Citation IDE Discussion Paper. No

Similar documents
Constitution and Human Rights Provisions in Indonesia: an Unfinished Task in the Transitional Process

Title Impact on Political Institutions in

Handbook on the. Legislative Process

ANALYSIS OF THE INDONESIAN PRESIDENTIAL SYSTEM BASED ON THE 1945 CONSTITUTION OF THE REPUBLIC OF INDONESIA

NEW YORK UNIVERSITY Department of Politics V COMPARATIVE POLITICS Spring Michael Laver. Tel:

The Moral of Politics Constitutes Ideological Perspectives

Samsuri Civic Education Department Faculty of Social Sciences, Yogyakarta State University Indonesia

Title Perspective. Author(s) Sato, Yuri. Citation IDE Research Paper No. 1. Issue Date

Political Participation in Digital World: Transcending Traditional Political Culture in India

Key Concepts & Research in Political Science and Sociology

Public opinion is concerned with specific leaders and government policies.

Cover Page. The handle holds various files of this Leiden University dissertation.

Presidentialism and Political Parties in Indonesia: Why Are All Parties Not Presidentialized?

TYPES OF GOVERNMENTS

This document is downloaded from DR-NTU, Nanyang Technological University Library, Singapore.

CONCEPTUAL FOUNDATIONS OF INTERNATIONAL POLITICS QUESTION 4

POLITICAL SCIENCE (POLS)

Should Indonesia Back to Developmental State Model?

POS 6933 Presidents, Prime Ministers, and Legislatures Department of Political Science University of Florida Spring Semester 2005

SS: Social Sciences. SS 131 General Psychology 3 credits; 3 lecture hours

Chapter I THE CONSTITUTION

DEMOCRACY AND DEVELOPMENT DR. RACHEL GISSELQUIST RESEARCH FELLOW, UNU-WIDER

The Impact of an Open-party List System on Incumbency Turnover and Political Representativeness in Indonesia

NEW YORK UNIVERSITY Department of Politics. V COMPARATIVE POLITICS Spring Michael Laver Tel:

Parliamentary vs. Presidential Systems

POLITICAL SCIENCE (POLI)

The Failure to Transplant Democracy, Markets, and the Rule of Law into the Developing World

Democratic Transition and Consolidation: Regional Practices and Challenges in Pakistan

Article Online Version For online version, check:

POLS - Political Science

INDONESIA S PRESIDENTIALISM: MODERATING STRONG PRESIDENTS, ENHANCING REPRESENTATION

ISSN International Journal of Advanced Research (2016), Volume 4, Issue 6, 7-12 RESEARCH ARTICLE.

Political Science Graduate Program Class Schedule Spring 2014

Syahrul Hidayat Democratisation & new voter mobilisation in Southeast Asia: moderation and the stagnation of the PKS in the 2009 legislative election

POLI 111: INTRODUCTION TO THE STUDY OF POLITICAL SCIENCE Session 8-Political Culture

COMPARATIVE POLITICS

Comparing political. Inglehart s Theory of Value Change and Support for Democracy

This document is downloaded from DR-NTU, Nanyang Technological University Library, Singapore.

Citation IDE Discussion Paper. No

Relationship Of Regional Representative Council With State Institutions In The System Of Constitutional In Indonesia

Comparative Political Systems (GOVT_ 040) July 6 th -Aug. 7 th, 2015

The Indonesia U.S. Caucus of Indonesia s Legislature: How it Views its Roles in Indonesia s Democracy and Foreign Policy

Legal Environment for Political Parties in Modern Russia

MODELING THE EFFECT OF EXECUTIVE-LEGISLATIVE RELATIONS ON DEMOCRATIC STABILITY. Terry D. Clark, Creighton University. and

CHAPTER 2: MAJORITARIAN OR PLURALIST DEMOCRACY

SELF DETERMINATION IN INTERNATIONAL LAW

Where does Confucian Virtuous Leadership Stand? A Critique of Daniel Bell s Beyond Liberal Democracy

Decentralisation Policy in Indonesia After 2001

INDONESIAN DEMOCRACY: TRANSITION TO CONSOLIDATION. R. William Liddle The Ohio State University Saiful Mujani Lembaga Survei Indonesia

THE THEORETICAL BASICS OF THE POST-SOVIET MEDIA

4 INTRODUCTION Argentina, for example, democratization was connected to the growth of a human rights movement that insisted on democratic politics and

Partai Amanat Nasional (National Mandate Party) is a political party that fights for popular sovereignty, democracy, progress, and social justice.

