The Mathematics of Apportionment

Similar documents
Chapter 4 The Mathematics of Apportionment

The Mathematics of Apportionment

Name Chapter 14 Apportionment. 1. What was the Great Compromise in 1787? Populations of 15 states in 1790 as in your book on page 506:

Chapter 4 The Mathematics of Apportionment

A small country consists of four states. There are 100 seats in the legislature. The populations are: A: 44,800 B: 52,200 C: 49,200 D: 53,800

In the next few lectures, we consider the problem of dividing indivisible things (say, seats in a legislature) among players (say, states) in

Rounding decimals or fractions to whole numbers might seem to be one of the most boring subjects ever.

Section Apportionment Methods. Copyright 2013, 2010, 2007, Pearson, Education, Inc.

Note: Article I, section 2, of the Constitution was modified by section 2 of the 14th amendment.

Chapter Four: The Mathematics of Apportionment

The Constitution directs Congress to reapportion seats in the House

Chapter 15 Section 4 - Slide 1

STUDY GUIDE FOR TEST 2

Lesson 2.4 More Apportionment Models and Paradoxes

Math of Election APPORTIONMENT

Proportional (Mis)representation: The Mathematics of Apportionment

Apportionment Problems

Presidential Election Democrat Grover Cleveland versus Benjamin Harrison. ************************************ Difference of 100,456

Apportionment. Seven Roads to Fairness. NCTM Regional Conference. November 13, 2014 Richmond, VA. William L. Bowdish

Fair Division in Theory and Practice

MATH 1340 Mathematics & Politics

n(n 1) 2 C = total population total number of seats amount of increase original amount

The Congressional Apportionment Problem Based on the Census : Basic Divisor Methods

The Mathematics of Apportionment

Chapter 12: The Math of Democracy 12B,C: Voting Power and Apportionment - SOLUTIONS

Lesson 2.3. Apportionment Models

Voting and Apportionment(Due by Nov. 25)

CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web

Hamilton s Method. By: Lauren, Lane, Devonte, Sarah, Hannah A, & Katie H

Apportionment Problems

Practice TEST: Chapter 14

The House of Representatives Apportionment Formula: An Analysis of Proposals for Change and Their Impact on States

A comparison between the methods of apportionment using power indices: the case of the U.S. presidential election

For each heir, find the fair share, the items received, the amount of cash, and the final settlement. Summarize your results in a matrix.

Thema Working Paper n Université de Cergy Pontoise, France

Voting and Apportionment(Due with Final Exam)

HOW TO APPORTION FAIRLY

12B,C: Voting Power and Apportionment

Fair Division in Theory and Practice

The 2000 U.S. presidential election was a

The History of the Congressional Apportionment Problem through a Mathematical Lens

CRS Report for Congress

PROPORTIONAL ALLOCATION IN INTEGERS

A New Method of the Single Transferable Vote and its Axiomatic Justification

Satisfaction Approval Voting

Regulating Elections: Districts /252 Fall 2008

WORKING PAPER N On allocating seats to parties and districts: apportionments

Congressional Apportionment: A Liberal Arts Perspective

Allocation of Seats and Voting Power in the Norwegian Parliament

UNITED STATES DEPARTMENT OF COMMERCE et al. v. MONTANA et al. appeal from the united states district court for the district of montana

Regulating Elections: Districts /252 Fall 2012

Voting: Issues, Problems, and Systems, Continued

Year 1 Mental mathematics and fluency in rapid recall of number facts are one of the main aims of the new Mathematics Curriculum.

Creating the Constitution

COLUMBIA UNIVERSITY SENATE

Sampling Equilibrium, with an Application to Strategic Voting Martin J. Osborne 1 and Ariel Rubinstein 2 September 12th, 2002.

Trump s victory like Harrison, not Hayes and Bush

DHSLCalc.xls What is it? How does it work? Describe in detail what I need to do

LAST WORDS ON THE APPORTIONMENT PROBLEM

Tie Breaking in STV. 1 Introduction. 3 The special case of ties with the Meek algorithm. 2 Ties in practice

arxiv: v2 [math.ho] 12 Oct 2018

A New Method for Congressional Apportionment (Congress/representation/fair division/u.s. Constitution) M. L. BALINSKI AND H. P.

*April 1997 *Supersedes Rules of the University Senate, Senate Assembly, and Senate Advisory Committee on University Affairs, dated December 1989.

Section I: Apportionment. Part A: The History of Apportionment

Random tie-breaking in STV

In this lecture, we will explore weighted voting systems further. Examples of shortcuts to determining winning coalitions and critical players.

