Family Structure, Institutions, and Growth: The Origins and Implications of Western Corporations. Avner Greif Stanford University 2006

Similar documents
Family Structure, Institutions, and Growth: The Origins and Implications of Western Corporations

Family Structure, Institutions, and Growth: The Origin and Implications of Western Corporatism. Avner Greif Stanford University 2005

European Economic History

Cultural and Institutional Bifurcation: China and Europe Compared

: Organizational Economics (CentER) Fall Jens Prüfer Office: K 311,

POL201Y1: Politics of Development

History/Social Science Standards (ISBE) Section Social Science A Common Core of Standards 1

Introduction. Cambridge University Press Lopez (1976); Persson (1998); Postan (1973); and Pounds (1994).

ONE MORE TIME WITH FEELING: THE LAW MERCHANT, ARBITRATION, AND INTERNATIONAL TRADE

CURRICULUM GUIDE for Sherman s The West in the World

The Historical Evolution of International Relations

Note on the historical background for European industrialization. Social organization. Trade in Feudal era. Social norms 9/20/2017

Part IIB Paper Outlines

Missouri Educator Gateway Assessments

World History and Civilizations

Chapter 2: The Modern State Test Bank

The Failure to Transplant Democracy, Markets, and the Rule of Law into the Developing World

Foundations of Institutional Theory. A block seminar in the winter term of 2012/13. Wolfgang Streeck, Max-Planck-Institut für Gesellschaftsforschung

WORLD HISTORY Curriculum Map

Chapter 8 Government Institution And Economic Growth

ECO 301Y The Economic History of Later Medieval and Early Modern Europe, ca ca Professor John H. Munro Department of Economics Room 348

HISTORICAL AND INSTITUTIONAL ANALYSIS IN ECONOMICS

Western University, Departments of History & Economics HIS 3426G / ECO 3318G Making a Living in the Middle Ages: Farmers, Guild Artisans and Merchants

+ Contents. Nation-State, Nationalism and Citizenship 4/9/2014. The Idea of Nation. Nation-State: Nation and Nationalism.

HISTORY. History A.A. for Transfer Degree

School of Economics Shandong University Jinan, China Pr JOSSELIN March 2010

2008 World History I History and Social Science Standards of Learning STANDARD

World History I (Master) Content Skills Learning Targets Assessment Resources & Technology CEQ: features of early. civilizations.

BACHELOR IN ECONOMICS FIRST YEAR

APWH Ch 19: Internal Troubles, External Threats Big Picture and Margin Questions

AP Gov Chapter 1 Outline

ILLINOIS LICENSURE TESTING SYSTEM

B.A. IN HISTORY. B.A. in History 1. Topics in European History Electives from history courses 7-11

Economic Change and The Bi-Polar World Economy

Grade Level: 9-12 Course#: 1548 Length: Full Year Credits: 2 Diploma: Core 40, Academic Honors, Technical Honors Prerequisite: None

II. MACRO- AND STRUCTURAL CHANGES IN THE EUROPEAN ECONOMY, D. Money and Population in Late- Medieval Price Movements and Long Waves

Possible Essay Topics for ECON 306 Final, Spring Semester 2016

History (HIST) History (HIST) 1

Natural Law and Spontaneous Order in the Work of Gary Chartier

Test Blueprint. Course Name: World History Florida DOE Number: Grade Level: 9-12 Content Area: Social Studies. Moderate Complexity.

We can distinguish classical and new legal pluralism. Legal pluralism was confined in three ways:

1. Base your answer to question on the chart below and on your knowledge of social studies.

Test Design Blueprint Date 1/20/2014

Citizen: Literally, citizenship means resident of the city, which later on came to be known as resident of a state.

Political Science 246A/446A Paths to the Modern World: Islam and the West

SOCIAL STUDIES 8 COURSE OUTLINE WORLD CIVILIZATIONS

What is a constitution? Do all democracies have them? Does a constitution protect citizens rights?

