapproved or disputed the numerous assumptions and predictions of the patent-holdup and royalty-stacking conjectures. ), available at https://www.criterioneconomics.com/docs/antitrust-divisions-devaluation-of-standardessential-patents.pdf; ANNE LAYNE-FARRAR, PATENT HOLDUP AND ROYALTY STACKING THEORY AND EVIDENCE: WHERE DO WE STAND AFTER 15 YEARS OF HISTORY? (Dec. 2014), available at http://www.oecd.org/officialdocuments/publicdisplaydocumentpdf/?cote=daf/comp/wd%282014%2984&docla nguage=en (surveying the economic literature and concluding that the empirical studies conducted thus far have not shown holdup is a common problem). 7 According to data from Gartner, worldwide smartphone sales to end-users have increased over 900 percent between 2007 to 2014, and 320 percent between 2010 to 2014. Market concentration in smartphones, as measured by HHIs, went from highly concentrated in 2007, as defined by the U.S. Antitrust Agencies Horizontal Merger Guidelines, to unconcentrated by the end of 2012. See Keith Mallinson, Theories of Harm with SEP Licensing Do Not Stack Up, IP FIN. BLOG (May 24, 2013), available at http://ipfinance.blogspot.com/2013/05/theories-of-harm- 4

in SEP-reliant industries in the United States have declined faster than prices in non-sep intensive industries. 8 A recent study by the Boston Consulting Group found that globally the cost per megabyte of data declined 99 percent from 2005 to 2013 (reflecting both innovation making data transmission cheaper as well as the healthy state of competition); the cost per megabyte fell 95 percent in the transition from 2G to 3G, and 67 percent in the transition from 3G to 4G; and the global average selling price for smartphones decreased 23% from 2007 through 2014, while prices for the lowest-end phones fell 63 percent over the same period. 9 All of this indicates a thriving mobile market as opposed to a market in need of fixing. Economic analysis provides the basis upon which to understand the apparent disconnect between holdup theory and the available evidence. As economic theory would predict, patent holders and those seeking to license and implement patented technologies write their contracts so as to minimize the probability of holdup. In addition, several market mechanisms are available to transactors to mitigate the incidence and likelihood of patent holdup. For example, reputational and business costs may deter repeat players from engaging in holdup and patent holders that have broad cross-licensing agreements with the SEP-owner may be protected from hold-up. 10 Also, patent holders often enjoy a first-mover advantage if their technology is adopted as the standard. As a result, patent holders who manufacture products using the standardized technology may find it more profitable to offer attractive licensing terms in order to promote the adoption of the product using the standard, increasing demand for its product rather than extracting high royalties per unit. 11 This is not surprising. The original economic literature upon which the patent holdup theories are based was focused upon the various ways that market actors use reputation, contracts, and other institutions to mitigate the inefficiencies associated with opportunism in transactions involving tangible property. 12 with-sep-licensing-do.html. According to the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, the ratio of the CPI for wireless telephone services to the overall CPI has dropped 34% from 2007 to 2014. 8 Alexander Galetovic, Stephen Haber, & Ross Levine, An Empirical Examination of Patent Hold-Up (Nat l Bureau of Econ. Research, Working Paper No. 21090, Apr. 2015), available at http://www.nber.org/papers/w21090.pdf. 9 JULIO BEZERRA ET AL., THE MOBILE REVOLUTION: HOW MOBILE TECHNOLOGIES DRIVE A TRILLION DOLLAR IMPACT 3, 9 (The Boston Consulting Group Jan. 15, 2015), available at https://www.bcgperspectives.com/content/articles/telecommunications_technology_business_transformation_mobi le_revolution/#chapter1. 10 See, e.g., Prepared Statement of the Federal Trade Commission Before the U.S. Senate Committee on the Judiciary Subcommittee on Antitrust, Competition Policy and Consumer Rights Concerning Standard Essential Patent Disputes and Antitrust Law at 6 (July 30, 2013), available at https://www.ftc.gov/sites/default/files/documents/public_statements/prepared-statement-federal-trade-commissionconcerning-standard-essential-patent-disputes-and/130730standardessentialpatents.pdf. 11 Id. (citation omitted). 12 Benjamin Klein, Why Hold-Ups Occur: The Self-Enforcing Range of Contractual Relationships, 34 ECON. INQUIRY 444, 449-50 (1996); Benjamin Klein, Robert G. Crawford & Armen A. Alchian, Vertical Integration, Appropriate Rents, and Competitive Contracting Process, 21 J.L. & ECON. 297, 303-07 (1978); OLIVER E. WILLIAMSON, MARKETS AND HIERARCHIES: ANALYSIS AND ANTITRUST IMPLICATIONS 26-30 (New York: Free Press 1975); see also Joshua D. Wright, Comm r, Fed. Trade Comm n, remarks before George Mason University School of Law: SSOs, FRAND, and Antitrust: Lessons Learned from the Economics of Incomplete Contracts at 2-3 (Sept. 12, 2013) 5

