Does Crime Breed Inequality?

Similar documents
Separate When Equal? Racial Inequality and Residential Segregation

The Economic Impact of Crimes In The United States: A Statistical Analysis on Education, Unemployment And Poverty

Residential segregation and socioeconomic outcomes When did ghettos go bad?

American Law & Economics Association Annual Meetings

THE EFFECT OF EARLY VOTING AND THE LENGTH OF EARLY VOTING ON VOTER TURNOUT

Crime and Corruption: An International Empirical Study

Tax Competition and Migration: The Race-to-the-Bottom Hypothesis Revisited

Brain drain and Human Capital Formation in Developing Countries. Are there Really Winners?

Fall : Problem Set Four Solutions

The 2010 Midterm Election for the US House of Representatives

Measuring International Skilled Migration: New Estimates Controlling for Age of Entry

ESSAYS ON MEXICAN MIGRATION. by Heriberto Gonzalez Lozano B.A., Universidad Autonóma de Nuevo León, 2005 M.A., University of Pittsburgh, 2011

Running head: School District Quality and Crime 1

Income inequality and crime: the case of Sweden #

Immigration and the Neighborhood

Separate When Equal? Racial Inequality and Residential Segregation

July, Abstract. Keywords: Criminality, law enforcement, social system.

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts

Skill classi cation does matter: estimating the relationship between trade ows and wage inequality

ESTIMATE THE EFFECT OF POLICE ON CRIME USING ELECTORAL DATA AND UPDATED DATA

Crime and economic conditions in Malaysia: An ARDL Bounds Testing Approach

Part 1: Focus on Income. Inequality. EMBARGOED until 5/28/14. indicator definitions and Rankings

Determinants of Violent Crime in the U.S: Evidence from State Level Data

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE SKILL COMPOSITION OF MIGRATION AND THE GENEROSITY OF THE WELFARE STATE. Alon Cohen Assaf Razin Efraim Sadka

Supporting Information Political Quid Pro Quo Agreements: An Experimental Study

Online Appendix for The Contribution of National Income Inequality to Regional Economic Divergence

DISCUSSION PAPERS IN ECONOMICS

THE EFFECT OF CONCEALED WEAPONS LAWS: AN EXTREME BOUND ANALYSIS

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach

Great Gatsby Curve: Empirical Background. Steven N. Durlauf University of Wisconsin

Voting with Their Feet?

Separate When Equal? Racial Inequality and Residential Segregation

Decision Making Procedures for Committees of Careerist Experts. The call for "more transparency" is voiced nowadays by politicians and pundits

Development Economics: Microeconomic issues and Policy Models

The Immigration Policy Puzzle

Purchasing-Power-Parity Changes and the Saving Behavior of Temporary Migrants

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE LABOR MARKET IMPACT OF HIGH-SKILL IMMIGRATION. George J. Borjas. Working Paper

Social Networks, Achievement Motivation, and Corruption: Theory and Evidence

Rethinking the Area Approach: Immigrants and the Labor Market in California,

The Economics of Rights: The E ect of the Right to Counsel

WORKING PAPER STIMULUS FACTS PERIOD 2. By Veronique de Rugy. No March 2010

This report examines the factors behind the

Non-Voted Ballots and Discrimination in Florida

Does Owner-Occupied Housing Affect Neighbourhood Crime?

Does Inequality Increase Crime? The Effect of Income Inequality on Crime Rates in California Counties

SKILLED MIGRATION: WHEN SHOULD A GOVERNMENT RESTRICT MIGRATION OF SKILLED WORKERS?* Gabriel Romero

University of Hawai`i at Mānoa Department of Economics Working Paper Series

The Substitutability of Immigrant and Native Labor: Evidence at the Establishment Level

This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research

A Role for Sunspots in Explaining Endogenous Fluctutations in Illegal Immigration 1

Expected Earnings and Migration: The Role of Minimum Wages

Labor Market Dropouts and Trends in the Wages of Black and White Men

Online Appendix. Capital Account Opening and Wage Inequality. Mauricio Larrain Columbia University. October 2014

Understanding the Impact of Immigration on Crime

The Impact of Income on Democracy Revisited

Towards a Coherent Diaspora Policy for the Albanian Government Investigating the Spatial Distribution of the Albanian Diaspora in the United States

WORKING PAPER NO IMMIGRATION AND THE NEIGHBORHOOD

Illegal Immigration. When a Mexican worker leaves Mexico and moves to the US he is emigrating from Mexico and immigrating to the US.

A Role for Government Policy and Sunspots in Explaining Endogenous Fluctuations in Illegal Immigration 1

Working Paper: The Effect of Electronic Voting Machines on Change in Support for Bush in the 2004 Florida Elections

Reevaluating the modernization hypothesis

Stimulus Facts TESTIMONY. Veronique de Rugy 1, Senior Research Fellow The Mercatus Center at George Mason University

Rural and Urban Migrants in India:

The Effects of Housing Prices, Wages, and Commuting Time on Joint Residential and Job Location Choices

Arrest Rates and Crime Rates: When Does a Tipping Effect Occur?*

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES INCOME INEQUALITY AND SOCIAL PREFERENCES FOR REDISTRIBUTION AND COMPENSATION DIFFERENTIALS. William R.

Schooling and Cohort Size: Evidence from Vietnam, Thailand, Iran and Cambodia. Evangelos M. Falaris University of Delaware. and

Unequal Recovery, Labor Market Polarization, Race, and 2016 U.S. Presidential Election. Maoyong Fan and Anita Alves Pena 1

EPI BRIEFING PAPER. Immigration and Wages Methodological advancements confirm modest gains for native workers. Executive summary

Allocating the US Federal Budget to the States: the Impact of the President. Statistical Appendix

Immigrant Legalization

The Effects of Ethnic Disparities in. Violent Crime

Skill Classification Does Matter: Estimating the Relationship Between Trade Flows and Wage Inequality

Was the Late 19th Century a Golden Age of Racial Integration?

