Course: Economic Policy with an Emphasis on Tax Policy

Similar documents
Labor Market Laws and Intra-European Migration

OECD ECONOMIC SURVEY OF LITHUANIA 2018 Promoting inclusive growth

Big Government, Small Government and Corruption: an European Perspective. Alina Mungiu-Pippidi Hertie School of Governance

2.2. From social efficiency to social welfare - Equity issues (Stiglitz ch.5, Gruber ch.2)

Curing Europe s Growing Pains: Which Reforms?

DANMARKS NATIONALBANK

2. Welfare economics and the rationale for public intervention 2.3. Equity: From Social Efficiency to Social Welfare

Supplementary figures

Are Labour Markets in the New Member States sufficiently flexible for EMU?

Council of Europe Annual Penal Statistics SPACE I & SPACE II Facts, figures and tendencies. Marcelo F. Aebi & Natalia Delgrande

EU Innovation strategy

Social capital and social cohesion in a perspective of social progress: the case of active citizenship

The economic outlook for Europe and Central Asia, including the impact of China

Education and Wage Inequality in Europe. Fifth EU Framework Programme for Research. Centre des Conferences Brussels. Final Meeting 22 nd Sept 2005.

Globalisation and flexicurity

Which policies for improved access to employment? Main findings of the OECD project JOBS for YOUTH

SPACE I 2016 Facts & Numbers

Key figures for 2012 In brief % 13% Survey 1/4

Convergence: a narrative for Europe. 12 June 2018

South-East Europe s path to convergence

Perceptions of Welfare in the European Union

SPACE I 2015 Facts & Figures

Challenges for Baltics as for the Eurozone countries having Advanced Economy status

European Union Passport

Off to a Good Start? Youth Labour Market Transitions in OECD Countries

Widening of Inequality in Japan: Its Implications

CLOUDY OUTLOOK FOR GROWTH IN EMERGING EUROPE AND CENTRAL ASIA

INTRODUCTION TO THE COURSE; ECONOMICS OF MIGRATION, INTRODUCTION, TRENDS AND CONCEPTS

The regional and urban dimension of Europe 2020

ARE EU EXPORTS GENDER-BLIND? SOME KEY FEATURES OF WOMEN PARTICIPATION IN EXPORTING ACTIVITIES IN THE EU 1

Value added trade dynamics in the wider Europe before and after the crisis:

Evaluating migration policy effectiveness

Reform agenda for 2017: Overview and country notes

Inventory of OECD Integrity and Anti-Corruption Related Data

Migration, Mobility and Integration in the European Labour Market. Lorenzo Corsini

Migration and the European Job Market Rapporto Europa 2016

Women in the Labour Force: How well is Europe doing? Christopher Pissarides, Pietro Garibaldi Claudia Olivetti, Barbara Petrongolo Etienne Wasmer

How does education affect the economy?

Francis Green and Golo Henseke

2019 OECD ECONOMIC SURVEY OF THE SLOVAK REPUBLIC

25 years of the European Single Market. Study funded by the Danish Business Authority

Implementing an ABC System: The Experience of the Czech Republic

Extended Findings. Finland. ecfr.eu/eucoalitionexplorer. Question 1: Most Contacted

EUROPEAN ECONOMY VS THE TRAP OF THE EUROPE 2020 STRATEGY

Options for Romanian and Bulgarian migrants in 2014

XII BGK Conference. Discussion Panel : Strategic Directions for Regional Development. Emilia Skrok Jan Gąska

Fertility rate and employment rate: how do they interact to each other?

Transatlantic Divergences in Globalisation and the China Factor

Identification of the respondent: Fields marked with * are mandatory.