Recognizing the theoretical nature of holdup concerns, the United States Court of Appeals for the Federal Circuit has held that a claim of holdup must be substantiated with actual evidence, and that the burden is on the accused infringer to show the patent holder used injunctive relief to gain undue leverage and demand supra-frand royalties. 13 IV. AN ANTITRUST SANCTION FOR BREACH OF CONTRACT IS UNNECESSARY AND IS LIKELY TO REDUCE INCENTIVES TO INNOVATE AND DETER PARTICIPATION IN STANDARD SETTING A FRAND commitment is a contractual commitment. 14 Economists have long understood that a contractual relationship involving asset-specific investments creates the potential for opportunism. Similarly, a patentee participating in the standard-setting process can, once the standard is adopted by an SSO, holdup potential licensees by exploiting asset-specific investments to demand a higher royalty rate than would have prevailed in a competitive setting. The view that contractual opportunism alone gives rise to an antitrust problem rather than a contract problem is in tension with substantial economic literature on the subject. 15 Consistent with this view, no United States court has held that seeking injunctive relief on a FRANDencumbered SEP violates the antitrust laws. Instead, every United States court that has addressed the issue has done so under contract law principles. With respect to reneging on a FRAND commitment, as the Supreme Court explained in NYNEX Corp. v. Discon, Inc., while the evasion of a pricing constraint may hurt consumers, it (explaining that the economics of hold-up began not as an effort to explain contract failure, but as an effort to explain real world contract terms, performance, and the enforcement decisions starting with the fundamental premise that contracts are necessarily incomplete ), available at https://www.ftc.gov/sites/default/files/documents/public_statements/ssos-frand-and-antitrust-lessons-economicsincomplete-contracts/130912cpip.pdf. There is empirical evidence that SSO contract terms vary both across organizations and over time in response to changes in the perceived risk of patent holdup and other factors. See Joanna Tsai & Joshua D. Wright, Standard Setting, Intellectual Property Rights, and the Role of Antitrust in Regulating Incomplete Contracts, 80 ANTITRUST L.J. 157 (2015). 13 See, e.g., Ericsson, Inc. v. D-Link Sys., 773 F.3d 1201, 1234 (Fed. Cir. 2014) ( In deciding whether to instruct the jury on patent hold-up and royalty stacking, again, we emphasize that the district court must consider the evidence on the record before it. The district court need not instruct the jury on hold-up or stacking unless the accused infringer presents actual evidence of hold-up or stacking. Certainly something more than a general argument that these phenomena are possibilities is necessary. ); see also Anne Layne-Farrar & Koren W. Wong- Ervin, An Analysis of the Federal Circuit s Decision in Ericsson v. D-Link, CPI ANTITRUST CHRONICLE, Mar. 2015, at 5-7, available at http://www.crai.com/sites/default/files/publications/an-analysis-of-the-federal-circuits-decisionin-ericsson-v-d-link.pdf. 14 See, e.g., Innovatio IP Ventures, LLC Patent Litig., No. 11 C 9308, 2013 WL 5593609, at *4 (N.D. Ill. Oct. 3, 2013); Microsoft Corp. v. Motorola, Inc., No. C10 1823JLR, 2013 WL 2111217, at *1 (W.D. Wash. Apr. 25, 2013), aff d 795 F.3d 1024 (9th Cir. 2015); Apple, Inc. v. Motorola Mobility, Inc., 886 F. Supp. 2d 1061, 1083-84 (W.D. Wis. 2012); Microsoft Corp. v. Motorola, Inc., 854 F. Supp. 2d 993, 999-1001 (W.D. Wash. 2012), reaffirmed, 864 F. Supp. 2d 1023, 1030-33 (W.D. Wash. 2012), aff d in relevant part, 696 F.3d 872, 884 (9th Cir. 2012). 15 See, e.g., Joshua D. Wright & Douglas H. Ginsburg, Patent Assertion Entities and Antitrust: A Competition Cure for a Litigation Disease, 79 ANTITRUST L.J. 501, 509 (2014); see also Benjamin Klein, Market Power in Antitrust: Economic Analysis After Kodak, 3 SUP. CT. ECON. REV. 43, 62-63 (1993) ( Antitrust law should not be used to prevent transactors from voluntarily making specific investments and writing contracts by which they knowingly put themselves in a position where they may face a hold-up in the future.... [C]ontract law inherently recognizes the pervasiveness of transactor-specific investments and generally deals with hold-up problems in a subtle way, not by attempting to eliminate every perceived hold-up that may arise. ). 6