Topic 4 Reasons For a

Safe Votes, Sincere Votes, and Strategizing

US vs. European Apportionment Practices: The Conflict between Monotonicity and Proportionality

Magruder s American Government

Lecture 7 A Special Class of TU games: Voting Games

Elections with Only 2 Alternatives

Arithmetic I. Activity Collection Sample file. Featuring real-world contexts: by Frank C. Wilson

Patrick J. Lingane February 7, 2008 A Letter to the Author Improvements to Spitzer s Chapter on Elections

SECTION 1 The President s Job Description. SECTION 2 Presidential Succession and the Vice Presidency

Elections and referendums

Nicholas R. Miller Department of Political Science University of Maryland Baltimore County (UMBC) Baltimore, Maryland

The full speech, as prepared for delivery, is below:

In Elections, Irrelevant Alternatives Provide Relevant Data

The Mathematics of Power: Weighted Voting

Elections and Electoral Systems

THE EXECUTIVE BRANCH THE PRESIDENT S ROLES THE PRESIDENT S JOB. The Presidency. Chapter 13. What are the President s many roles?

Fair Division in Theory and Practice

C H A P T E R 13. CHAPTER 13 The Presidency. What are the President s many roles? What are the formal qualifications necessary to become President?

Voting Criteria April

THE METHOD OF EQUAL PROPORTIONS

STV-PR Weighted Inclusive Gregory Method Rules for Manual Counting

arxiv: v1 [physics.soc-ph] 13 Mar 2018

Magruder s American Government

This situation where each voter is not equal in the number of votes they control is called:

Magruder s American Government

Introduction to the declination function for gerrymanders

The National Legislature Chapter 10 Section 1

LECTURE 3-3: THE ARTICLES OF CONFEDERATION AND THE CONSTITUTION

VOTING SYSTEMS AND ARROW S THEOREM

June 11, Commissioner Susan A. Gendron Maine Department of Education 23 State House Station Augusta, ME Dear Commissioner Gendron,

Delegate Ratios and Methodology

Jeopardy Q $100 Q $100 Q $100 Q $100 Q $100 Q $200 Q $200 Q $200 Q $200 Q $200 Q $300 Q $300 Q $300 Q $300 Q $300 Q $400 Q $400 Q $400 Q $400

Chapter 8: Mass Media and Public Opinion Section 1 Objectives Key Terms public affairs: public opinion: mass media: peer group: opinion leader:

MATH 1340 Mathematics & Politics

Transcription:

MATH 110 Week 4 Chapter 4 Worksheet The Mathematics of Apportionment NAME Representatives... shall be apportioned among the several States... according to their respective Numbers. The actual Enumeration shall be made... every ten Years... - Article 1, Section 2, US Constitution The constitution mandates that every 10 years (years ending in 0 ) the government produce a head count broken down by state. The key purpose of the state population numbers is to meet the constitutional requirement of proportional representation. The Constitution requires that seats in the House of Representatives be apportioned among the... States according to their respective numbers so every 10 years, two things happen: 1. the state population must be determined (by Census) and 2. the seats in the House of Representatives must be apportioned to the states based on their populations. While this does not sound all that complicated, we will investigate in this chapter the mathematics behind appointment and come to find that it has some interesting features. We will begin with an investigation into the following questions: What is an apportionment problem? and What is an apportionment method? 4.1 Apportionment Problems and Apportionment Methods There are two key elements of the dictionary definition of the word apportion: To get an idea of where interesting issues might arrise with apportionment problems, let s look at an example. Example: Kitchen Capitalism Mom has a total of 50 identical caramels which she is planning to divide among her five children. She could clearly divide them evenly by giving each child 10 caramels but she wants to teach them a lesson about the value of work and the relationship between work and reward so instead... She announces to the kids that the candy is going to be divided at the end of the week in proportion to the amount of time each of them spends helping with the weekly kitchen chores (i.e. if you worked twice as long as your brother, you get twice as much candy). The following table shows the amount of work (in minutes) that each child completed during the week: Child Alan Betty Connie Doug Ellie Total Minutes worked 150 78 173 204 295 According to the rules, how much candy should each child get? 1

Apportionment: Basic Concepts and Terminology While there are many different examples of appointment (assigning classrooms to departments in a university, assigning nurses to shifts in a hospital, etc), the standard practice in discussing appointment methods is to borrow terminology from that of legislative appointment and apply it to apportionment problems in general. states: seats: populations: apportionment method: There are also three important concepts that relate to apportionment methods: standard divisor (SD): standard quotas: upper and lower quotas: Let s now introduce a fictional (but realistic) example that we will return to a few times. Example: The Congress of Power Parador is a small republic located in central America and consists of six states: Azcar, Bahia, Cafe, Diamante, Esmeralda, Felicidad (A, B, C, D, E and F ). There are 250 seat in the Congress which are to be apportioned among the six states to their respective population. The following table shows the populations based on the most recent census: Population 1, 646,000 6,936,000 154,000 2,091,000 685,000 988,000 12,500,000 Compute the standard divisor (SD). Compute the standard quotas. Standard quotas are the benchmark for fair apportionment, however we need to somehow convert them to whole numbers (because we cannot have fractions of people!). Rounding is probably the most natural way to do this, but there is a problem. What is it? The most important moral of this example is that conventional rounding of standard quotas is not an apportionment method since it does not guarantee that it will apportion M seats. Our search of a good solution to this problem is the goal of the rest of the chapter. 2

