Testing Political Economy Models of Reform in the Laboratory

Similar documents
Compulsory versus Voluntary Voting Mechanisms: An Experimental Study

Supporting Information Political Quid Pro Quo Agreements: An Experimental Study

Tinbergen Institute Amsterdam Keizersgracht EG Amsterdam The Netherlands Tel.: +31.(0) Fax: +31.(0)

Experimental economics and public choice

Public opinion polls, voter turnout, and welfare: An experimental study *

Behavioral Public Choice. Professor Rebecca Morton New York University

Sequential vs. Simultaneous Voting: Experimental Evidence

Classical papers: Osborbe and Slivinski (1996) and Besley and Coate (1997)

Compulsory versus Voluntary Voting An Experimental Study

Does Lobbying Matter More than Corruption In Less Developed Countries?*

Choosing Among Signalling Equilibria in Lobbying Games

political budget cycles

UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA, SAN DIEGO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

THE PARADOX OF VOTER PARTICIPATION? A LABORATORY STUDY

Compulsory versus Voluntary Voting An Experimental Study

Information Acquisition and Voting Mechanisms: Theory and Evidence

EFFICIENCY OF COMPARATIVE NEGLIGENCE : A GAME THEORETIC ANALYSIS

At least since Downs s (1957) seminal work An Economic Theory of Democracy,

Enriqueta Aragones Harvard University and Universitat Pompeu Fabra Andrew Postlewaite University of Pennsylvania. March 9, 2000

A Simultaneous Analysis of Turnout and Voting under Proportional Representation: Theory and Experiments. Aaron Kamm & Arthur Schram

David Rosenblatt** Macroeconomic Policy, Credibility and Politics is meant to serve

1 Electoral Competition under Certainty

COSTLY VOTING: A LARGE-SCALE REAL EFFORT EXPERIMENT

Economics Bulletin, 2014, Vol. 34 No. 2 pp Introduction

External Validation of Voter Turnout Models by Concealed Parameter Recovery 1

INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS, FINANCE AND TRADE Vol. II - Strategic Interaction, Trade Policy, and National Welfare - Bharati Basu

ONLINE APPENDIX: Why Do Voters Dismantle Checks and Balances? Extensions and Robustness

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES

POLITICAL POWER AND ENDOGENOUS POLICY FORMATION OUTLINE

Understanding political behavior: Essays in experimental political economy Gago Guerreiro de Brito Robalo, P.M.

Agendas and Strategic Voting

Communication and Information in Games of Collective Decision: A Survey of Experimental Results

DISCUSSION PAPERS Department of Economics University of Copenhagen

Afterword: Rational Choice Approach to Legal Rules

Public choice and the development of modern laboratory experimental methods in economics and political science

Introduction to Political Economy Problem Set 3

The welfare effects of public opinion polls

Social Rankings in Human-Computer Committees

CALIFORNIA INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY

THE EFFECT OF OFFER-OF-SETTLEMENT RULES ON THE TERMS OF SETTLEMENT

The Citizen Candidate Model: An Experimental Analysis

1. Introduction. Michael Finus

The Possible Incommensurability of Utilities and the Learning of Goals

Third Party Voting: Vote One s Heart or One s Mind?

VOTING ON INCOME REDISTRIBUTION: HOW A LITTLE BIT OF ALTRUISM CREATES TRANSITIVITY DONALD WITTMAN ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA

Why do people vote? While many theories have

Refinements of Nash equilibria. Jorge M. Streb. Universidade de Brasilia 7 June 2016

The Swing Voter's Curse *

Voter Participation with Collusive Parties. David K. Levine and Andrea Mattozzi

Sincere Versus Sophisticated Voting When Legislators Vote Sequentially

Rational Choice. Pba Dab. Imbalance (read Pab is greater than Pba and Dba is greater than Dab) V V

International Cooperation, Parties and. Ideology - Very preliminary and incomplete

Communication and Information in Games of Collective Decision: A Survey of Experimental Results

James M. Buchanan The Limits of Market Efficiency

The E ects of Identities, Incentives, and Information on Voting 1

Supporting Information for Competing Gridlock Models and Status Quo Policies

"Efficient and Durable Decision Rules with Incomplete Information", by Bengt Holmström and Roger B. Myerson

Learning and Belief Based Trade 1

Lobbying and Bribery

Should We Tax or Cap Political Contributions? A Lobbying Model With Policy Favors and Access

Decision Making Procedures for Committees of Careerist Experts. The call for "more transparency" is voiced nowadays by politicians and pundits

