FACTOR PRICES AND INCOME DISTRIBUTION IN LESS INDUSTRIALISED ECONOMIES

Similar documents
Refrigeration and Distribution: New Zealand Land Prices and Real Wages *

GLOBALISATION AND WAGE INEQUALITIES,

The Comparative Advantage of Nations: Shifting Trends and Policy Implications

Lecture 1 Economic Growth and Income Differences: A Look at the Data

and with support from BRIEFING NOTE 1

Everyday Economics: Three Faces of Globalization

Quarterly Labour Market Report. February 2017

Has Globalization Helped or Hindered Economic Development? (EA)

1. Global Disparities Overview

Emerging Market Consumers: A comparative study of Latin America and Asia-Pacific

Industrial Policy and African Development. Justin Yifu Lin National School of Development Peking University

WORLD ECONOMIC EXPANSION in the first half of the 1960's has

Globalization and Inequality: Historical Trends

Chapter 18 Development and Globalization

Rising inequality in China

2014 BELGIAN FOREIGN TRADE

Asia-Pacific to comprise two-thirds of global middle class by 2030, Report says

Globalisation: International Trade

Population Composition

There is a seemingly widespread view that inequality should not be a concern

Dirección Internacional de la Empresa Lección 1ª: La dinámica de integración global. Fases

Asia's giants take different routes By Martin Wolf Published: February :36 Last updated: February :36

Inclusive global growth: a framework to think about the post-2015 agenda

CHAPTER I: SIZE AND GEOGRAPHICAL DISTRIBUTION OF THE POPULATION

Speech given by Mervyn King, Governor of the Bank of England. At Salts Mills, Bradford, Yorkshire 13 June 2005

Notes to Editors. Detailed Findings

INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS, FINANCE AND TRADE Vol. II - Globalization and the Evolution of Trade - Pasquale M. Sgro

Types of Economies. 10x10learning.com

INDONESIA AND THE LEWIS TURNING POINT: EMPLOYMENT AND WAGE TRENDS

Preliminary Assessment by the GATT Secretariat

Trends in inequality worldwide (Gini coefficients)

The new demographic and social challenges in Spain: the aging process and the immigration

THE NORTHERN TERRITORY S RY S OVERSEAS BORN POPULATION

Rethinking Growth Policy The Schumpeterian Perspective. EEA Meeting Geneva, August 2016

Global Trends in Wages

Land and Natural Resources. Factors of Production. Capital: funding, investments

May 2018 IPSOS VIEWS. What Worries the World. Michael Clemence

Inclusive growth and development founded on decent work for all

Key Facts about Long Run Economic Growth

Strengthening Integration of the Economies in Transition into the World Economy through Economic Diversification

BBC BBC World Service Long-Term Tracking

Since the Vietnam War ended in 1975, the

Analysis of Global Migration Patterns Part I: Push and Pull factors Adapted from Farhan

Mapping physical therapy research

Wage Gap Widens as Wages Fail to Keep Pace with Productivity

Australian Opportunities through the Chinese Structural Transformation

Trends in Labour Supply

Understanding inequality and what to do about it

CLMV and the AEC 2015 :

Labour Market Reform, Rural Migration and Income Inequality in China -- A Dynamic General Equilibrium Analysis

Charting South Korea s Economy, 1H 2017

POLI 12D: International Relations Sections 1, 6

POLICY OPTIONS AND CHALLENGES FOR DEVELOPING ASIA PERSPECTIVES FROM THE IMF AND ASIA APRIL 19-20, 2007 TOKYO

The globalization of inequality

Understanding institutions

Analysis on Phases of Globalization and Convergence

EMERGING PARTNERS AND THE SCRAMBLE FOR AFRICA. Ian Taylor University of St Andrews

Emerging Asian economies lead Global Pay Gap rankings

HIGHLIGHTS. There is a clear trend in the OECD area towards. which is reflected in the economic and innovative performance of certain OECD countries.