4.2 Hamilton s Method In 1792 Alexander Hamilton proposed the following simple method as a way to apportion the US House of Representatives. Hamilton s Method Step 1: Calculate each state s lower quota. Step 2: Round the standard quota s down and give to each state its lower quota. Step 3: Give the surplus seats (one at a time) to the states with the largest residues (fractional parts) until there are no more surplus seats. Example: Parador s Congress Revisiting the above example, use Hamilton s method to find an apportionment for Parador s congress. Standard Quota Lower Quota Residue Appropriation Do you notice any issues with Hamilton s method? 4.3 Jefferson s Method Notice that in Hamilton s method, it is the handling of the surplus seats that yields preferential treatment. So the idea behind our next method is to tweak things to that when the quotas are rounded down there are no surplus seats! How is this done? By changing the divisor, we will then change the quotas. By using a smaller divisor we will make the quotas bigger. In fact, we want to get the divisor just right so that when we round down, the surplus seats are gone. Thomas Jefferson proposed this method for the US House of Representatives in 1792 and it generally works as follows: Jefferson s Method Step 1: Find a suitable divisor d. Step 2: Using d as the divisor, compute each state s modified quota (modified quote = state population/d). Step 3: Each state is apportioned its modified lower quota. The difficult part of implementing Jefferson s method is Step 1 (i.e. picking the exact right d). Although it sounds, complicated we will really only use a guess-and-check method to find such d as illustrated by the following flow chart: 3

Make d smaller. Computation: 1. Divide state populations by d. Start: Guess d (d < SD). 2. Round numbers down. End. 3. Add numbers. Let total = T. Make d larger. Let s now try this method out on our previous example. Example: Parador s Congress Recall that we want to apportion 250 seats in Parador s Congress and that we found SD to be 50,000. In order to execute Jefferson s method we must first find a new d that fits the specifications above (the flow chart). So we may start by choosing d < 50, 000 to be whatever we want. You may choose 49,999 or 49,000 or even 10... and then follow the directed computations of the flow chart. In the interest of time, the modified divisor you should eventually get (or be lucky enough to choose off the bat!) will be d = 49, 500. Continue on by using the second two steps of Jefferson s method to find an apportionment for Parador s congress. Population 1, 646,000 6,936,000 154,000 2,091,000 685,000 988,000 12,500,000 Modified Quota (d=49,500) Rounded down to One question that is lurking in the background is: Can we really substitute the standard divisor by some other random divisor? 4.4 Adam s & Webster s Methods Adam s Method As you may have guessed at this point, Adam s method we first proposed by John Quincy Adams (in 1832) as an alternative to Jefferson s method. Adam s method is the mirror image of Jefferson s: Instead of rounding all quotas down to their lower quotas, it rounds them up to their upper quotas. 4

Notice though that in this case, something about the divisor d will need to change. What is it? Adam s Method Step 1: Find a suitable divisor d. Step 2: Using d as the divisor, compute each state s modified quota (modified quota = state population/d). Step 3: Each state is apportioned its modified upper quota. To find d: Make d smaller. Computation: 1. Divide state populations by d. Start: Guess d (d > SD). 2. Round numbers up. End. 3. Add numbers. Let total = T. Make d larger. Recall that we want to apportion 250 seats in Parador s Congress and that we found SD to be 50,000. Use Adam s method to find an apportionment for Parador s congress. Population 1, 646,000 6,936,000 154,000 2,091,000 685,000 988,000 12,500,000 Modified Quota (d=50,700) Rounded up to Webster s Method What is the obvious compromise between rounding all the quotas down (Jefferson s method) and rounding all the quotas up (Adam s method)? 5