*AP Government and Politics: US and Comparative (#3400)

The State of Democratic Governance in Asia. The State of Indonesia Democratic Governance: A Popular Assessment

Bridging research and policy in international development: an analytical and practical framework

Guidelines for Comprehensive Exams in Comparative Politics Department of Political Science The Pennsylvania State University December 2005

Political Parties. The drama and pageantry of national political conventions are important elements of presidential election

Behavior Political Engagement of Legislators

Working Paper Series: No. 38

POLI 5140 Politics & Religion 3 cr.

SS: Social Sciences. SS 131 General Psychology 3 credits; 3 lecture hours

THE CASE FOR PROMOTING DEMOCRACY THROUGH EXPORT CONTROL

Pancasila Democracy and the Play of the Good

Measuring Presidential Power in Post-Communist Countries: Rectification of Mistakes 1

PSOC002 Democracy Term 1, Prof. Riccardo Pelizzo Raffles 3-19 Tel

Kim, Dwight H. Perkins, and Jung-ho. Citation The Developing Economies 35.1 (1997

COMPARATIVE DEMOCRATIZATION AND CIVIL SOCIETY IN THE DEVELOPING WORLD

Ordering Power: Contentious Politics and Authoritarian Leviathans in Southeast Asia

Course Title: Advanced Placement American Government and Politics

Indonesian Reformasi as Reflected in Law

Unit 1 Introduction to Comparative Politics Test Multiple Choice 2 pts each

Political Beliefs and Behaviors

The Evolving Anti-terrorist Coalition in Southeast Asia: The View from Washington

17.50: Introduction to Comparative Politics Thursday and Friday, 9:30 a.m. to 11:00 a.m. Building 2, Room 142

Comparing political culture

This document is downloaded from DR-NTU, Nanyang Technological University Library, Singapore.

Ukrainian Teeter-Totter VICES AND VIRTUES OF A NEOPATRIMONIAL DEMOCRACY

Journal of Current Southeast Asian Affairs

lections are commonly viewed as the central component of representative democracy. Yet democratic representation entails a far more complex process

PUBLISHER AIPA SECRETARIAT. 1st Edition October nd Edition October rd Edition October th Edition October 2015

Why hasn t decentralisation done more to improve the quality of life for Indonesian villagers?

By the grace of God Almighty and urged by the lofty aspiration to exist as a free nation,

The 1945 Constitution of the Republic of Indonesia

The Role of the Judiciary and the Rule of Law in Democratization: The Case of Turkey and the Chances of Democratic Consolidation

Gender quotas in Slovenia: A short analysis of failures and hopes

EU citizenship: investigate, understand, act. Five workshop modules for advanced level secondary school and tertiary / higher education students

Viktória Babicová 1. mail:

The Sudan Consortium African and International Civil Society Action for Sudan. Sudan Public Opinion Poll Khartoum State

Political Science: An Introduction, 11e

Power: A Radical View by Steven Lukes

Fall 2012 Political Institutions and International Political Economy: China and Beyond

Philips Vermonte CSIS December The 2014 Election and Democracy in Indonesia

Democratic Support among Youth in Some East Asian Countries

American Government. Week. Folders

Guarding Constitution of Indonesia through the Court. Wasis Susetio Universitas Indonusa Esa Unggul Indonesia

THE ROLE OF THINK TANKS IN AFFECTING PEOPLE'S BEHAVIOURS

Do you think you are a Democrat, Republican or Independent? Conservative, Moderate, or Liberal? Why do you think this?