Organized Interests, Legislators, and Bureaucratic Structure

PS 124A Midterm, Fall 2013

Topics in Applied Economics I: Explaining Economic Policy

The Principle of Convergence in Wartime Negotiations. Branislav L. Slantchev Department of Political Science University of California, San Diego

Social Preferences and Voting on Reform: An Experimental Study

An Overview Across the New Political Economy Literature. Abstract

Sincere versus sophisticated voting when legislators vote sequentially

LEARNING FROM SCHELLING'S STRATEGY OF CONFLICT by Roger Myerson 9/29/2006

A positive correlation between turnout and plurality does not refute the rational voter model

Jury Voting without Objective Probability

policy-making. footnote We adopt a simple parametric specification which allows us to go between the two polar cases studied in this literature.

Intro Prefs & Voting Electoral comp. Voter Turnout Agency GIP SIP Rent seeking Partisans. 4. Voter Turnout

Coalition Governments and Political Rents

EC260: The Political Economy of Public Policy

Laboratory Experiments in Political Economy by Thomas R. Palfrey, Princeton University CEPS Working Paper No. 111 July 2005

Political Economy. Pierre Boyer and Alessandro Riboni. École Polytechnique - CREST

HANDBOOK OF SOCIAL CHOICE AND VOTING Jac C. Heckelman and Nicholas R. Miller, editors.

Published in Canadian Journal of Economics 27 (1995), Copyright c 1995 by Canadian Economics Association

Policy Reputation and Political Accountability

External Validation of Voter Turnout Models by Concealed Parameter Recovery 1

Influencing Expectations in the Conduct of Monetary Policy

Experimental Evidence on Voting Rationality and Decision Framing

Illegal Migration and Policy Enforcement

Robust Political Economy. Classical Liberalism and the Future of Public Policy

ECO/PSC 582 Political Economy II

Do States Free Ride in Antitrust Enforcement?

APPLICATION FORM FOR PROSPECTIVE WORKSHOP DIRECTORS

3. Public Choice in a Direct Democracy

How do domestic political institutions affect the outcomes of international trade negotiations?

Choice Under Uncertainty

Get Out the (Costly) Vote: Institutional Design for Greater Participation. Current Version: May 10, 2015

HOTELLING-DOWNS MODEL OF ELECTORAL COMPETITION AND THE OPTION TO QUIT

Common-Pool Resources: Over Extraction and Allocation Mechanisms

Repeat Voting: Two-Vote May Lead More People To Vote

Voting as a Right or a Duty: A social Psychological Analysis. Meredith Sprengel. Georgetown University

Candidate entry and political polarization: An experimental study *

Chapter 14. The Causes and Effects of Rational Abstention

Goods, Games, and Institutions : A Reply

POL-GA Comparative Government and Institutions New York University Spring 2017

Transcription:

Testing Political Economy Models of Reform in the Laboratory By TIMOTHY N. CASON AND VAI-LAM MUI* * Department of Economics, Krannert School of Management, Purdue University, West Lafayette, IN 47907-1310, and Department of Economics, University of Notre Dame, Notre Dame, IN 46556. 208 A fast-growing theoretical literature on the political economy of reform has provided a sizable collection of models that have deepened our understanding concerning how distributional conflict manifests itself in the political process and can prevent efficiency-enhancing economic reform from taking place (see e.g., Allan Drazen [2000 Ch. 10, 13] for an insightful review). Unfortunately, systematic empirical work that provides direct tests of the validity and significance of the mechanisms articulated in these models has been limited. As Torsten Persson and Guido Tabellini (2000 p. 481) note in their evaluation of the larger political economy literature, The gap between theory and evidence is a final weakness of the existing literature....[w]hen there is empirical work, its ties to the underlying theory are often loose... [and] are not tied well to the extensive form games or theoretical predictions in theoretical work. Ideally, we would like more empirical work derived from theory as opposed to informed by theory. One reason for the lack of such empirical studies is that most of these (often gametheoretic) models explain policy outcomes as a result of strategic interaction of forward-looking agents. Direct tests of these models using field data are subject to the same difficulties that researchers have faced when testing gametheoretic models in other areas such as industrial organization, since qualitative features of the equilibria often depend sensitively on the specific assumptions of the game structure (see Richard Schmalensee, 1988 pp. 675 76; Gilles Saint-Paul, 2000). In addition, the politicaleconomy literature of reform explains policy outcomes using political variables such as the distribution of voters preferences and the nature of political institutions (see e.g., Drazen, 2000; Stephan Haggard, 2000). The time variation of these variables is often limited, leading to a classic identification problem and making direct tests of theoretical models difficult (Saint-Paul, 2000). Laboratory studies allow the researcher to manipulate explanatory variables of a theory as treatment variables, so such studies should be helpful in partially overcoming these difficulties and can complement field empirical work on reform. The study of reform also poses new challenges to experimental economists, and a dialogue between political economists and experimental economists can enable both sides to capture gains from trade. This paper aims to illustrate this using an experimental study of the model in the influential paper by Raquel Fernandez and Dani Rodrik (1991). I. An Experiment on Uncertainty, Reform, and Costly Political Participation In a pioneering study, Fernandez and Rodrik (1991; hereafter FR) show how individual-specific uncertainty can prevent efficiency-enhancing reform from taking place. The following example from their paper illustrates the basic idea. Suppose a reform benefits citizens in the winning sector but hurts citizens in the losing sector. Currently, 40 percent and 60 percent of citizens belong to the winning and losing sectors, respectively. Moreover, one-third of the citizens in the losing sector, representing 20 percent of all citizens, can switch to the winning sector if the reform occurs. When there is no uncertainty regarding who will gain or lose from reform, a majority of citizens (40 percent who are in the winning sector and 20 percent who are in the losing sector but can switch to the winning sector) will gain from reform. Therefore, if majority preferences determine the policy outcome, the reform will take place. Now consider the effect of the following kind of uncertainty on the incidence of reform. Suppose that citizens in the losing sector know that one-third of them will be able to switch to the