AN ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF CAMPUS CRIME AND POLICING IN THE UNITED STATES: AN INSTRUMENTAL VARIABLES APPROACH

19 ECONOMIC INEQUALITY. Chapt er. Key Concepts. Economic Inequality in the United States

Do barriers to candidacy reduce political competition? Evidence from a bachelor s degree requirement for legislators in Pakistan

LEFT BEHIND: WORKERS AND THEIR FAMILIES IN A CHANGING LOS ANGELES. Revised September 27, A Publication of the California Budget Project

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA?

A poverty-inequality trade off?

Crime in Oregon Report

Openness and Poverty Reduction in the Long and Short Run. Mark R. Rosenzweig. Harvard University. October 2003

Swiss National Bank Working Papers

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES PARDONS, EXECUTIONS AND HOMICIDE. H. Naci Mocan R. Kaj Gittings. Working Paper

Family Values and the Regulation of Labor

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal

The Crime Drop in Florida: An Examination of the Trends and Possible Causes

Reevaluating the Modernization Hypothesis

Crime in Urban Areas: An Empirical Investigation

The Determinants and the Selection. of Mexico-US Migrations

Inequality and Growth: The Role of Beliefs and Culture

The Economic and Social Review, Vol. 42, No. 1, Spring, 2011, pp. 1 26

CH 19. Name: Class: Date: Multiple Choice Identify the choice that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation

The Analytics of the Wage Effect of Immigration. George J. Borjas Harvard University September 2009

Owner-Occupied Housing and Crime rates in Denmark

George J. Borjas Harvard University. September 2008

ARE GHETTOS GOOD OR BAD?*

Household Income, Poverty, and Food-Stamp Use in Native-Born and Immigrant Households

Transcription:

Does Crime Breed Inequality? Igor Barenboim Harvard University Dec 24th, 2007 Abstract Crime and income inequality are positively correlated. Most authors have developed theories that study the causation from income inequality to crime. To our knowledge, no studies have been written on the reverse causality. This paper aims to ll in this gap. Theoretically, we show that if the marginal return to buying protection declines with the amount of protection goods owned, income inequality increases with crime. We also analyze this relationship in an investment and a spatial model. We present some suggestive evidence of the theoretical mechanisms described and quantify it using overcrowding litigations as an instrument. 1 Introduction 1 Crime and Inequality are positively correlated. Most authors have developed theories that study the causation from income inequality to crime. Becker (1968) explained that in more unequal societies, the return to committing a crime increases, since there is more wealth to be taken away at each crime. Ehrlich (1973) documented this positive relationship using US data. In Figure 1, we plot crime rates per 100,000 inhabitants against the Gini coe cient for a panel of US states from 1969 to 1994 to show this positive correlation. However, Bourgingnon et al. (2003) points out that the evidence of causality from inequality to crime is weak. The same study indicates that these variables are indeed consistently positively correlated in many cross sections studies. However, 1 I would like to thank Elias Albagli, Alberto Alesina, David Cutler, Alex Gelber, Edward Glaeser, Alex Kaufman, Lawrence Katz and Andrei Shleifer for their insightful comments and support. Needless to say, all potential mistakes are mine only. 1

this relationship fails to be signi cant in a panel data setting in which xed e ects are controlled for. Freeman (1996) has shown this fact for US metropolitan areas and Fajnzylber et al. (2002) for a cross country panel. Nonetheless, the latter authors did nd a positive signi cant coe cient when they took into account a dynamic relationship between crime and inequality using time series variation 2. This evidence suggests that a theory for reverse causality between inequality and crime may be of help to comprehend reality. There are at least three channels through which crime can breed income inequality. First, consider an environment where individuals can engage in self-protection by buying security goods. Assume that the marginal protection that a security good provides is declining with the amount of security goods already owned. Then, lower income individuals will nd optimal to allocate a larger share of their income to acquiring security goods relatively to the rich. As a result, the disposable income distribution, after paying for crime and protection, will be more unequal than the total income one. The main assumption necessary for the mechanism to go through is that there are negative returns to scale in the protection technology. One would believe that this is a good assumption if one thinks that the amount of security an individual gets from installing a home alarm security system is smaller for individuals who have already a wall around 2 using the Arellano-Bower system estimator. 2

their house than for individuals who do not do so. Di Tella and coauthors (2006) show that after a massive crime increase in Argentina during the 1990s, victimization rates for the poor increased more than for the rich for home robberies. They present evidence that suggests that the rich have invested more in security goods and therefore were less likely to be victimized. They also showed that victimization rates for on-street robberies rose by the same proportion for rich and poor since there is not much for the rich to do besides mimicking the poor while walking on the street. This evidence suggests that there is so much that security goods can do for you and that concavity has to kick in at some point. In sum, this latter study shows that (i) individuals do acquire security goods to self-protect, (ii) the poor do seem to su er more due to the lack of income to self protect 3 and (iii) security goods become somewhat redundant once one owns a lot of them. An alternative assumption that would make the same mechanism work is that there are xed costs embedded in security goods, or that security goods costs are concave. Think of the cost of building a wall in front of a two bedroom house compared to the cost of building it to protect a four bedroom one. Both endeavors involve transporting the materials to the building site and perhaps the same amount of concrete - the most expensive material for building a wall. The marginal cost would be in terms of bricks and hours worked. A starker example is that to install a home alarm system in both types of houses may cost precisely the same. Or even to buy a German Shepard and feed it shall entail the same cost for two or four bedroom householders. Second, consider a two period investment model where individuals can choose in the rst period to consume, save, or buy security goods to protect themselves from crime in the second period. Then, lower income individuals will choose to save a smaller share of their income relatively to the rich, because crime creates a wedge in the inter-period marginal rate of substitution. Hence, total income in the second period shall be more unequal than in the rst period. In other words, even if the poor allocate a larger share of their income to protection in the rst period, they will not be as well protected as the rich, therefore the returns to savings for the poor is lower and hence the total income inequality in the second period shall be higher than in the rst. This investment model has a clear and veri able empirical implication, that the di erence of saving rates of rich and poor is larger when crime rates are higher. Using data from the US Consumption Expenditure Survey we are able to calculate saving rates for above and below median income individuals per state. We then show that the di erence 3 Levitt (1999) show similar evidence for the US. 3