1.Myths and images about families influence our expectations and assumptions about family life. T or F

COURSE DESCRIPTION Comparative Law. Description

INSTITUTIONS AND THE PATH TO THE MODERN ECONOMY: LESSONS FROM MEDIEVAL TRADE, Avner Greif, 2006, Cambridge University Press, New York, 503 p.

CITY OF MISSISSAUGA. Overview 2-1. A. Demographic and Cultural Characteristics

Income Sharing Amongst Medieval Peasants: Usury Prohibitions and the Non-Market Provision of Insurance

Political Science 346 Middle East Politics, Section 730 Fall Semester, 2018

World History I: Civics and Economics Essential Knowledge

History (

COLGATE UNIVERSITY. POSC 153A: INTRODUCTION TO COMPARATIVE POLITICS (Spring 2017)

HIST252 Guide to Responding to Units 3 & 4 Reading Questions

Ordering Power: Contentious Politics and Authoritarian Leviathans in Southeast Asia

The dynamics of family systems: Lessons from past and present

MIDDLE GRADES SOCIAL SCIENCE

Christopher Heurlin. Responsive Authoritarianism: Protest and Policymaking in China. (Cambridge University Press, 2016) (225 pages)

Robust Political Economy. Classical Liberalism and the Future of Public Policy

Hudson Institute Robert Dujarric Senior Fellow Tel (202)

INSTITUTIONS MATTER (revision 3/28/94)

(3) parliamentary democracy (2) ethnic rivalries

Social Studies World History Classical Civilizations and Empires 1000 B.C. to 1450 A.D.

Patterns of immigration in the new immigration countries

Religious legitimacy and the joint evolution of. culture and institutions

The Sultztonian Institute. World History End Of Course Exam Review

Syllabus for 260A: Comparative economics. ( ). Instructor : Gérard Roland

European History

7.1.3.a.1: Identify that trade facilitates the exchange of culture and resources.

Nathan Glazer on Americans & inequality

Economic History of Europe Economics Course Syllabus and Reading List

EC260: The Political Economy of Public Policy

Topic for Fall 2013 : The Co-evolution of States and Markets in Western Europe

SOCIAL STUDIES GRADE 7. I Can Checklist Office of Teaching and Learning Curriculum Division

Gender and Institutions: Creating an Enabling Environment

PETERS TOWNSHIP HIGH SCHOOL

Chapter Test. Multiple Choice Identify the choice that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Globalization in History

Base your answers to questions 1 and 2 on the art work below and on your knowledge of social studies.

Teaching Notes The Third Revolution: Xi Jinping and the New Chinese State

AP Euro: Past Free Response Questions

Fall Quarter 2018 Descriptions Updated 4/12/2018

Course Descriptions Political Science

InspireData Standards Match

Title: Religious Differences in Wome n s Fertility and Labour Force Participation in France Nitzan Peri-Rotem

SENIOR 4: WESTERN CIVILIZATION HISTORICAL REVIEW OF ITS DEVELOPMENT (OPTIONAL)

Are Asian Sociologies Possible? Universalism versus Particularism

The origins of public finance, as a field of study though most certainly not

Coercion and Exchange: How did Markets Evolve?

II. Thematic Learning Objectives

North Carolina Essential Standards for Social Studies Grade 7

Introduction. Good luck. Sam. Sam Olofsson

Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance by Douglass C. North Cambridge University Press, 1990

The Impact of Administrative Power on Political and Economic. Developments: Toward Political Economy of Implementation

IS - International Studies

Federica Carugati. Stanford University, Stanford, CA Program Director, Center for Advanced Study in the Behavioral Sciences (2018-present)

Family Values and the Regulation of Labor

Transcription:

Family Structure, Institutions, and Growth: The Origins and Implications of Western Corporations Avner Greif Stanford University 2006 Forthcoming American Economic Review, May 2006. There is a vast amount of literature that considers the importance of the family as an institution. Little attention, however, has been given to the impact of family structures on institutions and their dynamics. This limits our ability to understand distinct institutional developments and hence growth in the past and the present. This paper supports this argument by highlighting the importance of the European family structure in one of the most fundamental institutional changes in history and reflecting on its growth-related implications. What constituted this change was the emergence of the economic and political corporations in late medieval Europe. Corporations are defined here, consistent with their historical meaning, as intentionally created, voluntary, interest-based, and self-governed permanent associations. Guilds, fraternities, universities, communes and city-states are some of the corporations that have dominated Europe in the past; businesses and professional associations, business corporations, universities, consumer groups, counties, republics and democracies are examples of corporations in modern societies. The provision of corporation-based institutions to mitigate problems of cooperation and conflict constituted a break from the ways in which institutions had been provided in the past. Historically, large kinship groups, such as clans, lineages and tribes, often secured the lives and property of their members and provided them with social safety nets. Institutions were also often provided by states, governed by customary or authoritarian rulers and by religious authorities. Private-order, usually undesigned, institutions prevailed as well. Corporation-based institutions can substitute for institutions provided in these ways. When they substitute for kinship groups and provide social safety nets, corporations complement 1

the nuclear family. An individual stands to gain less from belonging to a large kinship group while the nuclear family structure increases his benefit from being a member of such a corporation. In tracing the origins of the European corporations, this paper (which draws on Greif 2006) focuses on their complementarity with the nuclear family. It presents the reasons for the decline of kinship groups in medieval Europe (section 1) and why the resulting nuclear family structure, along with other factors, led to corporations (section 2). European economic growth in the late medieval period was based on an unprecedented institutional complex of corporations and nuclear families (section 3) which, interestingly, still characterizes the West. More generally, European history suggests that this complex was conducive to long-term growth although we know little about why this was the case or why it is difficult to transplant this complex to other societies. The papers conclusion reflects on these issues (section 4). I. The Evolution of Family Structures in Europe The conquest of the Western Roman Empire by Germanic tribes during the medieval period probably strengthened the importance of kinship groups in Europe. Yet, the actions of the Church caused the nuclear family constituting of husband and wife, children, and sometimes a handful of close relatives to dominate Europe by the late medieval period. The medieval church instituted marriage laws and practices that undermined kinship groups. Its dogma was self-serving in that it increased, for example, the likelihood that an individual would make a bequest to the church. (Mitterauer et. al. 1982; Goody 1983; Ekelund et. al. 1996.) The church discouraged practices that enlarged the family, such as adoption, polygamy, concubinage, divorce, and remarriage, and restricted marriages among individuals of the same blood (consanguineous marriages), which had historically provided one means of creating and maintaining kinship groups. It also curtailed parents abilities to retain kinship ties through arranged marriages by prohibiting unions that the bride didn t explicitly consent to. European family structures did not evolve monotonically toward the nuclear family nor was their evolution geographically and socially uniform (Herlihy 1969; Greif 2006, chapter 8). However, by the late medieval period the nuclear family was dominant. Even among the Germanic tribes, by the eighth century the term family denoted one s immediate family, and 2

shortly afterwards tribes were no longer institutionally relevant. (Guichard and Cuvillier, 1996.) Thirteenth-century English court rolls reflect that even cousins were as likely to be in the presence of non-kin as with each other. (Razi 1993). The practices the church advocated (e.g., monogamy), are still the norm in Europe. Consanguineous marriages in contemporary Europe account for less than one percent of the total number of marriages in contrast to such marriages in Muslim, Middle Eastern countries where (our particularly good) data yields a percentage of between twenty to fifty percent in each country. (Bittles 1994.) Among the anthropologically defined 356 contemporary societies of Euro-Asia and Africa, there is a large and significant negative correlation between the spread of Christianity (for at least 500 years) and the absence of clans and lineages; the level of commercialization, class stratification, and state formation are insignificant. (Korotayev 2003.) II. Incorporation as a Function of Family Structure The decline of large kinship groups in Europe transpired during a period in which the state was also disintegrating and the church s secular authority was diminishing. Furthermore, individualist cultural beliefs hindered the rise of effective private-order institutions based on collective punishment. (Greif 1994.) A new solution was needed to solve problems of conflict and cooperation and it took the form of corporations. These corporations were voluntary, interest-based, self-governed, and intentionally created permanent associations. In many cases, they were self-organized and not established by the state. Participation was voluntary in the sense that one had to be attracted to be a member and therefore corporations had to cater to their members interests. Corporations were self-governed in that their members participated in specifying the rules that regulated their activities; power was shared and leaders were held accountable for their actions. They were permanent in the sense that whether one was established for an indefinite or finite length of time, its perpetuation didn t depend on the participation of any particular member and they were permanent in the sense that their property, rights, and obligations were distinct from that of each individual member. Subsequently, this implied that corporations could sue and be sued. The nuclear family structure and the weakness of the state and church contributed to the rise of corporations, but weren t the determining factors. Multiple outcomes could have 3