THAILAND SYSTEMATIC COUNTRY DIAGNOSTIC Public Engagement

ASIAN TRANSFORMATIONS: An Inquiry into the Development of Nations

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES INTERPRETING THE TARIFF-GROWTH CORRELATION OF THE LATE NINETEENTH CENTURY. Douglas A. Irwin

Designer Immigrants? International Students, as Potential Skilled Migrants Lesleyanne Hawthorne Professor International Workforce

Summary of the Results

People. Population size and growth. Components of population change

Mexico: How to Tap Progress. Remarks by. Manuel Sánchez. Member of the Governing Board of the Bank of Mexico. at the. Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas

Economic correlates of Net Interstate Migration to the NT (NT NIM): an exploratory analysis

A History of the Global Economy

How Extensive Is the Brain Drain?

Frustration, and even rage, over poor socio-economic

To be opened on receipt

World Economic and Social Survey

An Historical Perspective on Technological Shocks, Political Shocks and Globalization

Test Bank for Economic Development. 12th Edition by Todaro and Smith

Monthly Inbound Update June th August 2017

China After the East Asian Crisis

Ghana Lower-middle income Sub-Saharan Africa (developing only) Source: World Development Indicators (WDI) database.

POPULATION STUDIES RESEARCH BRIEF ISSUE Number

From Crisis to Redistribution? Global Attitudes Towards Equality, Welfare, and State Ownership

Trends in within-country

What can we learn from productivity dynamics over the crisis episode in the EU?

Chapter 9. Key Issue Two: where are more and less developed countries located?

Tilburg University. The digital divide across all citizens of the world James, Jeffrey. Published in: Social Indicators Research

CHAPTER 12: The Problem of Global Inequality

Population & Migration

GERMANY, JAPAN AND INTERNATIONAL PAYMENT IMBALANCES

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

Why international. trade is good for. New Zealand and. New Zealanders

The Demography of the Labor Force in Emerging Markets

Globalisation and Open Markets

The Information Dividend: International Information Well-being Index

Changes in Wage Inequality in Canada: An Interprovincial Perspective

Population & Migration

Executive summary. Part I. Major trends in wages

Analyzing the Nature and Quantifying the Magnitude of the Employment Linkage 03

Comparative Political Economy. David Soskice Nuffield College

Trans-national Policy Making:Towards Tri-Continental Perspective Abstract

Illustrative Examples Unit 5

Charting Indonesia s Economy, 1H 2017

BUILDING RESILIENT REGIONS FOR STRONGER ECONOMIES OECD

Transcription:

Blackwell Publishing AsiaMelbourne, AustraliaAEHRAustralian Economic History Review0004-8992 2006 The Authors; Journal compilation Blackwell Publishing Asia Pty Ltd and the Economic History Society of Australia and New Zealand 2006March 2007471 IntroductionFactor prices and income distribution in less industrialised economies 1870 1939David Greasley, Kris Inwood and John Singleton Australian Economic History Review, Vol. 47, No. 1 ISSN 0004-8992 March 2007 doi: 10.1111/j.1467-8446.2006.00193.x FACTOR PRICES AND INCOME DISTRIBUTION IN LESS INDUSTRIALISED ECONOMIES 1870 1939 BY DAVID GREASLEY, KRIS INWOOD AND JOHN SINGLETON University of Edinburgh, University of Guelph, and Victoria University of Wellington Global trade expansion after 1870 had potentially powerful effects on income distribution, especially in land-abundant less industrialised economies, by increasing land prices relative to wages. The papers in this issue add evidence on wage rentals for a range of countries, specifically Australia, Canada, Ghana, India, and Sweden. These new data offer partial support for Jeffrey Williamson s view that the distributional effects of booming global trade to 1914 were powerful and ubiquitous, but they highlight that more attention might be given to geographical boundaries and to other distribution forces including technology and wage bargaining conditions. JEL categories: F20, N30, N31, N33, N35, N37 Keywords: factor market, factor ratio, globalisation, land price, rent, wage In wide-ranging and hugely influential work Jeffrey Williamson has argued that transport innovation-driven global trade expansion after 1870 was accompanied by commodity price convergence. Price gaps for a wide range of manufactures, raw materials, and foodstuffs narrowed dramatically around the Atlantic economy. Freight factors also declined sharply for less industrialised economies, for example, the gap between the London and Rangoon price of rice was down to 26 per cent by 1913, and the London Calcutta jute price gap fell to four per cent. 1 For Williamson, commodity price convergence had powerful income distribution effects around the world economy. He argues for European economies that wage earners benefited and income distribution became more even. For many parts of the less industrialised world his analysis points to a rise in income inequality. The link from commodity price convergence to income inequality centres on the implications of the global trade booms for relative factor prices, specifically for the ratio of wages to the rental price of land (wage rentals). Commodity trade 1 Williamson, Land, Labor, p. 63. 1