of saving rates between rich and poor is positively correlated with percapita rates of property and violent crime obtained from the Uniform Crime Reports assembled by the FBI. Third, consider a spatial model of a metropolitan area in which individuals can choose to live in the city center with high density and hence high crime rates, or in the suburbs with lower crime rates. The supply of houses in the city is xed and the supply of housing in the suburbs is given by the marginal cost of construction. Using the absence of spatial arbitrage as our equilibrium concept 4, and assuming decreasing returns to scale in the protection technology, we can show that, in equilibrium, the rich and the poor will choose to live in the city, while the middle class will ee to the suburbs. This is the case because house prices in the city center drop because of crime, which works as an attraction for the poor. The rich are able to engage in protection and are also therefore better o living in the city center. The middle class is not rich enough to a ord enough protection and hence moves to the suburbs 5. We present some suggestive evidence that corroborates with our theoretical nding. We show that in the early 90s, when crime rates were still on the rise, migration to the suburbs was lower for rich and poor and higher for the middle class. We also show that the reverse is true for migration to the city centers. We nalize this article with an empirical exercise, which consists of nding an instrument that is correlated with crime and not with inequality to obtain an estimate of the impact of crime on inequality. We use overcrowding litigation of prisons in the US as an instrument for property crime - an instrument formerly used by Levitt (1996). The data shows that crime has a positive and signi cant e ect on inequality after three or more years 6. Our point estimates tell us that when crime per-capita rates increase by 10% the Gini coe cient rises by 1%. In the next section we proceed by building up a formal analysis of the theoretical mechanisms we have described here, in Section 3 we provide a discussion and some suggestive empirical evidence on critical assumptions and consequences of our models. In Section 4, we describe the data and the methodology for the instrumental variable estimation of the impact of crime on inequality. In Section 5, we show our estimates of the impact of crime and inequality. The last section concludes the study. 4 i.e. that individuals cannot be better o by moving to the other area of town 5 I am thankful to Edward Glaeser for this insight. 6 up to ve years. 4

2 Formal Analysis In this section we build the theoretical foundations of the mechanisms through which crime can breed income inequaliy. We start by looking at a static model, we then look at a two period model to incorporate investment. Next, we analyze a spatial model in which choice of location to live is endogenous. 2.1 Static Model Consider an environment with a continuum of individuals with an exogenous income distribution F (y) with support [0; y max ]:This economy has an exogenous crime rate k 2 [0; 1]; which works as a toll on k share of individual income. The proceeds from this toll are thrown away. Individuals can buy security goods s at price 1 to protect themselves from crime. Security goods provide protection (s) 2 [0; 1] from the crime toll, where 0 (s) > 0 and 00 (s) < 0: De ne the disposable income after crime and protection as ^y = y[1 k(1 (s))] s and suppose for simplicity that individuals maximize disposable income 7 in choosing s. De ne the distribution of disposable income yielded by this maximization is G(^y): Proposition 1 Crime convexi es the distribution of disposable income. In other words, any individual i will be richer relatively to the population below her and poorer relatively to the population above her in terms of disposable income than in terms of total income. (Proof in the Appendix) This result entails that for any distribution of income F (y); crime would yield a distribution of disposable income with fatter tails. This is the case because the poor in the original distribution nd it optimal to allocate a larger share of their income to security goods, since the marginal return of acquiring these goods is much higher for them. While the rich would allocate a smaller share of their income to reach their most desired and relatively high level of protection, shifting them to the right of the disposable income distribution. Figure 2 ilustrates the mechanics of the model well showing how an increase in the crime rate shifts the distribution of disposable income. The solid 45 degree line shows that when crime is zero income and disposable income are precisely the same. 5

Figure 2: Crime Convexifies Disposable Income y^y^ k=0 45 o k>0 y However when crime increases disposable income shifts down unevenly for di erent income levels breeding disposable income inequality. As we have mentioned previously, an alternative assumption that would make the same mechanism work is that there are xed costs embedded in security goods, or that security goods costs are concave. To see how that would work formally, just replace (s);by ((s)), where (:) is a cost function such that 0 (:) > 0 and 00 (:) < 0: 2.2 Investment Model Consider a two period investment model where individuals can choose in the rst period to consume right away c 1, invest to consume in the next period I with rate of return R, but subject to a crime toll k; which can be mitigated by acquiring security goods s at price 1 in the rst period. Protection is again an increasing and concave function (s): Individuals have exogenous income distributed by F (y) and maximize their time additive concave utility function. max u(c 1 ) + u(c 2 ) 7 Utility can also be de ned as concave, but this adds no value to the results here. So we proceed with the simplest formulation. 6

where is the discount rate. For simplicity, assume R = 1: Individuals maximize utility subject to the following budget constraints BC 1 : y = c 1 + I + s BC 2 : RI[1 k(1 (s))] = c 2 Taking the rst order condition with respect to investment, we can verify that crime creates a wedge between the marginal utility of period 1 and that of period 2. More speci cally crime creates a disincentive to save and consume in the second period and hence in equilibrium the marginal utility in period 2 is larger than in period 1. This implies that in this setting it is optimal to consume less in the second period than in the rst one. u 0 (c 1 ) = 1 k(1 (s)) < 1 u 0 (c 2 ) Note that the wedge between the marginal utlities is not only a function of crime, but also a function of security goods which depends on the level of income. This observation leads us to the next proposition. Proposition 2 In the presence of crime, consumption inequality rises over time. The proof of this proposition is straighforward. First note that if the crime rate is zero, there is no wedge between the marginal uilities. Next, note that the wedge between marginal utilities diminishes when security goods consumption rises, since the ratio of marginal utilities becomes closer to one. But security goods are normal goods 8 and hence consumption is smoother over time for higher levels of income. The intuition for this result is that lower income individuals will choose to save a smaller share of their income relatively to the rich, because crime creates a wedge in the inter-period marginal rate of substitution. Hence, total income in the second period shall be more unequal than in the rst period. In other words, even if the poor allocate a larger share of their income to protection in the rst period, they will not be as well protected as the rich, therefore the returns to savings for the poor is lower and thus total income inequality in the second period shall be higher than in the rst. In Figure 3, we ilustrate this result. The solid thick line shows that in the absence of crime individuals smooth consumption over time, i.e, 8 To see that security goods consumption rises with income look at the rst order condition with respect to security goods and apply the implied funtion theorem to get @s @y = u 00 (c 1) u 00 (c 1)+k 00 (s)u 0 (c > 0 2) 7