THE RECAST EWC DIRECTIVE

EuCham Charts. October Youth unemployment rates in Europe. Rank Country Unemployment rate (%)

ICT Strategic Study Part 1 Sectoral Outline May 2015

A2 Economics. Standard of Living and Economic Progress. tutor2u Supporting Teachers: Inspiring Students. Economics Revision Focus: 2004

Income inequality the overall (EU) perspective and the case of Swedish agriculture. Martin Nordin

GLOBAL MONITORING REPORT 2015/2016

The Good, the Bad and the Ugly: Controlling Corruption in the European Union

Asylum Trends. Appendix: Eurostat data

Asylum Trends. Appendix: Eurostat data

Asylum Trends. Appendix: Eurostat data

Asylum Trends. Appendix: Eurostat data

FIBRE CROPS WG REPORT FOR PHASE IX ( )

Through the Financial Crisis

The global and regional policy context: Implications for Cyprus

Asylum Trends. Appendix: Eurostat data

INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION

PUBLIC LIMITE EN COUNCIL OF THE EUROPEAN UNION. Brussels, 22 February /07 LIMITE FAUXDOC 2 COMIX 71

The determinants of Entrepreneurship Gender Gaps: A cross-country Analysis

Asylum Trends. Appendix: Eurostat data

Asylum Trends. Appendix: Eurostat data

The Construction Industry in Central and Eastern Europe Bucharest, May 19 th 2014

Working Party on Territorial Indicators

Varieties of Capitalism and Welfare States Policy and Performance

UNDER EMBARGO UNTIL 9 APRIL 2018, 15:00 HOURS PARIS TIME

MIC Forum: The Rise of the Middle Class

The Intrastat System

Asylum Levels and Trends: Europe and non-european Industrialized Countries, 2003

GDP per capita in purchasing power standards

Upgrading workers skills and competencies: policy strategies

The Boom-Bust in the EU New Member States: The Role of Fiscal Policy

CORRUPTION, SHADOW ECONOMY AND ECONOMIC GROWTH: AN EMPIRICAL SURVEY ACROSS THE EUROPEAN UNION COUNTRIES

Meeting of the OECD Council at Ministerial Level

THE CORRUPTION AND THE ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE

Use of Identity cards and Residence documents in the EU (EU citizens)

Gender pay gap in public services: an initial report

A2 Economics. Enlargement Countries and the Euro. tutor2u Supporting Teachers: Inspiring Students. Economics Revision Focus: 2004

Brexit. Alan V. Deardorff University of Michigan. For presentation at Adult Learning Institute April 11,

3-The effect of immigrants on the welfare state

The effect of migration in the destination country:

Europe divided? Attitudes to immigration ahead of the 2019 European elections. Dr. Lenka Dražanová

The Financial Crises of the 21st Century

2. The table in the Annex outlines the declarations received by the General Secretariat of the Council and their status to date.

WORLDWIDE DISTRIBUTION OF PRIVATE FINANCIAL ASSETS

Size and Development of the Shadow Economy of 31 European and 5 other OECD Countries from 2003 to 2013: A Further Decline

Proposal for a new repartition key

WILL CHINA S SLOWDOWN BRING HEADWINDS OR OPPORTUNITIES FOR EUROPE AND CENTRAL ASIA?

A Competitive Denmark:

International Migration and the Welfare State. Prof. Panu Poutvaara Ifo Institute and University of Munich

The Extraordinary Extent of Cultural Consumption in Iceland

Austerity and Gender Equality Policy: a Clash of Policies? Francesca Bettio University of Siena Italy ( ENEGE Network (

European patent filings

Transcription:

Course: Economic Policy with an Emphasis on Tax Policy Instructors: Vassilis T. Rapanos email address: vrapanos@econ.uoa.gr Georgia Kaplanoglou email address: gkaplanog@econ.uoa.gr Course website: http://eclass.uoa.gr/courses/econ208/ 1 Rapanos-Kaplanoglou

Economic theory and economic policy Introductory notes 2

Economic policy Economic policy analyses government economic intervention The use of taxes, expenditures, regulations, etc. It studies how decisions are made The processes through which government decisions are reached It analyses what decisions should be made The decisions that would be in the best interest of society 3

The 4 Questions of Economic Policy Analysis 1. Why should government intervene? 2. How should government intervene? 3. What are the effects of government intervention? 4. Why is government acting this way? 4