does not harm the competitive process. 16 The Court distinguished the mere breach of a pricing commitment from the unlawful exercise of monopoly power by pointing out that, with the breach, the consumer injury naturally flowed not so much from a less competitive market as... from the exercise of market power lawfully in the hands of a monopolist. 17 Moreover, an antitrust sanction is not only unnecessary to protect consumer welfare given that the law of contracts is sufficient to provide optimal deterrence, 18 but is likely to be harmful. 19 First, significant monetary sanctions are likely to over-deter procompetitive participation in SSOs; FRAND-encumbered SEP holders need the credible threat of an injunction if they are to recoup the value added by their patents and have no other adequate remedy against an infringing user. Indeed, excessive deterrence is particularly likely because, with liability turning upon whether the infringing user was truly a willing licensee 20 a factual determination that may be far from clear in many cases the outcome of an antitrust case will necessarily be uncertain. The prospect of penalizing a FRAND-encumbered SEP holder for seeking injunctive relief diminishes the value of its patents and hence reduces its incentive to innovate. Second, the prospect of antitrust liability for a patentee seeking injunctive relief would enable an infringing user to negotiate in bad faith, knowing its exposure is capped at the FRAND royalty rate; in this way, an unscrupulous or a judgment-proof infringing user can force the SEP holder to take a below-frand rate. Indeed, when the worst penalty an SEP infringer faces is not an injunction but merely paying, after a neutral adjudication, the FRAND royalty that it should have agreed to pay when first asked, then reverse holdup and holdout give implementers a profitable way to defer payment or if they are judgment proof, to avoid payment altogether and puts SEP holders at a disadvantage that reduces the rewards from, and can only discourage innovation and participation in, standard setting. 21 Third, antitrust liability is likely to deter patent holders from contributing their technology to an SSO under FRAND terms if doing so will require them to forfeit their right to protect their intellectual property by seeking an injunction against infringing users. These possibilities, far from protecting the public interest in competition and innovation, actually threaten to reduce the gains from innovation and standardization. 16 NYNEX Corp. v. Discon, Inc., 525 U.S. 128, 135-37 (1998). See also Kobayashi & Wright at 519-20, supra note 2. 17 NYNEX Corp., 525 U.S. at 129. 18 Douglas H. Ginsburg, Taylor M. Owings & Joshua D. Wright, Enjoining Injunctions: The Case Against Antitrust Liability for Standard Essential Patent Holders Who Seek Injunctions, ANTITRUST SOURCEat 5-6 (Oct. 2014). 19 Id.; see also Kobayashi & Wright, supra note 2. 20 See, e.g., Case C-170/13, Huawei Technologies Co. v. ZTE Corp., 77 (July 16, 2015), available at http://curia.europa.eu/juris/document/document.jsf?text=&docid=165911&pageindex=0&doclang=en&mode=lst& dir=&occ=first&part=1&cid=603775; Analysis of Proposed Consent Order to Aid Public Comment, In the Matter of Motorola Mobility LLC and Google, Inc., File No. 121-0120, at 2, 6 (F.T.C. Jan. 3, 2013), available at http://www.ftc.gov/sites/default/files/documents/cases/2013/01/130103googlemotorolaanalysis.pdf. 21 The effect of such delaying tactics is magnified when the patent owner has a large worldwide portfolio of SEPs requiring it to file lawsuits around the world in order to adjudicate a FRAND royalty on a patent-by-patent basis. In that circumstance, international arbitration on a portfolio basis would appear to be the most efficient and realistic means of resolving a FRAND dispute. 7

V. CONCLUSION The new antitrust rules are troubling not only because they are wholly unsupported by empirical evidence, but also because they threaten to deter participation in standard setting and reduce the incentive to innovate. Antitrust enforcers around the globe should be wary of upsetting the carefully balanced FRAND-ecosystem, and should consider the unintended consequences of their proposed solution to the largely theoretical problem of patent holdup. 8