Recall that we have tried conventional rounding of standard quotas previously but that is not an apportionment method. However, we have not yet tried using conventional rounding of modified quotas. Now that we know we can use modified divisors to manipulate the quotas, it is always possible to find a suitable divisor that will make conventional rounding work. Daniel Webster first proposed this method in 1832 so this method is called Webster s method. Webster s Method Step 1: Find a suitable divisor d. Step 2: Using d as the divisor, compute each state s modified quota (modified quote = state population/d). Step 3: Find the apportionments by rounding each modified quota to the nearest integer. The following is a flow chart illustrating how to find d for this method. Make d smaller. Computation: 1. Divide state populations by d. Start: Guess d = SD. 2. Round numbers conventionally to the nearest integer. End. 3. Add numbers. Let total = T. Make d larger. Let s now try this method out on our previous example. Example: Parador s Congress Recall that we want to apportion 250 seats in Parador s Congress and that we found SD to be 50,000. Use the above chart to find th appropriate d for Webster s method. Use Webster s method to find an apportionment for Parador s congress. Population 1, 646,000 6,936,000 154,000 2,091,000 685,000 988,000 12,500,000 Modified Quota Rounded to 6

4.5 Huntington-Hill Method Until 1940, the method used to apportion the US House of Representatives was chosen by Congress every 10 years, typically for political reasons and with little consideration given to the mathematical subtleties of apportionment or to its consistency. Hamilton s, Jefferson s and Webster s were all used at some point. In 1941, Congress passed and President Roosevelt signed An Act to Provide for Apportioning Representatives in Congress among Several States by the Equal Proportions method known as the 1941 apportionment act. This act made two important changes in the process of apportioning the seats in the House of Representatives every 10 years: 1. the number of seats is permanently set at M = 435, and 2. the method of apportionment is permanently set to be the Huntington-Hill method. The Huntington-Hill method is a sophisticated variation of Webster s method. The Geometric Mean and the Huntington-Hill Rule Under the Huntington-Hill method, quotas are rounded in a manner that is very similar to but not quite the same as the conventional rounding used in Webster s method. Under the Huntington-Hill method, the cutoff point for rounding a quota down or up is a bit top the left of 0.5 and it varies with the size of the quota. To understand these unusual cutoff points for rounding we introduce the two key concepts in this section: geometric mean: Huntington-Hill rounding rule: Examples: Round q using the Huntington-Hill rounding rule. 1. q = 1.51 2. q = 1.41 3. q = 1.42 4. q = 3.48 5. q = 5.48 6. q = 6.48 7. q = 42.49 You may have observed two useful facts about the Huntington-Hill rounding method: There is only a narrow window to the left of 0.5 where Huntington-Hill rounding is different from conventional rounding. 7

The Huntington-Hill Method Once we understand the Huntington-Hill rounding rule, the description of the Huntington-Hill method is straightforward. Huntington-Hill Method Step 1: Find a suitable divisor d. [Here a suitable divisor means a divisor that produces an apportionment of exactly M seats when the quotas (populations divided by d) are rounded using the Huntington-Hill rounding rule.] Step 2: Find the apportionment of each state by rounding its quota using the Huntington-Hill rounding rule. To find d: Make d smaller. Computation: 1. Divide state populations by d. Start: Guess d (d = SD). 2. Round numbers using HH Rounding Rule. End. 3. Add numbers. Let total = T. Make d larger. Example: Parador s Congress Recall that we want to apportion 250 seats in Parador s Congress and that we found SD to be 50,000. Use the Huntington-Hill method to find an apportionment for Parador s congress. Population 1, 646,000 6,936,000 154,000 2,091,000 685,000 988,000 12,500,000 Modified Quota Cutoff point Round quota to 8

4.6 The Quota Rule and Apportionment Paradoxes Each of the apportionment methods has both positive and negative features. Some methods are better than others but none is perfect. Violating the Quota Rule What is the quota rule? If an apportionment method apportions to a state more than U seats we say it violates the upper quota. If an apportionment method apportions to a state less than L seats we say it violates the lower quota. We will now consider how the various methods we learned in this chapter fare with respect to the quota rule. Hamilton s method Jefferson s method Adam s method Webster s and the Huntington-Hill method Apportionment Paradoxes There are three paradoxes that sometimes come up in apportionment problems: 1. Alabama paradox: 2. Population paradox: 3. New-states paradox: Of the five methods, Webster s method and the Huntington-Hill method are in some sense the best because while in theory they can violate the quota rule, in practice this happens very rarely. Of course, it would be ideal to find a method that does not violate the that does not violate the quota rule and does not produce any of the apportionment paradoxes. In 1980, Michel Balinski of the State University of New York and H. Peyton Young to Johns Hopkins University were able to prove that such a method is mathematically impossible. 9

Balinski and Young s Impossibility Theorem If an apportionment method does not violate the quota rule, then apportionment paradoxes are possible. If the apportionment method does not produce apportionment paradoxes, then violations of the quota rule are possible. Summary: Homework: Ch.4 (p.128) #1, 3, 41, 45, 47, 51-57 (odd), 60-63, 76-78 10