Figure 3: Crime Increases Consumption Inequality c 1 c 2 high crime low crime 1 no crime y consumption is the same in period 1 and 2. However as crime rises, it is optimal for poorer individuals to consume more in the rst period relative to the second, however this di erence in inter-temporal consumption choice declines with income for all levels of crime. Note that for the previous result we did not have to assume concavity of the protection technology function. Another result that we can obtain from this model which is connected to the results obtained for our static model is that lower income individuals would decide so save a smaler share of their income relatively to higher income individuals. Proposition 3 Crime convexi es savings, leading to higher total income inequality over time. (Proof in the appendix) This result shows that in a two period dynamic model the same intuition that we got from the static model holds. There, crime provoked higher disposable income inequality because the returns to acquiring security goods was higher for lower income individuals. Here crime breeds income inequality by inducing a lower saving rate to poor individuals. 8

2.3 Spatial Model We go back to our static setting in which individuals maximize their disposable income ^y after crime, security expenditures and now housing outlays h. The focus now is on spatial income inequality and for that matter the variable of interest is location choice of individuals. The total population in this economy is normalized to 1: Think of a metropolitan area in which individuals can choose to live in the city center with limited amount of housing 1, higher density and therefore a higher level of crime 2 k: The price of housing in the city is hence endogenous depending on the demand. The other option is to live in the suburbs where the crime rate is lower k which we normalize to zero. Here again individuals can engage in self protection by acquiring security goods and we also assume that the protection technology is concave. We also assume an exogenous distribution of income F (y): So the individual maximization problem can be written as follows. max u(^y) = ^y = y[1 k(1 (s)] s h Where the housing costs h are equal to the marginal cost of construction q if individuals choose to live in the suburbs, or equal to p the equilibrium price of housing in the city center. Now maximize disposable income by choosing security goods expenditures to obtain the optimal s. s = 0 1 1 ky To solve this model we use an equilibrium concept from the urban economics literature, which is the absence of spatial arbitrage. This consists on individuals not being able to improve upon moving to another area of town, in other words prices adjust so that the utility of individuals are equalized across suburbs and city center. Mathematically this condition can be written as y q = y[1 k(1 ( 0 1 1 )] ky 0 1 1 p ky Note that if crime is zero p = q: Now,we can rewrite this expression to obtain the demand price for city center housing for each income level y: p = q yk 1 ( 0 1 1 ky 0 1 1 ky The city center housing demand expression is intuitive. The city center housing price is equal to the housing price in the suburbs minus the share of income that is taken away by crime and protection. We are now ready to state our last proposition. 9

Proposition 4 In equilibrium the poor and the rich decide to locate in the city center and the middle class ees to the suburbs, breeding thereby spatial inequality in the city. To understand the economics behind this proposition we will go over the brief proof. We start by seeing how the demand price for city center housing varies with income and to do that we take its derivative with respect to income. @p @y = k[1 (s )] + k 00 (s ) y k 2 0 (s ) 00 (s ) The rst two terms of the expression above are negative and they correspond respectively to the loss of income to crime as income rises and the higher expenditures in security goods that richer people choose to do if they locate in the city. The last term is however positive and it corresponds to the protection from crime that individuals get from the security goods acquired. Note that the last term depends linearly and positively on income. So optimal demand prices for housing in the city center vary with income in the following manner. For zero income individuals the demand price for housing in the city is the same as the price in the suburbs q. Then as income rises the demand price starts declining until income reaches ey = k 1 f1 0 (s ) 00 (s )[1 (s )]g > 0 and demand 1 (s prices reach their lower bound at ~p = q ) f1 00 (s )[1 (s )]g s : 0 (s) After this level of income, the demand price starts rising as the e ect of having protection dominates. Since there is not enough housing in the city for all the population in the city center the equilibrium price p will be higher than ~p, so the middle class which is willing to pay a price close to ~p will be driven out of the city center by the poor and the rich. We depict the economics of this proof in Figure 4. 3 Empirical Evidence In this section, we provide empirical support for the most critical modelling assumptions. We also provide suggestive evidence that supports some of our main theoretical ndings. We start by asking if it is right to assume that individuals engage in self-protection and if better-o individuals do more of that. Next, we evaluate the plausibility of the concave protection technology assumption. Third, we look at correlations of crime and the saving rates for di erent income levels to check if our result that crime curbs more the savings of the poor goes through in the data. Finally, we use metropolitan area migration data to look for some suggestive evidence that supports the prediction of our spatial model. 10

p Figure 4: Crime Breeds Spatial Inequality q p* p ~ y ~ y 3.1 Evidence on the Static Model There are three key assumptions that we make in the static model (i) individuals acquire security goods to self-protect in the presence of crime, (ii) security good is a normal good, i.e. its consumption rises with income and (iii) security goods become somewhat redundant once one owns a lot of them. All of these assumptions are common sense, but in any case we look for evidence of them to get a better grasp if they are true. One consequence of the model is that the poor are more likely to be victimized so we look for evidence on that as well. Di Tella et al (2006) analyzed victimization survey data in Argentina through the 1990s, when crime rates more than doubled. Looking at the data, we can see that in the early 1990s - low crime era- 10% of the rich (population above the median income) and 2 % of the poor had alarms at their homes. In 2001 these numbers increased respectively to 25% and 8% for the rich and the poor. A similar pattern is observed for the percentage of population that hired security guards. These data suggests that (i) people do engage in costly self-protection activities to avoid crime and that (ii) rich people do more of that. 11

