The impact of Chinese import competition on the local structure of employment and wages in France

Similar documents
Notes on exam in International Economics, 16 January, Answer the following five questions in a short and concise fashion: (5 points each)

The China Syndrome. Local Labor Market Effects of Import Competition in the United States. David H. Autor, David Dorn, and Gordon H.

Research Report. How Does Trade Liberalization Affect Racial and Gender Identity in Employment? Evidence from PostApartheid South Africa

International Trade 31E00500, Spring 2017

Chapter 5. Resources and Trade: The Heckscher-Ohlin

Explaining the Unexplained: Residual Wage Inequality, Manufacturing Decline, and Low-Skilled Immigration. Unfinished Draft Not for Circulation

Source: Piketty Saez. Share (in %), excluding capital gains. Figure 1: The top decile income share in the U.S., % 45% 40% 35% 30% 25%

Chapter 4 Specific Factors and Income Distribution

HIGHLIGHTS. There is a clear trend in the OECD area towards. which is reflected in the economic and innovative performance of certain OECD countries.

International Trade Theory College of International Studies University of Tsukuba Hisahiro Naito

Explaining the Unexplained: Residual Wage Inequality, Manufacturing Decline, and Low-Skilled Immigration

Changes in Wage Inequality in Canada: An Interprovincial Perspective

Chapter 5. Resources and Trade: The Heckscher-Ohlin Model

Is Economic Development Good for Gender Equality? Income Growth and Poverty

UNION COLLEGE DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, FALL 2004 ECO 146 SEMINAR IN GLOBAL ECONOMIC ISSUES GLOBALIZATION AND LABOR MARKETS

Study. Importance of the German Economy for Europe. A vbw study, prepared by Prognos AG Last update: February 2018

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

How does international trade affect household welfare?

Commentary: The Impact of Trade on Inequality in Developing Countries

Globalization: What Did We Miss?

Persistent Inequality

Chapter 4. Preview. Introduction. Resources, Comparative Advantage, and Income Distribution

Primary inequality and redistribution through employer Social Security contributions: France

Ghana Lower-middle income Sub-Saharan Africa (developing only) Source: World Development Indicators (WDI) database.

Commentary: The Impact of Trade on Inequality in Developed Countries

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach

Raymundo Miguel Campos-Vázquez. Center for Economic Studies, El Colegio de México, and consultant to the OECD. and. José Antonio Rodríguez-López

11/2/2010. The Katz-Murphy (1992) formulation. As relative supply increases, relative wage decreases. Katz-Murphy (1992) estimate

Inequality in Labor Market Outcomes: Contrasting the 1980s and Earlier Decades

Patrick Adler and Chris Tilly Institute for Research on Labor and Employment, UCLA. Ben Zipperer University of Massachusetts, Amherst

IV. Labour Market Institutions and Wage Inequality

International Trade: Lecture 5

The Impact of Immigration on Wages of Unskilled Workers

Labour Market Reform, Rural Migration and Income Inequality in China -- A Dynamic General Equilibrium Analysis

Understanding the dynamics of labor income inequality in Latin America (WB PRWP 7795)

The Impact of Foreign Workers on the Labour Market of Cyprus

Labor market consequences of trade openness and competition in foreign markets

Unequal Recovery, Labor Market Polarization, Race, and 2016 U.S. Presidential Election. Maoyong Fan and Anita Alves Pena 1

Cleavages in Public Preferences about Globalization

Real Wage Trends, 1979 to 2017

Over the past three decades, the share of middle-skill jobs in the

The textile industry in Ukraine

Do (naturalized) immigrants affect employment and wages of natives? Evidence from Germany

Abstract/Policy Abstract

High Technology Agglomeration and Gender Inequalities

Foreign workers in the Korean labour market: current status and policy issues

Computerization and Immigration: Theory and Evidence from the United States 1

Supplementary/Online Appendix for:

The Challenges of Global Trade: Globalization or Fragmentation? Dany Bahar, PhD The Brookings Institution

First Midterm. Time allowed: 50 minutes. Please answer ALL questions. The total score is 100. Please budget your time wisely.

Conventional economic theory holds that

Part 1: Focus on Income. Inequality. EMBARGOED until 5/28/14. indicator definitions and Rankings

Is inequality an unavoidable by-product of skill-biased technical change? No, not necessarily!

