INTERNAL INCONSISTENCIES: LINKING THE WASHINGTON CONSENSUS AND POVERTY IN LATIN AMERICA. Rory Creedon LSE MPA (ID) GV444

Similar documents
The Political Challenges of Economic Reforms in Latin America. Overview of the Political Status of Market-Oriented Reform

Latin America and the Caribbean

Latin America in the New Global Order. Vittorio Corbo Governor Central Bank of Chile

Welfare, inequality and poverty

Globalization, economic growth, employment and poverty. The experiences of Chile and Mexico

Is Economic Development Good for Gender Equality? Income Growth and Poverty

remain in favor of the moves made to help Mexico for three reasons.

Development, Politics, and Inequality in Latin America and East Asia

a model for economic and social development in Scotland

Lecture 1. Overview of the Ghanaian Economy. Michael Insaidoo

UNRISD UNITED NATIONS RESEARCH INSTITUTE FOR SOCIAL DEVELOPMENT

HURRICANE KATRINA AND ITS IMPACT ON LATIN AMERICA

Lecture 1 Economic Growth and Income Differences: A Look at the Data

The Big Switch in Latin America: Restoring Growth Through Trade

VENEZUELA: Oil, Inflation and Prospects for Long-Term Growth

GLOBALIZATION S CHALLENGES FOR THE DEVELOPED COUNTRIES

EVOLUTION OF STRUCTURAL ADJUSTMENT POLICY IN AFRICA. Kodjo Evlo Université de Lomé Accra, 20 July 2015

Trans-national Policy Making:Towards Tri-Continental Perspective Abstract

Reducing poverty amidst high levels of inequality: Lessons from Latin America and the Caribbean

OFFICIAL DEVELOPMENT ASSISTANCE AND THE FIGHT AGAINST POVERTY AND HUNGER IN LATIN AMERICA AND THE CARIBBEAN

LECTURE 23: A SUMMARY OF CAPITAL IN THE 21 ST CENTURY

Social Policy and Inequality in Latin America Compared to Other Countries

New Perspectives of Development for Latin America: Critiques of the Past and Proposals for the Future. Joseph E. S+glitz October 2015

1. Define GDP. The market value of all final goods and services produced within a nation in a given time period

CHAPTER 12: The Problem of Global Inequality

The State, the Market, And Development. Joseph E. Stiglitz World Institute for Development Economics Research September 2015

The repercussions of the crisis on the countries of Latin America and the Caribbean

Final exam: Political Economy of Development. Question 2:

Transition: Changes after Socialism (25 Years Transition from Socialism to a Market Economy)

Strengthening Financial Markets and Corporate Governance. Executive Summary

GLOBALIZATION AND DEVELOPMENT

THE AMERICAS. The countries of the Americas range from THE AMERICAS: QUICK FACTS

Unpaid domestic work: its relevance to economic and social policies

Growth and Migration to a Third Country: The Case of Korean Migrants in Latin America

TRENDS AND PROSPECTS OF KOREAN ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT: FROM AN INTELLECTUAL POINTS OF VIEW

Will the US turn into a modern day Weimar Germany? Marshall Auerback

Latin America Public Security Index 2013

Latin America's Energy Outlook:

Gertrude Tumpel-Gugerell: The euro benefits and challenges

Governance & Development. Dr. Ibrahim Akoum Division Chief Arab Financial Markets Arab Monetary Fund

Neo-liberalism and the Asian Financial Crisis

for Latin America (12 countries)

Honors Thesis: The Veil of Communism: An Analysis of Lifespan, GDP per Capita, Human Capital, and Agricultural Productivity in Eastern Europe

General Certificate of Education Advanced Level Examination January 2012

Issued by the PECC Standing Committee at the close of. The 13th General Meeting of the Pacific Economic Cooperation Council

island Cuba: Reformulation of the Economic Model and External Insertion I. Economic Growth and Development in Cuba: some conceptual challenges.

Globalization and social development

Economic Development: Miracle, Crisis and Regionalism

Political Economy of. Post-Communism

Trends in inequality worldwide (Gini coefficients)

Globalization: What Did We Miss?