The remaining assumption necessary for the mechanism to go through is that there are negative returns to scale in the protection technology. One would believe that this is a good assumption if one realizes that for some type of crimes it is really hard to avoid victimization despite investment in security goods. Di Tella and coauthors (2006) show that after a massive crime increase in Argentina during the 1990s, victimization rates for the poor increased more than for the rich for home robberies. More speci cally, for the period 1990-1994, high-income households su ered a home victimization rate that was more than double than that observed by low-income families (11 percent versus 5 percent). After that period, low-income households su ered a signi cant increase in victimization, while high-income families showed a non-signi cant decline. The crosssectional di erence becomes insigni cant in those subsequent periods. Thus, the victimization rate of the low-income households caught up to the high-income rate during the decade. However, they also showed that victimization rates for on-street robberies rose by the same proportion for rich and poor since there is not much the rich can do besides mimicking the poor while walking on the street. This evidence suggests that there is so much that security goods can do for you and that concavity has to kick in at some point. An alternative assumption that would make the same mechanism work is that there are xed costs embedded in security goods, or that security goods costs are concave. Think of the cost of building a wall in front of a two bedroom house compared to the cost of building it to protect a four bedroom one. Both endeavors involve transporting the materials to the building site and perhaps the same amount of concrete - the most expensive material for building a wall. The marginal cost would be in terms of bricks and hours worked. A starker example is that to install a home alarm system in both types of houses may cost precisely the same. Or even to buy a German Shepard and feed it shall entail the same cost for two or four bedroom householders. Finally, we ought to address one of the consequences of our model, which is that despite the higher returns to investment in security goods for the poor, they still become more likely to be victimized than the rich. Di Tella et al. (2006) also addresses this issue. Their paper has two passages describing their evidence for Argentina and evidence by Levitt on the US that support our theoretical nding. "The rich start the decade with double the victimization rate than the poor (22 percent versus 11 percent, a di erence that is signi cant at the 1 percent level). By the year 2001, the rates had risen to approximately 40 percent and were statistically indistinguishable." 12

"The evidence suggests that the poor have been the recipients of most of the increase in crime. The increase in crime for the poor has been approximately 1.5 times that su ered by the rich. The di erence-indi erences change of the victimization rates between the rst and last period of our study is signi cant at the 5 percent level. As a comparison note that, for the US, Levitt (1999) nds that property crime has become more concentrated on the poor over time. The magnitude of our nding is in line with his estimates. He reports that while in the 1970 s highincome households were slightly more likely to be burglarized than lowincome households, by the 1990 s low income households were 60 percent more likely to be the victims of crime." 3.2 Evidence on the Investment Model The investment model has a clear and veri able empirical implication, that the di erence of saving rates of rich and poor is larger when crime rates are higher. Using data from the US Consumption Expenditure Survey of 1993 we are able to calculate saving rates for above and below median income individuals per state. We than look at how the saving rates of the rich and the poor and their di erence is correlated with state per-capita rates of property and violent crime obtained from the Uniform Crime Reports assembled by the FBI. These correlations provide suggestive evidence that this central result of our investment model takes place in reality. The Consumer Expenditure Survey provides data for more than 5000 households on their total yearly income and on their total consumption expenditure per quarter. To calculate the saving rates we simply calculate total yearly income minus the sum of total quarterly consumption expenditure and divide this number by total income. We also lter the data for outliers which we de ne as households who save more than 100% of their income and that consume more than 150% of their income. There are many reasons why we would like to exclude these observations for our sample such as the well know problems in self-reports for individuals that are in the extremes of the income distribution. Poor people tend to get cash transfers from family members and rich people tend to under-report income. We remain with 2832 observations after ltering the data. In Figure 4, we provide a simple correlation matrix using cross sectional variation for the US states for saving rates of the population above and below the median income for each state and two types of per-capita crime rates: property and violent. We look at past crime rates (3, 5 and 10 year averages) to help our inference of causality, since one could 13

Saving Rate of Rich Saving Rate of Poor Saving Rate Rich Minus Poor Figure 5: Crime and Saving Rates for the Rich and Poor: Correlation Matrix Vcrime Past 3Y Average Vcrime Past 5Y Average Vcrime Past 10Y Average Pcrime Past 3Y Average Pcrime Past 5Y Average Pcrime Past 10Y Average -9.9% -10.3% -9.9% 0.8% -0.2% -0.2% -22.7% -23.1% -21.5% -7.6% -7.3% -9.9% 17.9% 18.1% 16.7% 7.6% 7.0% 9.4% possibly think of a story for reverse causality. The picture tells us that saving rates of the poor are much more correlated with crime rates than that of the rich. More speci cally, the correlation between savings of the poor and of the rich with 10 year violent crime average is respectively -21,5% and -9.9%. While the correlation with past 10 year averages of property crime is smaller for both types of households, we still observe the same pattern. The correlation with savings of the poor is -9.9% and of the rich is approximately zero. Also, in the last row of Figure 5, we can see that the di erence between saving rates of the poor and of the rich is positively correlated with violent crime (16.5%) and with property crime (9.4%). This evidence is consistent with our theoretical ndings, which predicts that in high crime areas, poor people will allocate a larger share of their income to acquiring security goods and forgo savings, whereas this e ect will be smaller for the rich. We proceed with our analyzes by studying the data more carefully. There are two observations that stand out, Washington DC for the very high crime rates and Oklahoma, for which we have very few household observations, this state displays a di erence in saving rates between rich and poor of more than four standard deviations above the mean. We now proceed by excluding these two outliers and looking at scatter plots of crime measures and di erence of saving rates for rich and poor. In Figure 5 Panel A, we display a plot of violent crime rates per 100 thousand inhabitants and the di erence and in Panel B we show the same varible on the horizontal axis and property crime rates on the vertical axis. Without these two outliers the correlations do drop around 3 percentage points, for example the correlation with 10 year average of property crime drops from 9.4% to 6.3% and for violent crime the correlation drops from 16.7% to 13.9%. Nonetheless they remain positive and signi cant. Running a simple regression of the di erence in saving rates on violent crime yields a t-statistic of 11, dropping the two outliers the t-statistc drops to 9. A similar pattern is observed for property crime. The regression without excluding the outliers yields a t-statistic of 6, while after dropping the outliers the t-stistic drops to 4. 14