Presidentialized Semi-Presidentialism in Taiwan: View of Party Politics and Institutional Norms. Yu-Chung Shen 1

GOVT-452: Third World Politics Professor Daniel Brumberg

Genuine Electoral Democracy and Human Rights. S. Wang (CityU)

Transcription:

Title Consensus and democracy in Indonesi revisited Author(s) Kawamura, Koichi Citation IDE Discussion Paper. No. 308. 2011 Issue Date 2011-09 URL http://hdl.handle.net/2344/1091 Rights < アジア経済研究所学術研究リポジトリ ARRIDE> http://ir.ide.go.jp/

INSTITUTE OF DEVELOPING ECONOMIES IDE Discussion Papers are preliminary materials circulated to stimulate discussions and critical comments IDE DISCUSSION PAPER No. 308 Consensus and Democracy in Indonesia: Musyawarah-Mufakat Revisited Koichi KAWAMURA* September 2011 Abstract This paper analyzes customary practices of consensus decision making, called musyawarah mufakat, as a basis of democratic stability in Indonesia. Musyawarah and mufakat (deliberation and consensus) are a traditional decision making rule in Indonesia which has often been observed in village meetings. This paper argues that this traditional decision making rule is still employed even in a modernized and democratized Indonesia, not only at rural assemblies but in the national parliament as well. Furthermore, this consensus way of decision making provides an institutional basis for democratic stability by giving every parliamentary player, whether big or small, an equal opportunity to express his/her interests. On the other hand, this system of musyawarah mufakat decreases political efficiency in the sense that it takes a long time to deliberate drafted laws in the parliament. Keywords: Indonesia, democracy, political culture, legislature * Associate Senior Research Fellow, Southeast Asian Studies Group I, Area Studies Center, IDE (kawamura@ide.go.jp)

The Institute of Developing Economies (IDE) is a semigovernmental, nonpartisan, nonprofit research institute, founded in 1958. The Institute merged with the Japan External Trade Organization (JETRO) on July 1, 1998. The Institute conducts basic and comprehensive studies on economic and related affairs in all developing countries and regions, including Asia, the Middle East, Africa, Latin America, Oceania, and Eastern Europe. The views expressed in this publication are those of the author(s). Publication does not imply endorsement by the Institute of Developing Economies of any of the views expressed within. INSTITUTE OF DEVELOPING ECONOMIES (IDE), JETRO 3-2-2, WAKABA, MIHAMA-KU, CHIBA-SHI CHIBA 261-8545, JAPAN 2011 by Institute of Developing Economies, JETRO No part of this publication may be reproduced without the prior permission of the IDE-JETRO.

Consensus and Democracy in Indonesia: Musyawarah-Mufakat Revisited Koichi Kawamura Institute of Developing Economies Introduction Why do some democracies succeed and others fail? This question has long been debated among scholars as well as government and societal practitioners. Among comparative political scientists studying democracy, there have emerged three distinctive approaches of explaining democratic performance (Putnam 1993, 9-12). The first approach emphasizes institutional design. This tradition has its roots in formal legal studies such as John Stuart Mill s Considerations on Representative Government. This school of approach has continued to dominate the analysis of democratic performance right into the twenty-first century and has developed into the most recent version of the rational choice institutionalism. They argue that institutions matter in that institutions frame the incentives, strategies, and behaviors of actors in a political system. Appropriately established constitutions hinder all the actors from diverting from democratic decision making so that democratic stability is achieved. The second approach emphasizes socioeconomic factors. Political This is a revised version of a paper presented at the Workshop on Indonesia and Asian Democratic Transition and Reform Experiences, the Institute for Peace and Democracy, Bali, Indonesia, 22-25 February 2010. 1

sociologists such as Aristotle, Robert A. Dahl, Syemour Martin Lipset, and Barrington Moore have stressed various aspects of modernization (e.g., wealth, education, social class) in their discussions of the conditions underlying stable democracy. They argue that economic development changes social balances between classes or creates a new social class (the bourgeois or middle class). Those structural changes, in effect, lead to democratization, and without modernization a country cannot attain a stable and effective democracy. The third approach emphasizes sociocultural factors in explaining the performance of democratic institutions. This tradition goes back to Plato, later Alexis de Tocqueville, and more recently, Gabriel Almond and Sidney Verba. For example, Almond and Verba argued that citizens in stable democracies are characterized by a particular set of widely shared attitudes and values which they called the "civic culture." Citizens in stable democracies possess a relatively common set of understandings about the appropriate boundaries of government, the sanctity of political rights, and the duties of citizens to preserve them: If there is no consensus within society, there can be little potentiality for the peaceful resolution of political differences that is associated with the democratic process (Almond and Verba 1963, 358). Robert A. Putnam (1993), in his Making Democracy Work, also argues that democratic stability depends on a specific form of social organization and citizen values which he calls civic traditions. The literature on democratic consolidation also recognizes the importance of citizen values, norms, and traditions. For example, Juan J. Linz and Alfred Stepan argue that democracy, to be consolidated, has to be routinized and deeply internalized in social, institutional, and even psychological life (Linz and Stepan 1996, 5). 2