Economic Policies Are Everywhere Economic policies constantly affect our everyday life: Through price interventions: taxes (sales tax on what we buy, sin taxes on cigarettes or alcohol, income tax on what we earn, property taxes, etc.), transfers (Pensions, Unemployment benefits, etc.), public provision of public goods (schools & education, Security, etc.),... Through regulation: on what we eat and consume (food regulations, environmental regulation), on the way we drive,, on the labor market (minimum wage, labor laws, etc.), on how we educate our children (minimum education laws, etc.)... Economic policies may be very broad in scope: E.g. tax reforms, employment in public sector, health care programs, etc. 5

When should the government intervene in the economy? 1) Market Failures: Market economy sometimes fails to deliver an outcome that is efficient and Government intervention may improve the situation 2) Redistribution: Market economy generates substantial inequality in economic resources across individuals and Government intervention may help reduce inequality by redistributing resources through taxes and transfers Part of our lectures focuses on Market Failures, Another part of the class focuses on Redistribution 6

Main Market Failures 1) Public good provision and Externalities: (example: national defense, greenhouse carbon emissions) ) require government interventions (Pigouvian taxes and subsidies) 2) Imperfect competition: (example: monopoly) ) requires regulation (typically studied in Industrial Organization) 3) Imperfect or Asymmetric Information: (example: adverse selection in health insurance may require mandatory insurance) 4) Individual failures: People are not always rational. This is analyzed in behavioral economics, field in huge expansion (example: myopic people may not save enough for retirement) 7

Inequality and Redistribution Even if market outcome is Pareto efficient, society might not be happy with the market outcome because market equilibrium might generate very high economic disparity across individuals Governments use taxes and transfers to redistribute from rich to poor and reduce inequality Redistribution through taxes and transfers might reduce incentives to work (efficiency costs). So, redistribution may create an equity-efficiency trade-off. It has been observed in recent years that Pre-tax, pretransfer income inequality has soared in many countries and it has become an important issue in policy debates. 8

How does Government Intervene 1. Public Provision: The government can provide the good directly, in order to potentially attain the level of consumption that maximizes social welfare (example is defense) 2. Tax or Subsidize Private Sale or Purchase: Tax goods that are overproduced (e.g. carbon tax) and subsidized goods underproduced (e.g., subsidies for flu vaccines) 3. Restrict or Mandate Private Sale or Purchase: Restrict the private sale or purchase of overproduced goods (e.g. fuel efficiency requirements), or mandate the private purchase of underproduced goods (e.g., auto insurance) 4. Public Financing of Private Provision: Governments pays for the good but private sector supplies it (e.g., privately provided health insurance paid for by government) 9

Methods of analysis of government intervention Economic policy analysis uses models to investigate policy The possibilities for experimentation are limited Past experience cannot always be relied upon Models can take two forms Partial equilibrium models focus only on one or two markets taking behaviour elsewhere in the economy as given General equilibrium models describe a complete economic system with prices equilibrating supply and demand on all markets simultaneously 10

Methods of analysis of government intervention Actions of economic agents Consumers maximize private welfare Firms maximize profits The government chooses policy instruments Reactions to a policy change The reactions of economic agents are predicted through the solutions to the optimizations The independent decision-making of agents distinguishes economic models Agents do not respond mechanically 11

2.0 General Government Fical Balance (% GDP) 0.0-2.0-4.0-6.0-8.0-10.0-12.0-14.0-16.0 2009 2016 12

200.00 General Government Gross Debt (% GDP) (Countries subjected to programmes) 180.00 160.00 140.00 120.00 100.00 80.00 60.00 40.00 20.00 0.00 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 Ireland Greece Cyprus Portugal Euro area 13

General Government Revenue (% GDP) 60.0 50.0 40.0 30.0 20.0 10.0 0.0 FIN FRA DNK SWE BEL GRC AUT ITA HUN DEU NLD SVN PRT LUX EST CZE SVK GBR POL ESP LVA IRL 2009 2016 14