prevailed given the rules of the game spanned by these factors. Where power was distributed relatively symmetrically, anarchy, or the strengthening of large kinship groups, occasionally prevailed. Yet, in such cases, the European political culture and its legal heritage made corporations a cognitively feasible, focal, and normatively accepted outcome. Organization among free individuals governed by their laws under leaders who are first among equals are central concepts to Greek, Roman, and Germanic political traditions and their (and the Christian) legal codes provide precedents to corporate bodies. The actions of the late medieval Church (i.e., the Papacy) also contributed to the rise of corporations. During the eleventh century, the Church became a corporation to deflect threats to its independence and property from secular rulers and the Church s agents. To this end, the papacy formulated a corporate law that drew on Roman, Germanic and Christian legal principles. It rejected the view that royal permission was required to establish a corporation, asserted that any corporation has the right to tax its members over whom it also has legislative and judicial jurisdiction, and placed a corporation s agents under the authority of its members. (Berman 1983). This codification bestowed legitimacy on self-organized and self-governed corporations in general, created a related moral code and coordinated expectations. III. Europe Inc. and Late-Medieval Growth By the late medieval period, economic and political corporations dominated Europe. We know how they fostered growth although we still don t have micro-analyses of their internal governance. Corporations provided safety nets, secured property rights (from the grabbing hand of the state, pirates and each other), provided public goods, supported markets, and fostered innovation and training. Indeed, from circa 1050 to 1348, Europe experienced its longest, post- Roman period of economic growth. Monasteries, fraternities and mutual-insurance guilds provided social safety nets against famine, unemployment and disability. The majority of the population belonged to such fraternities and guilds, at least in England (Richardson 2005). Because corporations provided social safety nets that were alternatives to those provided by kinship groups, they enabled individuals to take risks and make other economic decisions without interference by members of such groups. Relative to a society dominated by kinship groups, the nuclear family structure 4

increased capital per-worker by encouraging late marriages and fewer children and it led to a more efficient distribution of labor and knowledge by facilitating migration. Craft guilds regulated production, training, and the protection of brand names. Universities, monastic orders, and guilds developed and distributed scientific and technological knowledge. Merchant guilds and communes protected property rights at home and abroad, secured brand names, and provided contract enforcement in exchange. Corporations, such as the Italian city-states and military orders, mustered armies to expand the European resource base. (E.g., Gonzalez 2004; Epstein 1998; Greif, et. al. 1994; Greif 2004; Greif, 2006; Mokyr 1990 Richardson 2004a,b.) Many late medieval corporations were political; they had their own legal systems, administrations, and military forces. The Italian city-republics were literally independent but most European cities west of the Baltic Sea in the north, and the Adriatic Sea in the south were also political corporations (communes). Political corporations also prevailed among western European peasants (Reynolds, 1984, ch. 4-5; Brenner 1987). Because such corporations preceded the pre-modern European states, they often provided these states with indispensable services, such as tax collection, law and order and an army. Self-interested rulers were therefore constrained from adopting policies that hindered these corporations economic interests or abusing their property rights. (Greif 2005.) Indeed, by the thirteenth century, most European principalities had representative bodies to approve taxation, and communes were represented in all of them (Ertman 1997). Economic corporations therefore had the ability to impact policies and, in the long run, they were influential in transforming the European state to a corporation in the form of a democracy. IV Corporations, Nuclear Families and Development Until the modern period, corporations and nuclear families constituted a distinguishing feature of the particularly European institutional foundations of markets, polities and knowledge. 1 There is still much to learn about the contributions corporation-based institutions 1 Although associations with corporation-like features were not unknown elsewhere. Greif (1994, 2006); Kuran (2005); Jabar and Dawod (2003); Hamilton (1991). 5