Marx, Capitalist Development, and the Turkish Crisis of 2001

Copyrighted Material

Test Bank for Economic Development. 12th Edition by Todaro and Smith

Social stratification under tension in a globalized era

COMMERCIAL INTERESTS, POLITICAL INFLUENCE, AND THE ARMS TRADE

What has changed about the global economic structure

Poverty in the Third World

Informal Summary Economic and Social Council High-Level Segment

THE EFFECTS OF INTEGRATION AND THE GLOBAL ECONOMIC CRISIS ON THE COUNTRIES IN SOUTH- EASTERN EUROPE

Economic and Social Progress in Latin America: A Focus on the Policies of Chile, Argentina and Brazil

Jens Thomsen: The global economy in the years ahead

Globalization and decent work in the Americas

MIDDLE CLASSES, MOBILITY, ECONOMIC GROWTH AND DEMOCRACY IN LATIN AMERICA

UNCTAD Public Symposium June, A Paper on Macroeconomic Dimensions of Inequality. Contribution by

LSE Global South Unit Policy Brief Series

INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION IN THE AMERICAS

Charting Cambodia s Economy

Youth Employment Project Call for Consultant

Report to the Economic and Social Council on Subprogramme 3: Macroeconomic Policies and Growth

Oxfam Education

Development Policy Choice in Ethiopia

Adam Habib (2013) South Africa s Suspended Revolution: hopes and prospects. Johannesburg: Wits University Press

America in the Global Economy

Globalisation and Open Markets

RULE OF LAW AND ECONOMIC GROWTH - HOW STRONG IS THEIR INTERACTION?

Trends in within-country

Celebrating 20 Years of the Bank of Mexico s Independence. Remarks by. Ben S. Bernanke. Chairman. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

Modern Political Economy and Latin America: Theory and Policy Edited by Jeffry Frieden, Manuel Pastor and Michael Tomz (Forthcoming, Westview Press)

History of Trade and Globalization

Economics International Finance. Sample for Introduction with Annotated Bibliography

The Global Crunch and Health: Issue, Threats and Responses

ADDRESS BY THE CHAIRMAN OF THE HELLENIC FEDERATION OF ENTERPRISES (SEV) Theodoros Fessas. at the SEV Annual General Assembly. Tuesday, 29 May 2018

Procedia - Social and Behavioral Sciences 109 ( 2014 ) The East Asian Model of Economic Development and Developing Countries

Edexcel (B) Economics A-level

Remittances in times of financial instability

Thoughts on Globalization, 1/15/02 Pete Bohmer

TRADE POLICY REVIEW OF SOUTH AFRICA 1-2 JUNE GATT Council's Evaluation

Beyond Recrimination: Perspectives on U.S. - Taiwan Trade Tensions, by Jimmy W. Wheeler

The Political Culture of Democracy in El Salvador, 2008

HOW ECONOMIES GROW AND DEVELOP Macroeconomics In Context (Goodwin, et al.)

International Development and Aid

When unemployment becomes a long-term condition

WORLD RADIOLOGY DAY CELEBRATION 2013

2017 SADC People s Summit Regional Debates and Public Speaking Gala. Strengthening Youth Participation in Policy Dialogue Processes

Did NAFTA Help Mexico? An Assessment After 20 Years February 2014

POLITICAL AND PUBLIC SERVICE UNDER-REPRESENTATION. Declining Citizenship CITIZENSHIP FOREIGN-BORN CANADIAN RESIDENTS 2011

ENHANCING DOMESTIC RESOURCES MOBILIZATION THROUGH FISCAL POLICY

Find us at: Subscribe to our Insights series at: Follow us

Chapter 13: NAFTA and Mexican Industrial Development

Transcription:

INTERNAL INCONSISTENCIES: LINKING THE WASHINGTON CONSENSUS AND POVERTY IN LATIN AMERICA Rory Creedon LSE MPA (ID) GV444 In what way did the Washington Consensus affect poverty in Latin America? There is a wealth of qualitative evidence that links the increase in poverty seen in Latin America between 1980 and 2002 to the free-market reforms undertaken in that period. There is a particularly strong association between poverty and the negative effects on employment of sudden exposure to external competition. 1 Empirically however, the causal underpinning of this correlation is somewhat more controversial. Characteristic of the debate is the differing stance taken by Huber & Solt as against Walton. The former conclude that there is a clear statistical link between poverty and the reforms 2 whereas the latter maintains that once other macro level variables are controlled for there is no statistically significant relationship. 3 These contradictory stances are evidence of the chronic endogeneity and omitted variable problems that plague macro level empirical analysis of this sort, and whilst it is prudent to be sensitive to these different debates, this paper starts from the non-controversial assumption that the policies of the Washington Consensus at best did very little to address the problem of poverty in Latin America, and at worst failed to prevent a large scale increase in the number of people living in poverty. This essay argues that this failure sprung from an internal inconsistency between the initial concept of the Washington Consensus as a short term plan for macroeconomic stabilization, and the policy tools recommended. Whilst certain of the policy tools were pertinent for addressing the severe hyperinflation and balance of payments problems faced by Latin American economies (particularly reducing fiscal deficits, and ensuring a competitive exchange rate), others (particularly trade liberalization) should have been part of a more comprehensive development strategy. This conceptual confusion led to implementation of long-term development strategy policies as though they were short-term macroeconomic policy programmes and this kept poverty extremely high in Latin America. By 1992 all the major economies of Latin America had embarked upon free market reforms. 4 During the reform period there was a concurrent and significant increase in poverty in the region: In 1980 the percentage of the population living in poverty stood at 40.5%. By 1990 this had risen to 48.3%. In 2002 the figure was 44%, a slight decrease from a decade earlier, but still higher than the 1980 level. Moreover the absolute number of people living in poverty rose consistently throughout this time period, from 136 million in 1980 to 221 million in 2002. 5 That poverty should not be addressed by the reforms is perhaps not entirely surprising. The original document in 1 SAPRIN The Policy Roots of Economic Crisis and Poverty (2002) 2 E. Huber and F. Solt Successes and Failures of Neoliberalism Latin American Research Review, Vol. 39, No. 3 (2004) pg.156 3 M Walton Neoliberalism in Latin America: Good, Bad, or Incomplete? Latin American Research Review, Vol. 39, No. 3 (2004) pg. 174 4 E. Huber and F. Solt Successes and Failures of Neoliberalism Latin American Research Review, Vol. 39, No. 3 (2004) pg.150 5 ECLAC Social Panorama of Latin America (2010)

which John Williamson coined the term Washington Consensus was concerned with how to deal with the debt crisis 6 not about how to reduce poverty. Jeffrey Sachs, one of the architects of the Bolivian adjustment commented that Bolivia had a miserable, poor economy with hyperinflation, and that if it followed the adjustment programme, it would be left a miserable, poor economy with stable prices. 7 Conceptually then, the Washington Consensus was not a programme for development, or indeed growth, it was merely concerned with the stabilization of economies that were in free-fall. 8 However, despite these arguments, when returning to the policy tools that were recommended as part of the Washington Consensus one can distinguish between those policies which might reasonably form part of short term stabilization plans and those which are inherently part of longer-term strategies for development. I argue that fiscal deficit reduction and maintaining a competitive exchange rate belong to the former group, whilst trade liberalization belongs firmly in the latter. Fiscal deficits were thought to be a key source of macroeconomic disequilibrium, inflation and capital flight 9 and thus dealing with such deficits was a key policy recommendation for the Latin American economies in crisis. Similarly a competitive exchange rate was recommended to redress seriously overvalued currencies in Latin America thus promoting exports, discouraging imports, and dealing with huge current account deficits that stood at around 20% GDP for Brazil, Peru and Chile in 1980. 10 At this level of generality these policies seem to fit naturally into a toolbox of policies that can be implemented to encourage macroeconomic stability. The spending cuts and devaluation these policies implied were simple and easily implementable partial solutions to what were very grave problems. Although the reduced government spending implied by the deficit reduction and the rising prices and fall in domestic demand implied by the devaluation would undoubtedly cause recessionary pain, particularly at the bottom end of the income distribution, it would be a temporary cost to pay for increased stability and a return to an economic environment where growth could resume. Additionally, from the point of view of the poor, a prospect theory perspective claims that the losses these policies implied were preferred to the continued enormous losses sustained due to the hyperinflation that was characteristic of the pre-reform period. 11 The same argument cannot be made regarding trade policy even at a high level of generality, meaning that means of implementation are not taken into account. Shifting toward an outward oriented economy 12 when the explicit development discourse and practice in Latin America had been centred on import substitution and inward orientation does not seem to occupy same policy space as the quick fix fiscal policies outlined above. Rather, a liberal trade policy is at the heart of the choices states 6 J. Williamson (ed.) Latin American Adjustment: How Much Has Happened? (1990) pg. 7 7 Quoted in Duncan Green The Silent Revolution: The Rise and Crisis of Market Economics in Latin America (2003) pg. 74 8 J. Williamson Economic Reform: Content, Progress, Prospects A lecture delivered to Indian Council for Research on International Economic Relations (Nov. 23 1999) 9 J. Williamson (ed.) Latin American Adjustment: How Much Has Happened? (1990) pg. 10 10 J. Sachs External Debt and Macroeconomic Performance in Latin America and East Asia Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Vol. 1985, No. 2 (1985) pg. 533 11 Kurt Weyland The Politics of Market Reform in Fragile Democracies: Argentina, Brazil, Peru, and Venezuela (2003) pg. 96 12 J. Williamson (ed.) Latin American Adjustment: How Much Has Happened? (1990) pg. 14