100% Structure of Government Revenues (2016) 90% 1.8 80% 70% 60% 7.2 16.6 20.5 28.1 27.9 31.5 32.3 27.1 23.9 24.1 31.3 29.2 35.4 34.9 30.3 37.1 35.9 34.4 28.5 36.8 36.4 35.9 50% 40% 30% 20% 87.4 80.5 72.7 70.2 55.2 62.9 62.0 59.5 58.6 58.2 59.7 57.7 55.9 56.4 54.5 53.9 56.6 52.3 53.0 51.3 49.5 51.0 45.8 10% 0% DNK SWE IRL GBR ITA LUX BEL ESP PRT LVA FIN AUT EST FRA GRC NLD HUN DEU POL SVN CZE SVK LTU Taxes Net social contributions Other 15

General Government Expenditures (% GDP) 60.0 50.0 40.0 30.0 20.0 10.0 0.0 FRA FIN DNK BEL AUT SWE ITA GRC HUN SVN PRT DEU NLD ESP GBR SVK POL LUX EST CZE LVA LTU IRL 2009 2016 16

17 Structure of general government expenditures by function, 2015 General public services Defence Public Economic order and affairs safety Environm ental protection Housing and communit y amenities Health Recreatio n, culture and religion Education Social protection Austria 13.3 1.1 2.7 11.9 0.9 0.7 15.5 2.4 9.6 42.0 Belgium 15.1 1.6 3.3 12.0 1.6 0.6 14.2 2.2 11.9 37.5 Czech Rep 10.3 2.2 4.4 15.6 2.6 1.6 18.2 3.2 11.8 30.1 Denmark 13.5 2.0 1.8 6.7 0.8 0.4 15.6 3.2 12.8 43.0 Estonia 10.6 4.7 4.5 11.8 1.7 0.9 13.7 4.9 15.1 32.1 Finland 14.9 2.4 2.2 8.3 0.4 0.7 12.6 2.6 11.0 44.9 France 11.0 3.1 2.9 10.0 1.8 1.9 14.3 2.3 9.6 43.1 Germany 13.5 2.3 3.6 7.1 1.4 0.9 16.3 2.3 9.6 43.1 Greece 17.8 4.9 3.8 16.0 2.7 0.4 8.2 1.3 7.8 37.0 Hungary 17.8 1.1 4.1 17.3 2.5 2.2 10.6 4.3 10.3 29.9 Ireland 13.9 1.2 3.7 11.5 1.4 2.0 19.3 2.0 12.4 32.7 Italy 16.6 2.4 3.7 8.1 1.9 1.2 14.1 1.5 7.9 42.6 Latvia 14.0 2.7 5.4 11.5 1.9 2.6 10.3 4.4 16.2 31.0 Lithuania 12.5 3.8 4.5 10.4 1.5 0.9 16.5 2.7 15.4 31.7 Luxembourg 10.5 0.7 2.4 11.9 2.6 1.2 10.9 2.8 12.4 44.8 Netherlands 11.1 2.5 4.0 8.8 3.2 0.7 17.7 3.1 12.0 36.8 Poland 11.8 3.8 5.3 11.1 1.5 1.7 11.2 2.7 12.6 38.3 Portugal 16.8 2.2 4.3 10.5 0.8 1.0 12.7 1.6 12.4 37.8 Slovak Rep 14.2 2.3 5.2 13.9 2.3 1.9 15.7 2.3 9.3 33.0 Slovenia 14.2 1.8 3.2 12.4 2.1 1.3 14.0 3.4 11.6 36.1 Spain 14.9 2.2 4.6 10.0 2.0 1.1 14.2 2.6 9.3 39.1 Sweden 14.1 2.3 2.6 8.4 0.6 1.5 13.8 2.2 13.0 41.6 UK 10.6 5.0 4.7 7.1 1.8 1.1 17.8 1.5 12.0 38.4

70.0 Production Costs (% GDP) 60.0 50.0 40.0 30.0 13.5 12.6 15.9 8.8 12.7 12.4 10.8 11.8 9.1 11.0 12.3 11.5 7.5 8.9 9.2 11.3 9.8 10.9 10.2 10.3 9.8 20.0 8.6 7.3 10.0 0.0 Other production costs Costs of goods and services used and financed by government Compensation of government employees Total production costs 18