5A. Wage Structures in the Electronics Industry. Benjamin A. Campbell and Vincent M. Valvano

14 The distributional implications of US trade liberalisation with China

The Demography of the Labor Force in Emerging Markets

The present picture: Migrants in Europe

Chapter 4: Specific Factors and

ARTNeT Trade Economists Conference Trade in the Asian century - delivering on the promise of economic prosperity rd September 2014

UNIVERSITY OF ESSEX AUTUMN 2016 DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS EC367 INTERNATIONAL TRADE ASSIGNMENT. Term Paper

Trade and Labor Market Adjustment: Recent Evidence from Brazil

14.54 International Trade Lecture 23: Factor Mobility (I) Labor Migration

Divided We Stand: Why inequality keeps rising

Wage inequality and skill premium

Trade Policy, Agreements and Taxation of Multinationals

US Exports and Employment. Robert C. Feenstra University of California, Davis and NBER

International Business Economics

Danish gender wage studies

GLOBALISATION AND WAGE INEQUALITIES,

Quantitative Analysis of Migration and Development in South Asia

Dirk Pilat:

Trade Openness and Inequality

The contrast between the United States and the

Wage Differentials in the 1990s: Is the Glass Half-full or Half-empty? Kevin M. Murphy. and. Finis Welch

Theoretical approaches to the analysis of trade and poverty and a review of related literature on South Africa

The Effect of International Trade on Wages of Skilled and Unskilled Workers: Evidence from Brazil

REGIONAL DISPARITIES IN EMPLOYMENT STRUCTURES AND PRODUCTIVITY IN ROMANIA 1. Anca Dachin*, Raluca Popa

Impulse paper: Economic globalisation Who s winning, who s losing out? Thieß Petersen, Senior Advisor, the Bertelsmann Stiftung, Gütersloh

The Backlash Against Globalization

PROJECTING THE LABOUR SUPPLY TO 2024

WhyHasUrbanInequalityIncreased?

The labor market in Japan,

The Minimum Wage. Introduction. Impacts on Employment

Wage Rigidity and Spatial Misallocation: Evidence from Italy and Germany

Canadian Labour Market and Skills Researcher Network

Poverty and Inequality

Wage inequality in Germany What role does global trade play?

Distributional Consequences of Trade and Technology

Rev. soc. polit., god. 25, br. 3, str , Zagreb 2018.

Gains from Trade. Is Comparative Advantage the Ideology of the Comparatively Advantaged?

Trade, informality and employment in a lowincome country: The case of Vietnam

Economic Globalization Under Pressure Why People in Industrial Nations Are Increasingly Critical of Globalization

Online Appendices for Moving to Opportunity

STRENGTHENING RURAL CANADA: Fewer & Older: The Coming Population and Demographic Challenges in Rural Newfoundland & Labrador

Earnings Inequality: Stylized Facts, Underlying Causes, and Policy

Accounting for the role of occupational change on earnings in Europe and Central Asia Maurizio Bussolo, Iván Torre and Hernan Winkler (World Bank)

US Trade and Wages: The Misleading Implications of Conventional Trade Theory

Economic and Political Consequences of China s Rise: Lessons from the China Shock

The Impact of Trade on Inequality in Developing Countries

The Jus Semper Global Alliance Living Wages North and South

Transcription:

No. 57 February 218 The impact of Chinese import competition on the local structure of employment and wages in France Clément Malgouyres External Trade and Structural Policies Research Division This Rue de la Banque presents the findings of research carried out at the Banque de France. The views expressed in this post are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the position of the Banque de France. Any errors or omissions are the responsibility of the authors. How has competition from Chinese exports affected the French labour market? This article aims to answer this question by exploiting the variation in exposure to competition from China across employment zones. The results suggest that around 13% of the decline in manufacturing employment in France from 21 to 27 is due to Chinese competition. The adverse effect on hourly wages is uniform along the wage distribution in the manufacturing sector, and concentrated in the middle of the distribution in the other sectors. The impact on the lowest wages is small, probably as a result of the lower limit set by the statutory minimum wage. The estimated impacts, albeit negative, do not necessarily imply that trade with China has not been generally beneficial. An assessment in terms of welfare would require the measurement of gains to consumers and firms that use imported intermediate goods and whose productivity gains also ultimately benefit consumers. The emergence of China as an industrial and trading power The impact of heightened import competition from low wage countries on manufacturing sector employment and wage inequalities is subject to intense debate in developed countries; and China is a key player among emerging countries. In the space of a decade (1998 28), it increased its share of global exports from 3.3% to 9.5%. Chart 1 shows France s imports and balance of trade vis à vis China and a range of low cost countries. The particular nature of trade relations between France and China not only results from the high growth rate of Chinese exports to France (see Chart 1a) but also from a substantial deficit in France s balance of trade (see Chart 1b). 1 Assessing the local impacts of a global shock The aim of this Rue de la Banque, which is derived from Malgouyres (216), is to estimate the effect of the huge surge in Chinese import competition on the local structure of employment and wage inequalities in employment zones in France. 2 It follows the same empirical strategy as that applied by Autor et al. (213) but also draws on the wealth of French data to assess the impact of this shock not only on employment and the average wage but also the impact along the wage distributions and on the type of jobs affected. The empirical strategy consists in exploiting the fact that (i) changes in productivity and Chinese exports are highly heterogeneous across industries within the 1 We can also see a clear acceleration from 21 when China joined the World Trade Organization. 2 An employment zone is a geographical area within which most of the labour force lives and works and firms can find the majority of the workforce needed to fill the jobs on offer. Dividing France into employment zones provides a suitable breakdown for the analysis of the local functioning of the labour market. 1 www.banque-france.fr