3.3 Evidence on the Spatial Model In this section, we present some evidence to provide some support for our theoretical nding that crime leads to spatial inequality in the city center. To do that we look at migration data for the US metropolitan areas and check if the middle class is indeed more likely to move to the suburbs when crime is rising and if the poor and the rich are more likely to stay put. We also look at the reverse migration ow, we look to see if the poor and the rich are more likely to move to the city center than the middle class. In Figure 7, one can see the percentage of the population living in metropolitan areas in the US that moved from central cities to suburbs and from suburbs to central cities sorted by income level. We use data from the Current Population Survey from 1990 to 1995, a period when crime rates were still on the rise and for which the CPS has migration data sorted by income and top coded at a high enough level $100,000 9. In the table we can see that the households earning between $30,000 to $70,000 are more likely to move to the suburbs and the households with earnings below $30,000 are more likely to move to the central city relatively to the other income brackets. Although, we do not provide information on the population already living across di erent areas of the metropolitan areas, we believe that looking at changes in the population during an era of rising crime has a avor of a di erence in di erence estimation and hence entails suggestive evidence to support our model. 9 1994 US dollars. 15

Poor (below $30,000) Middle ($30,000-70,000) Rich (above $70,000) Figure 7: Within Metro Area Migration 1990 to 1995 Movers from Central City to Suburbs % of Population Living in Metro Areas Movers from Suburbs to Central City % of Population Living in Metro Areas 3.0% 1.9% 4.0% 1.7% 3.7% 1.7% 4 Data and Methodology for Estimating the Impact of Crime on Inequality The theoretical mechanisms we have described and the evidence that support them discussed above give no quantitative measure of the e ect we are studying. To try to address this concern and quantify the impact of crime on inequality, we need some source of exogenous variation that a ects crime only, with no other impact on inequality other than through crime. For this purpose we use a variable called overcrowding litigation. In the US, when prison conditions deteriorated, human right groups would le judicial cases against the state responsible for that prison. In some cases, more precisely twelve states, the entire state prison system was under court order concerning overcrowding. According to Levitt (1996) in the three years prior to the initial lling of litigation in these twelve states, prison population growth was higher than the national average by 2.3%. In the three years after the lling of litigation, prisoner growth rates were 2.5 percentage points lower than the national average. In the three years after a nal court order, growth rates lagged the national average by 4.8%. Therefore, keeping crime constant across the nation, six years after the petition was led, states that had their prison system under court control would have incapacitated 24% less criminals than the national average. This measure gives us an idea of how big the e ect of our instrument is. Levitt (1996) uses this instrument to estimate that every non-incapacitated criminal produces on average 15 crimes per year. To get a better feel of the numbers, it is useful to look at the following back of the envelope calculation. During the period that we estimate our regressions 1970-1994, the average prison population in the US was around 750,000 persons. Twenty four percent less incapacitation in 12 out of 50 states in the nation imply an increase of 700,00 crimes in a period of six years, in these twelve states. Hence our instrument does 16

provide a meaningful variation for crime. We believe it is plausible to assume, that overcrowded prisons and less incapacitation has no other rst order impact on inequality rather than through crime 10. One caveat to that statement is that prisoners are not taken into account in Gini index calculations. Therefore we have to worry about the mechanical e ect. If imprisonment is biased towards very low income people, then letting criminals free should increase the Gini mechanically. The average six years growth of the prison population in our sample is of 400,000 prisoners which account for 0.2% of the US population on average in the period. Therefore if all prisoners had zero income, this mechanical e ect accounts for 0.002 point in the Gini. Hence our estimates should be read taking into account this small negative bias. However, our estimates are of one order of magnitude larger than this mechanical e ect, so the purpose of this comment is to note its lack of importance for our main results. Data on state crime rates are based on the number reported to the police over the course of the year, as compiled annually by the Uniform Crime Reports. Although victimization data would be preferable to reported crimes theoretically, such data is not available 11. Reported crime data is available for the seven crime categories: murder and nonnegligent homicide, forcible rape, aggravated assault, robbery, burglary, larceny and motor vehicle theft. The rst three are considered vilent crime and the latter four property crime.the use of reported crime data instead of victimization can lead to a bias, which we try to correct to by regressing time changes of gini on changes of crime, we also believe that after controlling for state and time xed e ects in addition to time di erencing the data, it is unlikely that systematic measurement error is driving the results. To measure income inequality we use the Gini Coe cient constructed by Galbraith and Hale (2006) for the U.S. states. The authors construct the index as follows 12 : at 10-year intervals, the Census Bureau (2005) 10 It is important to make the caveat, that instrumental variable estimates are many times imperfect, since the exogeneity of the instrument is hardly ever full with certainty. Alberto Alesina has suggested that if in more unequal states, more crimes are likely to be commited and if no more prisons are built to address this concern, then perhaps there could be some correlation between inequality and overcrowding litigation, rather than through crime. Although, it is usually possible to cook up a not so implausible theory about the non-exogeneity of an instrument, we believe that the impact of these theories are of second order and hence we proceed with the estimation. 11 See O Brien (1985) and Gove, Hughes and Geerken (1985) for di erent views on the validity of the use of reported crime data 12 We give a brief description of how the authors estimate the gini coe cients here, but for more details see original paper. 17