Indonesian scholars have become quite familiar with the cultural approaches in studying the politics and society of this country. The most obvious exemplar is the conceptualization of aliran politics by Clifford Geertz (1973) which is still influential in analyzing electoral and party politics in Indonesia. Besides, Indonesianists often discuss the political and societal effects of gotong royong (mutual help), kekeluargaan (familism), and musyawarah-mufakat (deliberation-and-consensus) to name a few. However, after Indonesia was democratized, the 1945 Constitution was totally amended to become a wholly new constitution; universal human rights were introduced, and free competition among political forces is guaranteed in electoral, legislative, and governmental arenas. Meanwhile studying the political culture of Indonesia is in decline. Probably since Western democratic systems and practices have been fully accepted in Indonesia of the 21st century, traditional cultures are no longer attracting the attention of Indonesian scholars. In this paper I would like to bring political culture back into the political analysis of Indonesia s democracy. I focus particularly on the traditional decision-making rule of musyawarah-mufakat, and I will present a hypothesis that customary practices of musyawarah-mufakat, which can still be observed in various political and social settings from the village community to the national legislature, have contributed to the successful democratic consolidation of Indonesia. I. Musyawarah-Mufakat in Indonesian Politics For many of the peoples of Indonesia as well as Indonesian scholars, 3

unanimous consent is an indigenous decision-making rule (Logsdon 1978, 96). Soetardjo (1953, 102) argues, according to original Indonesian law, every decision, whether accepted or rejected, has to be taken with unanimous consent. On the other hand, he dismisses a majority vote system like that employed in Western democracies since it is not familiar to the Indonesian people (Soetardjo 1953, 102). According to Koentjaraningrat, musyawarah and mufakat grew out of a cooperative spirit that underlies the village sense of community in most Indonesian cultures. An important manifestation of the gotong-royong ethos in most Indonesian village communities is the institution of musyawarah. The concept involves the processes that develop general agreement and consensus in village assemblies, which emerge as the unanimous decision or mufakat. This unanimous decision can be reached by a process in which the majority and minorities approach each other by making the necessary readjustments in their respective viewpoints, or by an integration of the contrasting standpoints into a new conceptual synthesis. Musyawarah and mufakat thus exclude the possibility that the majority will impose its views on the minorities (Koentjaraningrat 1967, 397). However, outsiders cannot necessarily observe a consensus-building process in a village meeting, therefore it often appears as if it were the head of the village who determines everything in an authoritarian manner, while all other members of the village community act only to approve his decisions (as yes-men) (Koentjaraningrat 2009, 44, fn. 2). In reality, intensive lobbying is conducted behind the scenes to find an agreeable point between those who proposed and 4

opposed. Therefore, the official meeting to vote for a final decision is only ceremonial after all the behind-the-scene maneuvers were completed. Koentjaraningrat considers the reason why such a system of conducting meetings is employed in rural communities lies in a corresponding element in the attitudes of the Javanese, which is to avoid at all costs controversy in public (Koentjaraningrat 2009, 44, fn. 2). While musyawarah-mufakat is considered as growing out of rural tradition, it has also been incorporated into the national political system. Musyawarah is one of the five pillars of the Five State Principles, Pancasila, declaring that democracy guided by the inner wisdom of deliberations (Permusyawaratan) amongst representatives. Article 2 of the 1945 Constitution states that all decisions of the People s Consultative Assembly (MPR) shall be taken by a majority vote, but when Soekarno established his Guided Democracy, the return to the 1945 Constitution included adoption of unanimous consent (mufakat) as the decision-making rule in the Parliament. Soeharto also recognized the importance of the musyawarah-mufakat rule to achieve political stability under his authoritarian regime. For example, the 1978 People s Consultative Assembly Decision on Pancasila Ethics Education (Ketetapan Majelis Permusyawaratan Rakyat Republik Indonesia Nomor II/MPR/1978 tentang Pedoman Penghayatan dan Pengamalan Pancasila [Ekaprasetia Pancakarsa]) stipulates that decisions should be made only after deliberation (musyawarah) has reached unanimous consent (mufakat) and that the Indonesian nation have to respect decisions made through musyawarah and have the responsibility to accept or implement those decisions. 5