VOL. 93 NO. 2 EXPERIMENTAL ECONOMICS 209 winning sector, but ex ante each one is equally likely to switch. Because of this uncertainty regarding who will ultimately gain or lose as a result of the reform, for some parameters ex ante all citizens in the losing sector prefer the status quo to the reform. In this case, opponents of the reform will constitute the majority, and reform will not take place. This occurs even though it is common knowledge that if the reform is adopted, it will enjoy majority support ex post. In Cason and Mui (2002), we report a laboratory test of this simple version of the FR model, using 85 undergraduate students as subjects who were randomly placed into new fiveperson groups each decision period, for up to 40 periods (this stranger design minimizes potential repeated-game effects). Two, one, and two subjects are randomly assigned the role of Blue, Green, and Red players, respectively, and all five players receive five experimental dollars (E$5) if the status quo is maintained. Both the Blue and Green subjects receive E$8 following reform and thus prefer reform to the status quo. The Blue subjects correspond to the individuals in the winning sector, while the Green subject corresponds to those who will be able to switch to the winning sector when reform takes place. The Red subjects received E$1 following reform and correspond to those who remain in the losing sector. All subjects decide each period whether to support, oppose, or abstain from participating in their group s reform choice. The reform occurs if it is supported by a strict majority of players in the group. In the Certain Roles treatment, subjects learn their roles before they make their decisions, so supporters of the reform constitute the majority. In the Uncertain Roles treatment, subjects are only informed whether they are Blue or non-blue subjects before they make their decision. For the three non-blue subjects the expected payoff from reform (E$10/3) is less than the certain payoff from the status quo (E$5), so opponents of reform constitute the majority. Since the only difference between the two treatments is the absence or presence of uncertainty, a betweensubjects comparison of the incidence of reform across the Certain Roles and Uncertain Roles treatment provides a direct test of whether uncertainty reduces the incidence of reform. Our experiment also introduces costly political participation to this reform game. Especially when a small number of groups or individuals influence a policy decision, it is reasonable to model their interactions as a competitive collective-action problem. A political actor may benefit from reform, for example, but would need to incur costs (such as explicit lobbying costs, or the implicit political costs for taking a stand regarding a controversial reform) to influence a policy outcome. This costly participation creates an incentive to free-ride on fellow group members efforts to influence policy. The FR model abstracts from costs of political participation to focus on how uncertainty affects the incidence of reform. When political participation is costless, the preferences of the majority will determine policy outcome. With costly political participation, however, whether reform will take place depends on the actual political support it obtains. In particular, using the participation game framework of Thomas Palfrey and Howard Rosenthal (1983), we show that, if the minority are always more willing to incur the cost to influence policy than the majority both with and without uncertainty (which occurs in one type of equilibrium), then reform is more likely with uncertainty than with certainty. But in another equilibrium reform is less likely with uncertainty. The experiment allows us to determine which equilibrium is more consistent with subjects behavior. Our results show that, both in the cases of costless and costly political participation, uncertainty reduces the incidence of reform. Overall, when subjects are certain of their roles and reform benefits, they implement the reform in 78 82 percent of the periods. Consistent with FR s original insight, adding uncertainty reduces the reform rate to only 47 66 percent of the periods. These differences are statistically significant in all four participation-cost treatments. We also find that, with only one exception, reform rates do not vary significantly with the participation cost. Moreover, regardless of whether uncertainty is present or not, the participation rates of both the majority and the minority groups decrease in the participation cost. II. Laboratory Method and the Study of Reform The experiment described above is a modest attempt to employ the laboratory method to