2 David Greasley, Kris Inwood and John Singleton booms of the late nineteenth century raised land prices around many parts of the less industrial world, including in Australasia, the southern cone of the Americas, and in parts of South and Southeast Asia. These economies experienced especially sharp increases in their terms of trade, as the price of agricultural goods and raw materials rose relatively to the price of manufactures. Concomitantly land prices boomed around the land-abundant periphery. Shifts in relative commodity prices favoured the less industrialised, land-abundant periphery, and the effects, for Williamson, were magnified in relative factor price shifts, which unleashed powerful and ubiquitous distributional forces around the world economy, principally by raising the relative price of land. 2 Williamson reported wage land rental ratios for a variety of countries which show falls in the ratio for land-abundant countries of the periphery, and rises both in land scarce Europe and in some land scarce Asian economies. In the extreme cases wage rentals were forty and eleven times higher respectively in Siam and Uruguay in 1870/4 than in 1911, but in western Europe, and in some land scarce east Asian economies, including Japan and Taiwan, wage rentals rose. The impact on income distribution, especially in parts of the less industrialised world may have been enormous. Shifts in real wages were, on Williamson s interpretation, powerfully influenced by the income distributional effects of movements in the wage rental ratio in land-abundant economies. Thus, the global trade booms of the late nineteenth century may have been accompanied by substantial income distributional effects. There appears little doubt that trade, and also the migration of capital and labour, by affecting relative factor prices, had potentially important consequences for income distribution around the world economy in the period between 1870 and 1914. In the case of less industrial economies, the distributional effects of globalisation were most powerful in land-abundant countries of the periphery rather than in the western offshoots where capital imports and capital deepening along with technological progress may have ameliorated the declines in the wage rental ratio. Distributional shifts in the western offshoots were less pronounced, particularly in North America, and indeed wage rentals rose in Canada, according to Williamson s data. Conversely, Williamson shows that changes in the relative price of agricultural goods impacted most strongly on land prices in the land-abundant regions where agriculture was a larger share of economic activity. In particular, in Uruguay, Argentina, Thailand, Egypt, and to a lesser extent in the Punjab, wage income fell relatively sharply. Elsewhere, in Europe and in land-scarce East Asia ( Japan, Korea, and Taiwan) the wage rental ratio rose. Relative factor price shifts, however, were less pronounced in the labour abundant economies of Williamson s sample. Labour gained most in Scandinavian countries. In Sweden and Denmark, the wage rental ratio doubled between 1870 and 1911. 2 Williamson, Land, Labor, p. 81, see also O Rourke, Taylor, and Williamson, Factor price convergence and O Rourke and Williamson, Globalization and History.