No. 57 February 218 C1 France s imports and balance of trade vis à vis China and other low cost countries (in current USD billions) C2 Development of exposure to Chinese import competition in the different employment zones (21 to 27) a) Imports 6 5 4 3 2 1 1996 1997 1998 1999 2 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 21 211 b) Balance of trade 1-1 -2 (1.3; 6] (.9; 1.3] (.7;.9] (.5;.7] [;.5] Source: Malgouyres (216). Note: The employment zones are classified into five categories by shades of blue, with zones where Chinese competition was most intense between 21 and 27 represented by the deepest blue (max. [1.3, 6] = USD 1,3 to USD 6, per job in the manufacturing sector). -3-4 1996 1997 1998 1999 2 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 21 211 Low-cost countries Source: Malgouyres (216). China manufacturing sector 3 and (ii) there is a significant variation in manufacturing specialisation between different employment zones in France. As a result, the rapid surge in Chinese competition will affect employment zones differently depending on their initial specialisation. By interacting the initial industrial composition at the local level with sectoral imports at the national level, we calculate an index of exposure to Chinese import competition. This index captures the value of imports per worker that each employment zone faces. It varies depending on the initial share and the local specialisation of the manufacturing sector. Chart 2 shows the share of the change in this index during the 21 to 27 period, which is attributable to differences in specialisation within the manufacturing sector of each employment zone for the whole of metropolitan France. We find that the changes are highly heterogeneous between employment zones. We will use this geographical variation to assess the effect of Chinese competition on local labour market outcomes. Significant effects on manufacturing employment We first consider the effects on local employment. Chart 3 shows the relationship between local employment growth (y axis) and changes in the index of exposure to Chinese import competition (x axis) between 1995 and 27. We find a strong negative relationship in regard to manufacturing sector employment (see Chart 3a). We also find a negative, albeit weaker, relationship between growth in non manufacturing sector employment and changes in the index of exposure to Chinese import competition (see Chart 3b). The econometric analysis confirms the negative correlation illustrated in Chart 3. The results for the manufacturing sector suggest that the average increase in import competition between 21 and 27 of approximately USD 1, per worker caused a drop in local employment growth of around 6 percentage points. 3 For example, growth in Chinese exports has been particularly strong in the textile and clothing industries, as well as in toy manufacturing, but has been relatively limited in the chemical, pharmaceutical and food products industries. 2