210 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 2003 evaluate a political-economy model of reform. Using this study as an illustration, we discuss here the general question of how the laboratory method can be useful in the study of reform, as well as the challenges that such studies pose for experimental economics. FR s argument that individual-specific uncertainty can prevent reform from taking place has had significant impacts on the study of reform and other topics in the political-economy literature. To our knowledge, however, there is no direct empirical test of the hypothesis that such uncertainty reduces the incidence of reform. The laboratory method permits a direct and controlled test of hypotheses that are explicitly derived from extensions of FR s theory. Furthermore, although there are not yet many experimental studies on the political economy of reform, an experimental literature on related political-economy issues exists that can help guide experimenters when adapting methodologies and proposing new questions for the study of reform (e.g., Charles Plott, 2001). For example, by drawing upon the theoretical and related experimental literature on the participation game (Gary Bornstein, 1992; Arthur Schram and Joep Sonnemans, 1996), our laboratory study allows us to extend the FR model to derive predictions regarding how costly political participation may affect the behavior of political actors and the incidence of reform. The extended model demonstrates that, with costly participation, under both certainty and uncertainty, the participation game admits multiple equilibria, even restricting attention to what Palfrey and Rosenthal (1983) and others consider as the most plausible totally mixed Nash equilibria. In one type of equilibrium, which we call type A, the majority always participate with a higher probability than the minority; and in another type, the minority always participate with a higher probability than the minority. Moreover, in both types of equilibrium, an increase in participation costs have opposite effects on the participation rates of the majority and the minority; for one group the participation rate decreases in the participation cost, and for the other group the participation rate increases in the participation cost. The laboratory study allows us to determine which type of equilibrium more accurately describes behavior because it provides access to micro-level data that are typically unavailable outside the laboratory. The type-a equilibrium accurately describes behavior for participants in the majority group. However, the empirical result that participation rates decrease with the participation cost for both the majority and the minority in all treatments cannot be reconciled with either type of totally mixed-strategy Nash equilibrium. This result illustrates another important benefit of using laboratory methods to study reform: the laboratory enables one to gather evidence about behavioral regularities of human decision-makers, which can in turn generate useful questions for field studies. For example, if future laboratory studies indicate that the negative relationship between participation costs and participation rates for both the majority and the minority is robust, this suggests that researchers should investigate whether this regularity is also observed in the field, as well as the extent to which this behavior may be important in determining whether reform will take place. The empirical regularities also suggest questions that need to be addressed in future theoretical work. In Cason and Mui (2002), we explore whether or not one modification of Nash equilibrium, the quantal response equilibrium (QRE) developed by Richard McKelvey and Palfrey (1995), can account for the negative relationship between participation costs and rates for all types of subjects in our experiment. 1 We find that the QRE almost always correctly predicts that the participation rates decrease for both the majority and the minority as participation cost increases. It also tracks the behavior of the majority extremely well in both the Certain Roles and the Uncertain Roles treatments. The QRE also explains the minority s behavior better than the mixed-strategy Nash equilibria, although there is still room for improvement. 2 1 In a QRE, each player plays a stochastic best response: he does not choose a best response with probability 1; instead, he chooses action that yields higher expected payoffs with a higher probability. A set of choice probabilities by all players constitute a QRE when each player s choice probabilities are a stochastic best response to the choice probabilities of all other players. 2 In particular, for the minority the QRE predicts a higher participation rate than observed in the Certain Roles