make about paths toward development, just as the illiberal trade policy Latin America pursued in the middle decades of the twentieth century was due to its choice of developmental path. Seen thus, there is an inconsistency within the core policies of the Washington Consensus between those that can be thought of as legitimate tools for the stated goal of economic stabilization (deficit reduction and a competitive exchange rate) and those that seem to belong to different set of long term development strategy policies. The most important of these is the trade liberalization policy, although also of great importance are the privatization and capital account liberalization policies. John Williamson has expressed disapproval that his policy recommendations were adopted into a broader neo-liberal framework 13. However, given that policies relating to trade and state owned companies are at the heart of any development strategy, I would suggest that this this neo-liberal co-option is not a great surprise. In other words, the Washington Consensus was not as narrowly defined in practice as perhaps it was intended conceptually. This conceptual confusion in turn spilled over into the way in which the policies were implemented. Trade liberalization was treated as a quick fix to economic malaise, and this has had serious consequences for domestic industry, employment and thus poverty. This is reflected in the speed in which liberalization occurred. Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Peru and Mexico, amongst others, all liberalized their trade regimes in a period of 2-3 years, 14 with the main instrument of reform being across the board liberalization of imports. In many places this lead to a large scale deindustrialization. In Mexico, in 2000 only 25% of the productive firms that existed in 1982 were still extant. 15 Similar stories are told in Argentina and Ecuador as firms supported by the import substitution regime were exposed to the world markets as uncompetitive and thus went out of business. This had a large impact on unemployment which rose to 66% in Ecuador by 1990 16 and could partially explain both the rising numbers of those living in poverty across the region, the high levels of participation in the informal sector which can exacerbate poverty due to the lack of inclusion of informal workers in social security programmes. As Agosin and Ffrench-Davis illustrate this model of liberalization was by no means the only one available to Latin American policy makers. An alternative would have been an export-lead strategy such as those implemented by the East Asian miracle states, whereby producers benefit from reduced input prices due to lower import tariffs, but are given continuing protection from competing imports such that they have the necessary time to restructure. A strict timeline is set in which producers must innovate and become globally competitive before being exposed to the vicissitudes of the world markets unprotected. 17 This model implies a gradual increase in domestic efficiency, and thus a much lesser loss of productive capacity and domestic jobs, when markets are liberalized. Such a strategy is however necessarily a much longer term view 13 J. Williamson Economic Reform: Content, Progress, Prospects A lecture delivered to Indian Council for Research on International Economic Relations (Nov. 231999) 14 M Agosin and R. Ffrench-Davis Trade Liberalization and Growth: Recent Experiences in Latin America Journal of Interamerican Studies and World Affairs, Vol. 37, No.3 (1995) pg. 17 15 SAPRIN The Policy Roots of Economic Crisis and Poverty (2002) 16 Ibid. 17 M Agosin and R. Ffrench-Davis Trade Liberalization and Growth: Recent Experiences in Latin America Journal of Interamerican Studies and World Affairs, Vol. 37, No.3 (1995) pg. 17-20