II. Musyawarah-Mufakat in Democratized Indonesia Considering that the decision-making rule of musyawarah-mufakat was used for repressive purposes by both Soekarno s and Soeharto s authoritarian governments, there was no forceful adoption of the rule after democratization in 1998. For example, the 1999 Law on Local Government (Undang-undang Nomor 22 Tahun 1999 tentang Pemerintahan Daerah) did not stipulate usage of the musyawarah-mufakat rule, even allowing village assemblies to adopt majority decision making. In reality, however, village assemblies after democratization and decentralization have adopted both majority rule and musyawarah-mufakat rule in a flexible way. Kosuke Mizuno has found that there are still strong tendencies to emphasize the musyawarah-mufakat rule in the decision-making process of village assemblies while majority voting is also observed especially in the reactivated village development councils (Mizuno 2006). The decision-making rule of unanimous consent through deliberation is still used, even after democratization, in the legislative process in the national parliament (Dewan Perwakilan Rakyat: DPR). The Rules of Procedure of the Parliament (Peraturan Tata Tertib DPR RI) call upon factions to endeavor to deliberate (musyawarah) as much as possible to achieve unanimous consent (mufakat). It is supposedly not until the failure to achieve unanimous consent that the rule of decision making by majority is allowed to be used. Many of the legislators hold to the norm that the parliament should avoid deciding by vote (Ziegenhain 2008, 161-163). In effect, there is only a small amount of legislation that is passed by majority vote. Even in cases where a specific bill in a 6

preliminary session is decided on by majority vote, such voting is hardly ever done at the committee stage. The amended 1945 Constitution also stipulates that each bill shall be discussed by the parliament and the president until reaching joint approval, thus requiring consensus between the legislators and the president. III. Musyawarah-Mufakat and Democratic Stability Is musyawarah-mufakat an outdated decision-making rule for democratized Indonesia? Is it inappropriate under democracy since it suppresses the raising of opposing opinions? Will it disappear as democracy is consolidated in Indonesia? I will argue here that musyawarah-mufakat can function to consolidate Indonesia s democracy in the way that it functions to integrate plural societies. Under the Soeharto regime musyawarah-mufakat was used to prevent the expression of opposing opinions in the public sphere. Musyawarah-mufakat was achieved only among political or community elites, or it was achieved through the show of force whether implicit or explicit. This could happen since, as Koentjaraningrat accurately recognized, musyawarah and mufakat imply the existence of personalities who, by virtue of their leadership, are able to bring together the contrasting viewpoints or who have enough imagination to arrive at a synthesis integrating the contrasting viewpoints into a new conception (Koentjaraningrat 1967, 397). Under the vertical interactions of authoritarianism, it only functioned to force the people to obey government instructions. However, with democratization and the guarantee of political rights, musyawarah-mufakat cannot be forced from above any more. I would rather argue 7

that it provides an institutional basis for democratic stability. In democratic settings, musyawarah-mufakat can be conceptualized as giving all the players concerned a veto power. In particular, it provides both majorities and minorities with an equal veto power so that minorities can prevent majorities from violating the former s rights and interests unilaterally. When minorities face a situation where their critical rights and interests are at risk, they will even resort to extra-constitutional or undemocratic actions such as a coup d etat in order to protect their rights and interests. Creating many veto points can secure credible commitment by all the players to democracy. Even if the one side transgresses the other s rights and interests unilaterally, the latter can veto such action, and the status quo is restored. As long as any single veto player does not agree to change, the status quo is always chosen. Thus, many veto players affect the stability of policies, the government, and the political regime. While veto points create political stability, they also affect policy efficiency. The more veto players there are, the more difficult it is to attain agreement among the actors, and the less efficient the policy response to changing environment is. In fact, policy inefficiency can be observed in Indonesian legislation. The author has found that Indonesia s parliament has not been so productive in legislation since democratization despite of the great need to enact various laws in order to adjust the legal system to the new democratic environment (Kawamura forthcoming). Table 1 shows the number of laws and other regulations enacted under post-democratization governments. We have to be careful when comparing the number of enacted laws and regulations since there were differences in terms of 8