No. 57 February 218 C3 Relationship between local employment and Chinese import competition (1995 to 27) (x axis : change in index of exposure to Chinese import competition; y axis : employment growth rate in %) a) Manufacturing sector 6 5 4 3 2 1-1 -2-3 -4-5 -4-3 -2-1 1 2 3 4 5 6 b) Non tradable sector 6 5 4 3 2 1-1 -2-3 -4-5 -4-3 -2-1 1 2 3 4 5 6 Source: Malgouyres (216). Note: Each point corresponds to an employment zone for a given period (1995 to 21 and 21 to 27). Variables are expressed as deviations from the period average. The non-tradable sector excludes public and parapublic sector employment. The presence of multiplier effects The effects on the non manufacturing sector are less pronounced but they are nonetheless far from negligible and are statistically significant. The average increase in Chinese competition from 21 to 27 was associated with a 3.5 percentage point decrease in local, non manufacturing sector employment. These adverse effects on a category of jobs often considered to be sheltered from international competition confirm the presence of significant local multiplier effects (Moretti, 21). The non manufacturing sector is largely made up of businesses whose production is not exportable and that depend heavily on local demand. In simplified terms, the negative shock to the manufacturing sector caused by the increase in Chinese competition propagates to the local non export sector through at least two channels. First, the shock results in a drop in local demand, which should exert downward pressure on employment in the non export sector. Second, the decline in manufacturing employment at the local level in the absence of perfect spatial mobility of the workforce should lead to a positive labour supply shock to the non export sector. The estimated impact results from the combined effects of these two channels. Our results suggest that over a horizon of six years, for every ten jobs destroyed in the manufacturing sector, around six are lost in the non tradable sector. What is the aggregate impact on employment in France? Assessing the aggregate impact of trade with China on employment in France using estimates based on local variation across employment zones is problematic. Indeed, the estimated impacts are relative: the decline in manufacturing employment has been faster in the most exposed employment zones than in the least exposed zones. But it is possible that through general equilibrium effects, the less exposed zones have benefited from the other zones exposure. A potentially significant general equilibrium channel is the reallocation of workers between employment zones. If, for example, the contraction of the manufacturing sector in a badly affected employment zone leads to the out migration of the workforce from that zone to another, it is possible that the estimated local impacts are more severe than the aggregate impact. 4 Chinese competition, in a borderline case, would have therefore simply led to the redistribution of jobs between zones, with no aggregate impact. Nevertheless, this adjustment margin plausibly implies a drop in the population of the areas directly affected by heightened Chinese competition, which is not observed. We perform a simple quantification exercise based on the assumption that the general equilibrium effects between zones cancel out in order to isolate the share of the growth in Chinese exports to France that is due to the expansion of Chinese competition rather than changes in French demand. It is estimated that between 21 and 27, 9, jobs were lost in the manufacturing sector and a further 19, jobs were lost in the non manufacturing sector as a result of Chinese competition. This represents around 13% of the decline in manufacturing sector employment over the same period. This is lower than 4 It should also be noted that the growth in exports to China has created jobs in other sectors, even though additional results based on net trade suggest that this effect is probably small in scale. 3

No. 57 February 218 the figure calculated by Autor et al. (213) for the United States, where the impact was estimated at around 5%, but significantly higher than in other European countries, particularly Germany, whose industrial base counts a smaller proportion of sectors in which China s comparative advantage most rapidly took hold (Dauth et al., 213). Job polarisation In addition to its impact on the number of jobs, how does Chinese competition affect the employment structure? The French labour market, like the labour markets of other advanced economies, has undergone a process of job polarisation (Goos et al., 214). Polarisation refers to the disproportionate growth in jobs within occupations that are traditionally at either extreme of the wage distribution, relative to jobs situated in the middle. Chart 4 shows that job polarisation between 1995 and 27 mainly took place in the non manufacturing sector whereas in the manufacturing sector, we can see a decreasing monotonic C4 Labour market polarisation in France from 1995 to 27 (x axis : reversed ranking of occupation based on average wages in 1995; y axis : employment growth rate in %) a) Manufacturing sector 1 75 5 25-25 -5 5 1 15 2 b) Non tradable sector 1 75 5 25-25 -5 5 1 15 2 Source: Malgouyres (216). Note: Each point corresponds to an occupation. The size of the circle is proportional to the total number of jobs within an occupation in 1995. relationship between the reverse initial wage rank and employment growth of an occupation. By tailoring the method developed by Juhn et al. (1993), we find that in contrast to the aggregate trends observed, the surge in Chinese competition has contributed to polarising employment within the manufacturing sector, but not in the non tradable sector. Adverse though differentiated effects on wages The theoretical literature on the effects of international trade on the relative remuneration of factors of production is extensive and long standing. The standard models show that although international trade generates aggregate gains, trade openness does not generally lead to a Pareto improvement. Heckscher Ohlin Samuelson (HOS) type models, for example, predict that trade openness increases the remuneration for the relatively abundant factors in each country at the expense of relatively scarce factors of production. In a country where skilled labour is relatively abundant such as France, this therefore implies an inegalitarian effect that would result in a rise in the relative wages of the skilled workforce. More recent research both theoretical and empirical shows that where in the presence of firm heterogeneity, trade is likely to amplify residual inequalities, i.e. inequalities that are not explained by observable variables such as education or occupational status. 5 Chart 5 shows the estimated impact on hourly wages for different percentiles of the wage distribution. We observe an average negative impact in the manufacturing sector. This finding conflicts with the results of Autor et al. (213), who concluded that wages in this sector were unaffected. 6 The effect is relatively uniform along the wage distribution in the manufacturing sector. In the non tradable sector, the average impact is weaker and wage effects are concentrated in the middle of the wage distribution. Consequently, we find that the shock at the local level is associated with an increase in inequalities at the upper end of the wage distribution the ratio of the 5 For example, Amiti and Davis (212) show that trade liberalisation in Indonesia magnified wage dispersion by generating salary increases for workers at exporting and importing firms while reducing salaries in firms that only operated in the domestic market. See Harrison et al. (211) for a recent review of the relationship between globalisation and inequality. 6 It should be noted that the estimated negative impact is not incompatible with the existence of downward wage rigidities in that it can simply be due to a smaller, though nevertheless positive, increase in wages or a cut in starting salaries. 4