than the model favoured in Latin America that saw a massive and near instantaneous reduction in the volume and use of productive resources including labour. It seems plausible that such a long-term strategy would have had a much lesser impact on bankruptcies, unemployment and thus poverty than the short-term strategies actually implemented. However such long-term thinking did not fit within the rubric of shortterm stabilization promulgated by the Washington Consensus. Similar evidence of short-term thinking can be found in the social policies that accompanied trade liberalization. Most of the liberalizing economies chose the pure form of trade liberalization, labeled the standard model by J. Sheahan 18 whereby private capital flows are the determinant of competitive advantage and the structures of production. This was the model chosen by Chile in the first years of the 1980s, as well as Mexico and Peru. 19 The model was accompanied in Chile by large increases in poverty and inequality 20 and was thus subsequently modified to encompass what Sheahan calls the competitive model which aims to build up the capacity of domestic production and factors of production to compete on a global level. The accompanying social policies these two models imply are vastly different. The standard model puts an emphasis on emergency relief from the extreme poverty that adjustment causes. The competitive model focuses on providing sufficient education, healthcare and improving opportunities for the abundant factors in society, in Latin America s case, unskilled labour. This model is infinitely more nuanced than the standard model and it recognizes that pressures from competitive advantage are not sufficient generate new industries in a short time frame. The ability of nations to restructure following an opening to trade depend heavily on promoting internal mobility, creating infrastructure and, perhaps most critically, increasing levels of human capital that allow workers to move with minimal friction through the labour market. As such a successful trade policy is comprised of much more than merely import liberalization and is inherently more longterm than the original conception of the Washington Consensus. Starting as it did from a position of relative underdevelopment, the crushing blow that liberalization dealt to those working in import protected industries in Latin America, was aggravated by the concurrent cuts in government spending on education and healthcare pursuant to the goal of reducing deficits. Mexico saw a 40.8% reduction in state spending on education in 1983 21 greatly reducing quality at the same time that access to education fell as more families fell into unemployment related poverty. It is clear therefore that the necessary investments in social expenditure that could have led to increased opportunities for the poor from trade liberalization, were in fact being scaled back. Thus we see that the marriage of trade and social policy was not viewed as a long-term developmental strategy, but rather a short-term corrective measures to end macroeconomic instability and as such trade liberalization had at best no power to improve the region s level of poverty, and at worst significant power to add new families to the roll call of the poor. The Washington Consensus was conceptualized as set of policies designed to stabilize the turbulent Latin American economies. It was not conceived as a programme 18 J. Sheahan the Effects of Liberalization Programs on Poverty and Inequality Latin American Research review, Vol. 32, No.3 (1997) pg. 10 19 Ibid. 20 Ibid. 21 SAPRIN The Policy Roots of Economic Crisis and Poverty (2002) pg. 151

for development. However, the policies enshrined in the doctrine belong both to the tools used for macroeconomic adjustment, and to long term development strategies. I have argued that there is therefore an internal inconsistency between the Washington Consensus conception, and its policy recommendations. This is because, even absent information about implementation, dealing with deficits and the exchange rate are a natural part of the macroeconomists toolbox whereas the same cannot be said for privatization, capital account liberalization, and most importantly as I have shown, trade liberalization. These policies are at the heart of any development strategy, and are inherently long-term and based on conceptions of, and paths toward development. This internal inconsistency or confusion played out in the manner in which the policies were implemented in Latin America. Long-term strategies were treated as quick short-term fixes. In the area of trade this led to deindustrialization, huge unemployment and I would suggest, poverty. This trend was exacerbated by cuts in social spending on human capital investment which could have smoothed the transition pains of the poor. Ultimately what was in practice the most destructive of the Washington Consensus policies had the potential to be the most welfare improving; there is no better way to lift the poor out of poverty than by the opportunities afforded them by trade. However, in order to capitalize on these welfare enhancing properties of trade, a long-term strategy for managing liberalization combined with real investment in improving human capabilities is needed. Sadly, such long-term visions were not part of the short-term stabilization programme offered by the Washington consensus.