25.0 Value added in General government 2013 20.0 15.0 10.0 5.0 0.0 19

Methods of analysis of government intervention Once a model is constructed its implications are derived Logical reasoning is used to derive formally correct conclusions These conclusions are interpreted in terms of the initial policy question The institutional setting is invariably the mixed economy Individual decisions are respected but the government intervenes A range of objectives can be assigned to the government 20

Analyzing Policy The effect of a policy is determined by contrasting the equilibrium with the policy to equilibrium without Policy can be analyzed from a positive or a normative perspective Positive analysis is about explaining why there is a public sector, how government policies are chosen and how these policies affect the economy An example is analyzing the effect of a corporate tax on inward investment 21

Analyzing Policy Normative analysis investigates what the best policy is, and aims to provide a guide to good government An example would be an assessment of whether the level of pensions should be indexed to average wages Normative analysis assumes the government has an objective and chooses its actions to best achieve the objective Positive and normative analysis are not distinct To evaluate a policy (normative) its effect must be determined (positive) 22

Analyzing Policy The government s objective is often taken to be the aggregate level of welfare This raises questions about welfare measurement Any aggregate measure assumes some degree of comparability of individual utility It is possible to proceed assuming utility is comparable and to derive general principles that apply for any degree of comparability 23

Basic concepts of welfare economics Determination of economic criteria for public policy evaluation has been a subject of great debate. The difficulty stems from the inability to decide on purely economic grounds how the goods and services produced in an economy should be distributed among individuals. Issues of distribution and equity are political and moral as well as economic in nature. 24

Social welfare function Classical philosophers such as Bentham long ago developed the concept of a social welfare function to measure the welfare of society as a function of the utilities of all individuals. Because use of a social welfare function is clouded by controversy, many economists have tried to maintain objectivity and the claim of their professional practice as a science by avoiding value judgments. A value judgment is simply a subjective statement about what is of value to society that helps to determine the social ordering of alternative states of the world. It is subjective in the sense that it cannot be totally supported by evidence. It is not a judgment of fact. The attempt to avoid value judgments led to development of the Pareto principle. 25

The Pareto criterion The Pareto criterion was introduced in the nineteenth century by the eminent Italian economist, Vilfredo Pareto (1896). Its potential for application to public policy choices, however, is still very much discussed. By this criterion, a policy change is socially desirable if, by the change, everyone can be made better off, or at least some are made better off, while no one is made worse off. If there are any who lose, the criterion is not met. 26

The Pareto criterion The Pareto criterion is a technique for comparing or ranking alternative states of the economy. By this criterion, if it is possible to make at least one person better off when moving from state A to state B without making anyone else worse off, state B is ranked higher by society than state A. If this is the case, a movement from state A to state B represents a Pareto improvement, or state B is Pareto superior to state A. 27

The Pareto criterion If society finds itself in a position from which there is no feasible Pareto improvement, such a state is called a Pareto optimum. That is, a Pareto-optimal state is defined as a state from which it is impossible to make one person better off without making another person worse off. 28

The Pareto criterion Pareto efficiency (optimality) means that the economy is on the utility possibilities frontier. U A A C B D U B 29

The Pareto criterion Moving from C to any point between A and B is Pareto improvement, and we move to a Pareto efficient point. Moving from C to D is a movement to a Pareto efficient point, but it is not Pareto improvement. Thus, moving to a higher utility possibilities frontier does not always imply Pareto improvement. To overcome this difficulty Nicholas Kaldor and John Hicks proposed some alternative to Pareto criteria. 30

The Pareto criterion and compensation If we move to a higher utility possibilities frontier fro U A U B to U AA U BB there is Pareto improvement only if we move between E and Z. If we move to H, there is no Pareto improvement. U AA Ε U A D Ζ Η 31 U B U BB

The Pareto criterion and Kaldor s and Hicks compensation Kaldor proposed that even if we move from D to H the change could be an improvement as long as there is the possibility to compensate those who lose to accept the change and those who gain are as well as or better than before the change. Hicks proposed that a change could be accepted as improving social welfare, if the losers could not compensate the gainers not to accept the new situation. 32