made to European growth. Yet, it is informative to note that Europe s economic ascendancy started after corporations began to dominate. Since then growth has prevailed, particularly when and where corporation-based institutions have reigned. Corporations have been in the forefront of the late medieval commercial revolution, the subsequent global commercial expansion, Imperialism, colonization, industrialization, and the development of modern science and technology. Although we know how particular European corporations contributed to growth, we know very little about why their overall impact seems to have been growth-enhancing. After all, corporations seek to benefit their members rather than to foster growth. History is rich with examples of even initially growth-enhancing economic corporations that later became a means for rent seeking, redistribution and control. Many political corporations degenerated into oligarchies or collapsed due to violent internal conflicts. Contemporary developing countries similarly provide many examples of growth-inhibiting corporations. Comparing historical and contemporary experiences suggests why the European corporations advanced growth. Unlike modern developing countries, an emerging pre-modern European state faced inter-state military threats and had to draw on domestic resources to confront them. Theoretically, in this context, corporations advance economic growth and prosperity when a ruler is strong militarily but has an ineffectual administration. (Bates, et. al. 2002.) An ineffectual administration implies that he depends on the services domestic corporations provide, which limits arbitrary use of his power against them. Administrative incapacity also limits corporate rent seeking. There is no point in paying for a monopoly that the state can t enforce. Finally, a militarily strong ruler who is dependent on corporations is able and motivated to protect them from the local predatory elites. Furthermore, he is able and motivated to limit inter-corporation military competition forcing corporations to compete economically, and not militarily with each other. The overall beneficial impact of European corporations may be attributable to the luck of having some areas, such as Flanders and England, where these conditions persisted and forced other competing states to promote growth. (Greif 2005.) More generally, Europe s long experience with corporations implied a social and cultural heritage that was conducive to the development of growth-enhancing institutions. Economically and politically, successful corporations undermined large kinship groups. Indeed, in the past and 6

present, these groups resisted growth-promoting institutions such as the democratic state, fearing their power would be undermined (Greif 2006, chapter 8). Furthermore, successful corporations fostered the beliefs and norms that justify and support self-governance, the rule of law, the legitimacy of majority rule, respect for minority rights, individualism, and trust among non-kin. Indeed, cross-country regressions indicate that a country s growth and the stability of its democracy increase the longer its historical democratic experience has been. (Persson and Tabellini 2005.) Different sets of beliefs and norms evolve in a corporation-based society than would otherwise be the case. Hence, whenever various European states emerged from absolutism and despotism, they built on this heritage. Many developing countries, however, share another heritage, one implied by institutions based on large kinship groups and autocratic (often colonial) rulers. Whatever the implications of corporation-based institutions may be, the relationship between their emergence and the nuclear family structure suggests that we have more to learn regarding distinct institutional and hence growth trajectories and their persistence through examining the dynamic interplay between family structures and institutional development. 7

Reference Bates, Robert, Avner Greif, and Smita Singh. 2002. Organizing Violence. The Journal of Conflict Resolution, 46(5, Oct.): 599-628. Berman, Harold J. 1983. Law and Revolution. The Formation of the Western Legal Tradition. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Bittles, Alan H. 1994. The Role and Significance of Consanguinity as a Demographic Variable. Population and Development Review 20 (3): 561-84. Brenner, Robert. 1985. Agrarian Class Structure and Economic Development in Pre-Industrial Europe. In T.H. Aston and C.H.E. Philpin (eds), The Brenner Debate: Agrarian Class Structure and Economic Development in Pre-Industrial Europe. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Pp. 10-63. Ekelund, Robert B., Jr., Robert F. Hébert, Robert D. Tollison, Gary M. Anderson, and Audrey B. Davidson. 1996. Sacred Trust: The Medieval Church as an Economic Firm. New York: Oxford University Press. Mitterauer, Michael, and Reinhard Sieder. 1982. The European Family. Oxford: Basil Blackwell. Epstein, Steven. R. 1998. Craft Guilds, Apprenticeship and Technological Change in Preindustrial Europe. Journal of Economic History 53 (4): 684-713. Ertman, Thomas. 1997. Birth of the Leviathan. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Gonzalez de Lara, Yadira. 2004. The State as an Enforcer in Early Venetian Trade: A Historical Institutional Analysis. Memo, University of Alicante. 8