produces a measure of income inequality at the state level for1969, 1979, 1989, and 1999. To move from decennial to annual data, the authors nd an annual dataset that measures wages or incomes for a large proportion of the population of each state, they then create a panel of inequality measures using this underlying data, and use the decennial Census values to transform these yearly inequality measures into estimates of the appropriate Gini coe cient. The ideal dataset for constructing state inequality measures would contain individual level income data for every American by state in every year. Such data do not exist, however, the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) in the U.S. Department of Commerce collects data necessary to create internally consistent measures of state pay inequality for the last three decades. For every year since 1969, the BEA has compiled data on wages and employment across dozens of industrial classi cations for every state. We now describe in detail the instrument we chose to disentangle the causal relationship between crime and inequality. The rst case on overcrowding litigation was led in 1965 on the grounds of cruel and unusual punishment. Similar lawsuits took place in 47 states and in DC. Of the approximately 70 cases brought to court, all have achieved at least partial victory but 6. Court orders on overcrowding took form typically by an imposition of population caps, leaving to the administrators to determine the means to comply with the court order (early release programs, construction of new facilities, fewer o enders sent to prison). Only in extreme cases, judges mandated the release of prisoners. The court frequently judged compliance to be inadequate leading to the further step of contempt orders, or court appointed monitors. In twelve states the entire prison system fell under the court order concerning overcrowding. We, as in Levitt (1996), restrict our instrument solely to the states where the entire state prison system fell under the control of the courts, since this states will not be able to comply with court orders on overcrowding simply by rearranging prisoners across prisons within the state. Levitt captured the prison litigation status by six indicator variables and we proceed similarly here. The categories are as follows: (1) Pre lling: no prison overcrowding litigation led in the state. (2) Filed: litigation led, but no court decision. (3) Preliminary decision: a court decision is available, but is under appeal. (4) Final decision: no further appeals. (5) Further action: subsequent court intervention on the issue of overcrowding, including appointment of special monitors, contempt orders. (6)Released by court: dismissal of case or relinquishing of court s oversight of prisons. In Figure 8 the categories that originate the indicator variables that we use as instruments for crime are fully described. 18

Figure 8: Prison Overcrowding Litigation Status 1971-1993 States with Entire Prison Systems Under Court Rule Prefilling Filed Prelim. Decision Final Decision Further Action Released by Court Alabama 71-73 74-75 76-77 78 79-83 84-93 Alaska 71-85 86-89 - 90-93 - - Arkansas - - - 71-73 74-81 82-93 Delaware 71-87 - - 88-91 92-93 - Florida 71 72-74 75-76 77-79 80-93 - Mississipi - 71-73 - 74-93 - - New Mexico 71-76 77-79 8089 90 91-93 - Oklahoma 71 72-76 - 77-85 - 86-93 Rhode Island 71-73 74-76 - 77-85 86-93 - South Carolina 71-81 82-84 85-90 91-93 - - Tennesse 71-79 80-81 - 82-84 85-93 - Texas 71-77 78-79 80-84 85-91 92-93 - Source: Levitt (1996) There is wide variation in the timing of prison overcrowding litigation status across the di erent states. Final court decisions were taken as early as 1971 and as late as 1991. The state prison systems that fell under court order are predominantly Southern though not exclusively so. To avoid major bias from the use of the cross-state variation we regress changes in addition to use state xed e ects. 5 Estimating the Impact of Crime on Inequality Having described the data in the previous section we can now proceed to estimate the model, using an instrumental variable technique. We rst concentrate on checking if our instrument is well correlated with crime. Next, we proceed to the instrumental varible estimation. To check for the correlation between our instrument and crime, we look at the following rst stage regression 13. log crime s;t = + 5X ' i Dummy i;s;t 1 + i=1 5X i Dummy i;s;t 2 where the dependent variable is the percentage change in per-capita crime rates, which is regressed on a constant, the rst lag and the second lag of the change in the ve overcrowding litigation status dummies described in the previous section. This is a panel data regression and hence the index s represent the state, the index t represent the year and i 13 Our approach to how to use the instrument follows Levitt (1996). i=1 19

Figure 9: First Stage Regression Dependent Variable: DLOG(CRIME) Coef. t-stat C 0.030 9.160 D[Prefilling(-1)] 0.338 10.551 D[Filed(-1)] 0.326 8.401 D[Prelim. Decision(-1)] 0.297 5.985 D[Final Decision(-1)] 0.293 7.368 D[Further Action(-1)] 0.142 3.170 D[Prefilling(-2)] 0.118 3.630 D[Filed(-2)] 0.092 2.365 D[Prelim. Decision(-2)] 0.076 1.515 D[Final Decision(-2)] 0.102 2.514 D[Further Action(-2)] 0.013 0.280 R-squared 0.114 F-statistic 14.25 N. Obs 1117 Cross Sections 51 indexes the overcrowding dummies. In Figure 9 we display the results of this rst stage regression. The t-statistics of the overcrowding litigation signi cant coe cients range from 2 to as high as 10. More importantly the F-statistic for the regression is 14.25 and hence according to Staiger and Stock (1997) we shall not worry about the weak instrument problem. Since the impact of crime on inequality may take some time to go through as individuals could take a while to realize that there is a permanent change in place and therefore a change in the allocation of income may take a while to materialize, we use lags in our main estimation. This also contributes to mitigate endogeneity worries. We now proceed to estimate the main regression: log(gini s;t Gini s;t j ) = + log crime s;t j +X t + + + " t Where log crime; stands for the yearly percentage change of the per-capita crime rate, s for state, t for time and j for the lag. X t are the are the socioeconomic controls 14 used, denotes the time e ects 14 We control for the standard deviation of the percentage of the population that is white, black, American Indian, Asian and Paci c Islander, which is a positive non-linear function of the percentage non-white population. The advantage of this 20