No. 57 February 218 C5 The impact of Chinese competition along the wage distribution (x axis : percentile; y axis : estimated impact on growth in hourly wages) a) Manufacturing sector b) Non tradable sector 1 1-1 -1-2 -3-2 -3-4 -4-5 -5-6 -6-7 1 15 2 25 3 35 4 45 5 55 6 65 7 75 8 85 9-7 1 15 2 25 3 35 4 45 5 55 6 65 7 75 8 85 9 Source: Malgouyres (216). Note: Each point corresponds to the estimated impact on growth over a six year period of the percentile shown on the x axis. For example, at the 2th percentile (the wage level at which 2% of employees in an employment zone earn a lower wage and 8% are paid a higher wage) the impact represents a reduction of 1.4 percentage points in the manufacturing sector and.7 percentage point in the non traded sector (vertical line: 95% confidence interval). 85th percentile relative to the median wage rises and a decrease at the lower end the ratio of the median wage relative to the 15th percentile falls. As a result of these two opposing movements, the ratio between the 85th and 15th percentiles an overall measure of wage inequality remains unchanged. However, a supplementary analysis demonstrates that Chinese competition is linked to an increase in this ratio in employment zones where minimum wage coverage is low. With regards to the adjustment margin, the negative impact of the shock on total labour earnings is due in large part (7%) to a reduction in working hours and to a lesser extent (3%) to a decrease in the average hourly wage. China has not been generally beneficial from France s point of view. An overall assessment of the impact of trade with China and other emerging countries on aggregate welfare in France would notably require the measurement of gains to consumers, which are assessed as being relatively favourable to low income households (Fajgelbaum and Khandelwal, 216). 7 It would also be advisable to include firms that use imported intermediate goods and whose productivity gains also benefit consumers. Nevertheless, given the substantial local multiplier effects and the limited sectoral and spatial mobility of the workforce, the negative estimated impacts are likely to be long lasting in the most affected employment zones. Conclusion The negative impact of Chinese import competition on jobs and wages does not necessarily mean that trade with 7 As well as the potential positive impacts on exports, notably via access to inputs with lower quality adjusted prices. 5

No. 57 February 218 References Amiti (M.) and Donald (R. D.) (212) Trade, firms, and wages: theory and evidence, Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 79, No. 1, pp. 1 36. Autor (D. H.), Dorn (D.) and Hanson (G. H.) (213) The China syndrome: local labor market effects of import competition in the United States, American Economic Review, Vol. 13, No. 6, pp. 2121 2168. Dauth (W.), Findeisen (S.) and Südekum (J.) (214) The rise of the East and the Far East: German labor markets and trade integration, Journal of the European Economic Association, Vol. 12, No. 6. Fajgelbaum (P.) and Khandelwal (A.) (216) Measuring the unequal gains from trade, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 131. Harrison (A.), McLaren (J.) and McMillan (M.) (211) Recent perspectives on trade and inequality, Annual Review of Economics, Vol. 3, No.1, pp. 261 289. Juhn (C.), Murphy (K. M.) and Pierce (B.) (1993) Wage inequality and the rise in returns to skill, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 11, No. 3, pp. 41 442. Malgouyres (C.) (216) The impact of Chinese import competition on the local structure of employment and wages: evidence from France, Journal of Regional Science, Vol. 57, No. 3, pp. 411 441. Moretti (E.) (21) Local multipliers, American Economic Review, Vol. 1, No. 2, pp. 373 377. Goos (M.), Manning (A.) and Salomons (A.) (214) Explaining job polarization, American Economic Review, Vol. 14, No. 8, August. Published by Banque de France Managing Editor Olivier Garnier Editor in Chief Françoise Drumetz Production Press and Communication Department February 218 www.banque-france.fr 6