VOL. 93 NO. 2 EXPERIMENTAL ECONOMICS 211 Experimental work on the political economy of reform is not merely a straightforward extension of laboratory research to a new domain of inquiry, however, because it poses new methodological challenges. For example, our experiment shows that uncertainty reduces the incidence of reform in small-group participation games even with costly participation. Future research should investigate whether this result also holds with large groups. More generally, reforms often involve large-scale distributional conflicts that affect almost everyone in society and are rarely occurring political events. The study of reform thus requires experimenters to develop methods to study collective decisionmaking for large groups in a controlled environment. Experimenters also need to capture rarely occurring political events more realistically and to create different political institutions in the laboratory. Advancements along these lines will enable researchers to conduct laboratory studies on questions such as how differences in political institutions (e.g., parliamentary versus presidential) affect the adoption and sustainability of reform in two otherwise identical economies. III. Concluding Remarks A substantial gap exists between the stylized experiment summarized here and the political process affecting the adoption of actual reforms. 3 Many contributors to the political-economy literature of reform have argued that efforts to close a similar gap between the theory and practice of reform should be a priority of researchers. As Drazen (2000 p. 404) observes, theorists are often concerned that too many factors are at play in practical discussions of real-world reform to model them with any degree of theoretical rigor, while practitioners often view treatment and a lower participation rate than observed in the Uncertain Roles treatment. 3 We do not view this as an argument that the experiment is not useful for the study of reform, however. The laboratory is a screen for basic ideas articulated in theoretical models; if a model does not predict behavior in controlled conditions where it should apply, there are reasons to be skeptical about its ability to explain behavior in more complex field settings (Plott, 2001). theoretical treatments of reform as elegant but hopelessly out of touch with reality. We view the role of experiments in the study of reform to have modest near-term and ambitious long-term goals to help close this gap. In the immediate and foreseeable future, we see experiments as most useful in providing direct controlled tests of theoretical models, as well as in generating new empirical regularities regarding human behavior in these reform settings to guide future theoretical work. Eventually, however, sustained dialogues involving theorists, experimenters, and practitioners should generate useful insights and tools for addressing policy questions more directly. The literature on market experiments provides a hint of how this might be possible. Early market experiments (e.g., Vernon Smith, 1962) were concerned with testing basic theoretical propositions, such as whether competitive equilibria are reached in markets populated by human traders even when agents are not infinitesimal price-takers. Following the positive results of these early experiments, researchers could turn to study topics such as how existing, field trading institutions affected price formation. Eventually (decades later), because of the insight provided by the extremely detailed laboratory empirical data and the parallel development of game-theoretic models of auctions and other institutions, theorists and experimenters could begin to design completely new trading institutions for transactions not even envisioned when the early experiments were conducted, such as combinatorial auctions for broadcast-spectrum rights (e.g., Jeffrey Banks et al., 2003). The early laboratory research on markets had the benefit of being guided by a general and well-established equilibrium theory, while unifying theoretical propositions that can provide guidance for an analogous development in the study of reform do not yet exist. A rewarding and challenging task lies ahead, but we believe that progress can be made through continued interactions between political economists and experimental economists. REFERENCES Banks, Jeffrey; Olson, Mark; Porter, David; Rassenti, Steve and Smith, Vernon. Theory, Experiment and the Federal Communications

212 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 2003 Commission Spectrum Auctions. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 2003 (forthcoming). Bornstein, Gary. The Free Rider Problem in Intergroup Conflicts over Step-Level and Continuous Public Goods. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, April 1992, 62(4), pp. 597 606. Cason, Timothy and Mui, Vai-Lam. Uncertainty and Resistance to Reform in Laboratory Participation Games. Working paper, Purdue University, 2002. Drazen, Allan. Political economy in macroeconomics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2000. Fernandez, Raquel and Rodrik, Dani. Resistance to Reform: Status Quo Bias in the Presence of Individual-Specific Uncertainty. American Economic Review, December 1991, 81(5), pp. 1146 55. Haggard, Stephan. Interests, Institutions, and Policy Reform, in Anne Krueger, ed., Economic policy reform: The second stage. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2000, pp. 21 57. McKelvey, Richard and Palfrey, Thomas. Quantal Response Equilibria in Normal Form Games. Games and Economic Behavior, July 1995, 10(1), pp. 6 38. Palfrey, Thomas and Rosenthal, Howard. A Strategic Calculus of Voting. Public Choice, 1983, 41(1), pp. 7 53. Persson, Torsten and Tabellini, Guido. Political economics: Explaining economic policy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2000. Plott, Charles R. Public economics, political processes, and policy applications: Collected papers on the experimental foundations of economics and political science. Cheltenham, U.K.: Elgar, 2001. Saint-Paul, Gilles. The New Political Economy : Recent Books by Allan Drazen and by Torsten Persson and Guido Tabellini. Journal of Economic Literature. December 2000, 38(4), pp. 915 25. Schmalensee, Richard. Industrial Economics: An Overview. Economic Journal, September 1988, 98(392), pp. 643 81. Schram, Arthur and Sonnemans, Joep. Voter Turnout as a Participation Game: An Experimental Investigation. International Journal of Game Theory, 1996, 25(3), pp. 385 406. Smith, Vernon. An Experimental Study of Competitive Market Behavior. Journal of Political Economy, April 1962, 70(2), pp. 111 37.