Figure 10: The Impact of Crime on Inequality Dependent Variable: LOG(GINI(3))-LOG(GINI) D(LOG(CRIME)) Coef. t-stat F-Stat OLS TE CSE 0.019 3.681 16.061 IV TE 0.047 2.375 33.812 IV TE CSE 0.105 3.149 14.871 Dependent Variable: LOG(GINI(4))-LOG(GINI) D(LOG(CRIME)) Coef. t-stat F-Stat OLS TE CSE 0.018 3.317 13.431 IV TE 0.060 2.662 24.049 IV TE CSE 0.105 3.017 14.069 Dependent Variable: LOG(GINI(5))-LOG(GINI) D(LOG(CRIME)) N. Obs 1011, Cross Sections 51 Coef. t-stat F-Stat OLS TE CSE 0.016 2.829 15.122 IV TE 0.075 3.000 21.703 IV TE CSE 0.084 2.487 16.757 and the state xed e ects, which given our speci cation act as a state speci c time trend because our dependent variable is in log changes. In Table 8 we present estimates for, the elasticity of inequality to crime, for three di erent speci cations. We rst run an OLS regression using time and xed e ects, in which we nd a positive signi cant coe cient of one order of magnitude smaller than our IV estimates. We then run the IV speci cation with time e ects TE. The last speci cation we run IV TE CSE also controls for cross section e ects which here work as state speci c time trends. We do this for lags j = 3; 4; 5:Our estimates in Figure 10 suggest that a doubling of property crime, should increase the gini coe cient by about 10% from 3 to 5 years later. The coe cient of interest is signi cant across all speci cations with t-statistics close to or above 3. Perhaps the best robustness check to perform to check the validity of our estimates is to look the same regressions using as dependent variables di erent types of crime. In doing that, we nd that the results hold perfectly for property crime. For violent crime the standard errors grow measure is that it takes into account other inter-racial di erences in addition to the black and white divide. We also control for the percentage of the population who has a high school diploma minus the share of the population with Bachelors degree. This variable shall capture the variation of inequality due to the college wage premium. The controls yield the expected sign and excluding them from the regressions does not change the qualitative results. 21

more and we nd positive coe cents of the same order of magnitude signi cat at 20%. 6 Conclusion In this study, we show theoretically that crime distorts the opitmal allocation of income di erently across the income spectrum and thereby breeds inequality. We have also provided suggestive evidence of the mechanisms we describe theoretically. Finally, we have quanti ed the impact of crime on inequality using overcrowding litigation as an instrument and noted its quantitative importance. In light of this work, the way we think about the relationship between crime and inequality should probably change. Causality could be present in both directions and the channel from crime to inequality appears to be of rst order. 7 Appendix Proof. (Proposition 1) The maximization yields the following FOC: @ ^y = @s yk0 (s) 1 = 0: Applying the implicity funtion theorem we obtain @y = 0 (s) @ ^y > 0: Note that ^y is increasing on y; = [1 k(1 (s))]: @s y 00 (s) @y Now we have all ingredients to see that crime convexi es disposable income. @ 2^y @y = 2 k0 (s) @y @s > 0 Proof. (Proposition 3) Take the rst order conditions. F OC I : u0(c 1 )+ R[1 k(1 (s))]u 0 (c 2 ) = 0 and F OC s : u0(c 1 )+RIk 0 (s)u 0 (c 2 ) = 0: 1 k(1 (s)) The FOCs an be combined to I = 0: Now apply the k 0 (s) implicit function theorem to this expression to obtain @I @y = f[k 0 (s)] 2 k 00 (s)[1 k(1 (s)]g @s @y > 0 [k 0 (s)] 2 f[k 0 (s)] 2 k 00 (s)[1 k(1 (s)]g @s since @s < 0: k 0 (s)] 2 k 00 (s)[1 k(1 (s)] Now that we have showned that savings increase with income we can show that in the presence of crime it increases at an increasing rate. @I = k 0 (s)] 2 @ 2 I @y 2 = 2k 2 00 (s) @s @y k00 (s)[1 k(1 (s)] f[k 0 (s)] 2 f[k 0 (s)] 2 k 00 (s)[1 k(1 (s)]g @s @I g2 > 0 @I 22

References [1] BARRERA, F., IBANEZ, A., "Does Violence Reduce Investment in Education?: A Theoretical and Empirical Approach". Documento CEDE 2004-27, Universidad de los Andes. [2] BUREAU OF ECONOMIC ANALYSIS, (2005), "Regional Economic Accounts: Annual State, Personal Income", Online, Available: http://www.bea.doc.gov/bea/regional/spi/. [3] BOURGUIGNON, F., NÚÑEZ, J. and SÁNCHEZ, F., (2003), "What Part of the Income distribution matters for explainin property crime? The case of Colombia", Documento CEDE ISSN 1657-7191 [4] BECKER, G. (1968), "Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach". Journal of Political Economy, vol. 76, pp. 169-217. [5] CULLEN, J.B., LEVITT, S. (1999), "Crime, Urban Flight, And The Consequences For Cities", Review of Economics and Statistics, vol. 81, pp.159-169 [6] DI TELLA, R., GALIANI, S. and SCHARGRODSKY, E., (2006), "Crime Distribution and Victim Behavior during a Crime Wave ", mimeo Harvard Business School [7] EHRLICH, I. (1973), "Participation in Illegitimate Activities: A Theoretical and Empirical Investigation". Journal of Political Economy, vol. 81, pp. 521-565. [8] KELLY, M. (2000), "Inequality and Crime", Review of Economics and Statistics, vol.82, pp.530-539. [9] LEVITT, S. (1999), "The Changing Relationship between income and Crime Victimization", FRBNY Economic Policy Review, September 1999 [10] LEVITT, S. (1996), "The E ect of Prision Population Size on Crime Rates: Evidence from Prision Overcrowding Litigation", Quarterly Journal of Economics [11] FAJNZYLBER, P., LEDERMAN, D. and LOYAZA, N. (2002), "What Causes Violent Crime?" European Economic Review v46, n7, pp. 1323-57 [12] FIELD, E., "Entitled to Work: Urban Property Rights and the Labor Supply in Peru", Quarterly Journal of Economics, November 2007. [13] GALBRAITH, J., HALE, T. (2006), "State Income Inequality and Presidential Election Turnout and Outcomes", UTIP Working Paper 33 [14] GOVE, W., HUGHES, M., GEERKEN, M. (1985) " Are Uniform Crime Reports a valid indicator of the Index Crimes? An A rmative Answer with Minor Quali cations," Criminology XXIII, 451-23

501 [15] GROGGER, J. (1997), "Local Violence, Educational Attainment and Teacher Pay", NBER Working Paper No. 6003 [16] O BRIEN, R. (1985), "Crime and Victimization Data", Berverly Hills, CA: Sage, 1985 [17] STAIGER, D. and STOCK, J. (1997), "Instrumental Variable Regression with Weak Instruments", Econometrica 65(3): pp. 557-586 [18] WILSON, J. (1987), "The Truly Disadvantaged: The Inner City, The Underclass, and Public Policy". Chicago: University of Chicago Press. 24