Goody, J. 1983. The Development of the Family and Marriage in Europe. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Greif, Avner. 1994. "Cultural Beliefs and the Organization of Society: A Historical and Theoretical Reflection on Collectivist and Individualist Societies." The Journal of Political Economy, vol. 102, No. 5 (October): 912-50. Greif, Avner. 2004. Impersonal Exchange without Impartial Law: The Community Responsibility System. Chicago Journal of International Law, Vol. 5(1): 109-138. Greif, Avner. 2005. Commitment, Coercion, and Markets: The Nature and Dynamics of Institutions Supporting Exchange. In the Handbook for New Institutional Economics. Edited by Claude Menard and Mary M. Shirley. Norwell MA: Kluwer Academic Publishers. Chapter 28. Greif, Avner. 2006. Institutions and the Path to Economic Modernity: Lessons from Medieval Trade. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Greif, Avner, Paul Milgrom and Barry Weingast. 1994. "Coordination, Commitment and Enforcement: The Case of the Merchant Gild." The Journal of Political Economy, vol. 102, No. 4 (August): 745-776. Guichard, Pierre and Cuvillier, Jean-Pierre. 1996. Barbarian Europe in Ed. André Burguiére et. al. A History of the Family, Vol. I. Cambridge: Polity Press. Pp. 318-378. Hamilton, Gary G. 1991. The Organizational Foundations of Western and Chinese Commerce: A Historical and Comparative Analysis. In Gary G. Hamilton (ed.), Business Networks and Economic Development in East and Southeast Asia, 48-65. Hong Kong: University of Hong Kong, Centre of Asian Studies. 9

Herlihy, David. 1969. Family Solidarity in Medieval Italian History. In David Herlihy, Robert S. Lopez, and Vsevolod Slessarev (eds). Economy, Society and Government in Medieval Italy. Kent, Ohio: Kent University Press. Jabar, Faleh A. and Hosham Dawod. 2003. Tribes and Power. Nationalism and Ethnicity in the Middle East. London: Saqi. Korotayev, A.V., 2003. Unilineal Descent Organization and Deep Christianization: a Crosscultural Comparison. Cross-cultural Research 37 (1): 133-157. Kuhn, Arthur K. 1912. Comparative Study of the Law of Corporations. Columbia in the Social Sciences, no. 123. New York: AMS Press. Kuran, Timur. 2005. 2005. Why the Islamic Middle East Did Not Generate an Indigenous Corporate Law. Memo, University of Southern California. Mokyr, Joel. 1990. The Lever of Riches. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Persson, Torsten and Guido Tabellini. 2005. Democratic Capital: the Nexus of Political and Economic Change. Memo. Razi Z.. 1993. The Myth of the Immutable English Family. Past & Present 140(Aug), Pp. 3-44 Reynolds, Susan. 1984. Kingdoms and Communities in Western Europe, 900-1300. Oxfrod: Clarendon Press. Richardson, Gary. 2004a. Guilds, Laws, and Markets for Manufactured Merchandise in Latemedieval England. Explorations in Economic History 41(1): 1-25. Richardson, Gary. 2004b. Brand Names before the Industrial Revolution. UC Irvine. 10

Richardson, Gary. 2005. The Prudent Village: Risk Pooling Institutions in Medieval English Agriculture. Journal of Economic History, 65(2) (June): 386-413. 11