The Pareto criterion and Kaldor s and Hicks compensation In effect Kaldor proposed that there is social improvement if the gainers can fully compensate the losers and still be better off (Kaldor referred to improvement from the point of view of production, not necessarily all-round social improvement. But the term Kaldor criterion is usually used with reference to a social improvement). Hicks supported the criterion (The Kaldor or Kaldor Hicks criterion) and also proposed a sister criterion, the Hicks criterion, which states that there is social improvement if the losers cannot profitably bribe the gainers to oppose a change (Hicks, 1940). 33

The Pareto criterion and Kaldor s and Hicks compensation Both criteria are satisfied when utility possibilities frontiers do not cross each other. If, however, the two frontiers cross each other, then as Scitovsky showed there is no clear answer. Scitovsky showed that the Kaldor (and the Hicks) criterion could lead to a contradiction. According to the Kaldor criterion a certain change can be proposed, but the reverse change (that is, changing the situation after the first change back to the original situation) can also be proposed by the same criterion. A logical inconsistency is therefore involved. This inconsistency is illustrated in the Figure below. 34

The Scitovsky paradox We have two individuals A and B, and two utility possibilities frontiers. U A U C U D Ε. Ζ U U U B 35

The Scitovsky paradox Let the original situation be at E on the utility possibility curve UU. What matters in this analysis is that movement along the curve is caused only by costless lump-sum transfers. Consider a change that will carry us from E to D. This change passes the Kaldor criterion as it is possible, after the change, to redistribute income to reach point Z where everyone is better off than at E. Starting from D, transferring income from A to B will enable us to move along the curve U U to point Z. Since Z is north-east of E, both individuals will be better off at Z than at E. 36

The Scitovsky paradox According to the Kaldor criterion, therefore, the change from E to D is a social improvement. However, by exactly the same reasoning the change from D back to E fulfils the same Kaldor criterion. This is because we can also redistribute income from E to C, which is north-east of D. Since the same criterion dictates that D is socially preferable to E and that E is socially preferable to D, a logical inconsistency is involved. 37

The Scitovsky paradox If one is skeptical about the possibility of contradiction and thinks that this could just be the result of unrestricted manipulation of UPCs, it should be remembered that Scitovsky was using an Edgeworth box that consisted of commodity space with wellbehaved indifference maps. The following simple example should be sufficiently convincing. 38

The Scitovsky paradox 39 Imagine a community in which there are just two individuals, A and B, and two goods, X and Y. In situation E individual A has two X and B has one Y; In situation D individual B has one X and A has two Y. Now suppose that A would prefer one X and one Y to two X, and would prefer two X to one X; while B would prefer one X and one Y to two Y, and would prefer two Y to one Y. These preference patterns are quite reasonable and satisfy the conventional diminishing marginal rates of substitution. It can easily be seen that the movement from E to D and the reverse movement from D to E both satisfy the Kaldor criterion. Thus after moving from E to Z, if the gainer (B) gives one unit of Y to the loser (A ), A is made better off than at E and B is no worse off. Similarly, if we move back from D to E and the gainer (now A) gives one unit of X to B, B is made better off than at D and A is no worse off.

The Scitovsky paradox The contradiction in the Hicks criterion can also be seen in the Figure below. U A U D U C Ζ Ε U U U B 40

The Scitovsky paradox Here the change from E to D satisfies the Hicks criterion as it is not possible to redistribute income from E to reach a point north-east of D. By similar reasoning, the reverse change from D to E also satisfies the Hicks criterion. 41

The Scitovsky paradox To avoid contradiction Scitovsky proposes that a change should be regarded as unambiguously favourable only if it satisfies both the Kaldor criterion and the Hicks criterion (or, equivalently, the Scitovsky reversal test). In terms of UPFs this means that, for the change from E to D to be unambiguously desirable, not only must the UPF through D pass over (north-east of) E, but also the UPF through E must pass under (south-west of) D. 42