Factor prices and income distribution in less industrialised economies 1870 1939 3 Of course Williamson was acutely aware that his key facts surrounding relative factor prices and thus the distributional effects of globalisation are based on a small sample of countries, and accordingly he called for more research. The papers in this issue are a response, and they form part of a wider group of papers which were presented at the 2006 Helsinki Congress of the International Economic History Association. These papers report new data for factor prices (in several cases for both land and labour, but simply for labour in others) for a variety of countries, including Australia, Canada, New Zealand, Uruguay, India, Brazil, Sweden, Denmark, Ghana, and for various East Asian and European cities. 3 The detailed investigations of particular countries offered by this new research provide both support and some challenges for Williamson s general observations. In the cases of Australia and Canada, the importance of regional variation in relative factor prices is highlighted in the papers by Shanahan and Wilson, and by Emery, Inwood, and Thille. For Australia, Shanahan and Wilson stress the divergent wage rental shifts in South Australia compared with the other colonies. Wage rentals rose in South Australia to the early 1880s, and the ratio was roughly constant in the half century to World War I. Seemingly the distributional forces unleashed by global trade were not ubiquitous in land-abundant countries, and Shanahan and Wilson attribute relatively slow land price growth to both technological and policy forces that stimulated unusually rapid expansion of South Australia s farm frontier. Rather differently, Emery, Inwood, and Thille consider the puzzling characteristics of Canadian factor price history and they provide explanation of the rise in wage rental in land-abundant Canada shown by Williamson s data. In effect Emery, Inwood, and Thille argue that Canada was a microcosm of the Atlantic economy, in which relatively land scarce eastern Canada experienced outmigration and land-abundant western Canada in-migration; concomitantly wage rentals rose in the east and fell in the west. Emery, Inwood, and Thille s findings support Williamson s factor market and factor prices hypotheses, but they also highlight that national economies are not always the appropriate unit for analysis. Their perspective may also shed light on other land-abundant countries, including on the USA, where falls in wage rentals were comparatively modest according to Williamson s evidence. Bohlin and Larsson report new evidence for Swedish land prices using information on private sales, which shows faster growth than the public land sales data deployed by Williamson. Accordingly Bohlin and Larsson argue that Swedish wage rentals rose less quickly and at a similar pace to other protectionist European economies. Furthermore, they show that more powerful distributional shifts in favour of labour occurred during World War I and its aftermath when pay bargaining conditions advantaged workers. Wage rentals did rise rather faster in Denmark than in Sweden, but a strong distributional shift in favour of Danish wages in an era of trade union militancy in the aftermath of World War I was 3 The papers of session 62 may be found at http://www.helsinki.fi/iehc2006/sessions41_80.html

4 David Greasley, Kris Inwood and John Singleton also found by Greasley and Madsen. 4 Indeed, in the course of a comparison of Danish and New Zealand wages they argue that the effects of open economy forces on relative real wages in these two peripheral economies was modest compared with the effects of World War I and limited to the impact of capital flows, which especially benefited Danish wages. In contrast, land prices rose sharply in New Zealand in the years around World War I. Among Williamson s sample of land-abundant non-developed economies, India or more specifically the Punjab experienced the least fall in wage rentals to 1914, although the ratio did fall by around 50 per cent. Wage rentals in Punjab, however, continued to fall after World War I. In his paper, Roy takes issue with the view that the roots of poverty in India lie in global trade. For India, generally, export to gross domestic product ratios at around four to five per cent between 1870 and 1909 were low compared with the settler economies of the Americas and Australasia. 5 Roy argues that the stagnation in rural wages and rise in poverty must be explained with reference to factors internal to the rural economy, in particular to production conditions in agriculture, which moved from land-surplus to land-shortage with more or less unchanging land-yield. For Roy the critical problem was the stagnation in yield. He proposes that the roots of present-day poverty in India cannot be found in colonial trade, but in the absence of an agrarian revolution in the region until the last quarter of the twentieth century. Sub-Saharan African countries are absent from Williamson s sample. 6 In pioneering work Austin begins to remedy this deficiency by considering the case of Ghana. He argues that there was a lowering of the cost of labour in relation to that of land in Ghana within the late nineteenth and early twentieth century, but that in the West African context the change was more fundamental, in the sense of being institutional rather than simply quantitative. Specifically, slavery and debt bondage were replaced by wage labour and the mortgaging or pledging of land, while in some parts of the country a factor market in land materialised for the first time. Austin reports that the transition from slave to free labour meant that labourers gained in absolute terms even while the free-market bargaining power of land-owners increased. The papers in this issue add to our understanding of how global trade expansion and commodity market integration influenced income distribution among less industrialised countries between 1870 and 1939. Of course much more needs to be done, especially for Asian economies before we will be able to judge the ubiquity of the distributional forces unleashed by the late nineteenth century commodity export booms. The papers in this volume highlight the need for caution when attributing causes of distributional changes. This may especially be so for the South and Southeast Asian economies where stagnant farm productivity may, as Roy argues, have had important distributional effects. In innovative work 4 Greasley and Madsen, A tale of two peripheries. 5 Williamson, Globalization, p. 90. 6 There is a paucity of data for these countries. Mosley, The Settler Economies: presents some data for African wages and European areas land prices.

Factor prices and income distribution in less industrialised economies 1870 1939 5 Austin also shows that more African economies can and should be included in the debates. He highlights the profound institutional consequences of the rise of global trade in the case of Ghana, where free labour markets developed and wages rose. Nor did the land booms in western Canada preclude rapid wage growth in the Dominion generally. In other western offshoots, New Zealand, for example, shifts to more equitable land distribution helped offset the effects of falling wage rentals to 1914. 7 Moreover, Shanahan and Wilson show wage rentals did not deteriorate in South Australia, and point to the impact of technological progress. For the European economies, for example, Sweden and Denmark, wage bargaining conditions and the power of organised labour appears to have eventually had important distributional effects, as shown by Bohlin and Larsson. Almost self-evidently, the global trade expansions of the late nineteenth century were not the only forces shaping income distribution among the less industrialised economies. Equally certainly, there is much validity in Williamson s general observations that commodity price convergence happened, that the terms of trade rose most strongly for the land-abundant economies of the periphery, and that concomitantly wage rentals tended to fall in land-abundant economies to 1914, but to rise elsewhere. Globalisation did powerfully affect income distribution. The papers here show that the effects may not have been ubiquitous, and that other distributional forces were at work. We suspect that Williamson might agree, and we are certain that he would encourage further research to further extend the evidence surrounding the globalisation and income distribution debates. REFERENCES Greasley, D., and Madsen, J. B. (2006) A tale of two peripheries: real wages and Denmark and New Zealand 1875 1939. Scandinavian Economic History Review, 54, 116 36. Greasley, D., and Oxley, L. (2004) Globalization and real wages in New Zealand. 1873 1913. Explorations in Economic History, 41, 26 47. Greasley, D., and Oxley, L. (2005) Refrigeration and distribution: New Zealand land prices and real wages. Australian Economic History Review, 45, 23 44. Mosley, P. (1983) The Settler Economies: Studies in the Economic History of Kenya and Southern Rhodesia (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press). O Rourke, K. H., and Williamson, J. G. (1999). Globalization and History: the Evolution of a Late Nineteenth Century Atlantic Economy (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press). O Rourke, K. H., Taylor, A., and Williamson, J. G. (1996) Factor price convergence in the late nineteenth century. International Economic Review, 37, 499 530. Williamson, J. G. (2002) Land, labor and globalization in the Third World, 1870 1940. Journal of Economic History, 62, 55 85. Williamson, J. G. (2006) Globalization and the Poor Periphery Before 1950 (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press). 7 Greasley and Oxley, Refrigeration and Distribution; Greasley and Oxley, Globalization and Real Wages.