governments and political institutions during the four-year period of constitutional amendments between 1999 and 2002, but the most productive government in enacting laws after democratization was that of President Habibie, which enacted 66 laws during his presidential term of one year and five months, or 45 laws per year. Most of the 66 laws were proposed by the government. By contrast, the government that was least productive in enacting laws was Wahid s. Only 51 laws were established during his term of one year and nine months, or 28 laws per year. Finally, the number of enacted laws under the Megawati government was 122, or 36 per year, while the number of enacted laws under the first Yudhoyono government (until the end of January 2009) was 153, or 34 per year. When we look at the number of laws proposed by these two governments, it further decreases to 29 laws per year for Megawati and 15 laws per year for Yudhoyono. These numbers show quantitatively that the government and the parliament have failed to pass necessary laws. Table 1. Number of Established Laws Habibie Wahid Megawati 1st Yudhoyono Law 66 51 122 153 Proposed by Government 61 48 94 67 Initiated by MPs 5 3 28 86 The Number of Established Laws per Year 45.4 28.3 36.7 34.8 Laws Proposed by Government per Year 43.1 27.3 29.0 15.6 Laws Proposed by Government per Year except for Laws on New Regional Government 28.9 14.2 17.9 15.6 Government Regulation in lieu of Law (Perpu) 3 3 4 12 Government Regulation (PP) 118 219 211 321 Presidential Regulation --- --- --- 384 Presidential Decision (Kepres) 255 318 350 100 Presidential Instruction (Inpres) 31 17 21 36 Source : Kawamura (Forthcoming). Note : The data refer to the first Yudhoyono government as of the end of January 2009. 9

Legislative inefficiency can also be observed when we analyze deliberation periods, which refers not to the total number of days spent deliberating the bill, but to the period from the day that the bill was presented to parliament to the day of its ratification by the president, enabling the bill to be promulgated as a law. Table 2 shows the average periods of deliberation under the Megawati and Yudhoyono governments. Under the Yudhoyono government, it took over a year on average to enact a law. The deliberation periods for the laws proposed by the government were a little shorter than for those proposed by the legislature, but even so, it took almost a year to turn these government-proposed bills into legislation. It should be noted in particular that it took on average over 600 days to deliberate economic laws. This indicates that, although the most pressing issues before the Yudhoyono government were economic growth, the creation of employment opportunities, and the eradication of poverty, Yudhoyono could not effect a speedy passage of bills even on legislative procedures related to his own policy requirements. While long periods of deliberation and a small number of approved bills were caused by the weak legislative power of the president, his weak partisan power, and the fragility of coalitions (Kawamura forthcoming), the musyawarah-mufakat principle embodied in the legislative decision-making process worsened delays in legislation. In other words, Indonesia has achieved democratic stability at the sacrifice of political efficiency. 10

Table 2. Periods of Deliberation Megawati 1st Yudhoyono Number of Laws (N) Period (days) Number of Laws (N) Period (days) Average period of Deliberation 122 66 250.0 153 141 397.7 Laws Proposed by Government 94 49 166.6 67 56 355.3 Politics & Justice 17 8 392.5 7 7 435.0 Local Autonomy 1 0 n/a 3 3 74.5 Economy 23 4 557.5 21 18 606.5 Society & Religion 1 0 n/a 6 5 95.0 Budget 8 0 n/a 9 8 86.9 Settlement 4 0 n/a 4 4 473.0 New Regional Government 36 35 74.4 0 --- --- Ratification 4 2 95.5 17 11 137.5 Perpu 4 1 94.0 12 7 110.4 Laws Initiated by MPs 28 17 490.4 86 85 419.4 Politics & Justice 9 9 610.0 10 10 744.4 Local Autonomy 4 2 375.5 2 2 429.5 Economy 7 1 759.0 6 6 622.8 Society 3 1 737.0 5 5 453.8 Religion 0 --- --- 3 2 1057.0 New Regional Government 5 4 149.8 60 60 321.0 Source : Kawamura (Forthcoming). Note : The data refer to the first Yudhoyono government as of the end of January 2009. Conclusion The experience of Indonesia s successful democratization poses many interesting questions for scholars as well as government officials, and the causes for this success story have yet to be fully analyzed theoretically or comparatively. Indonesian scholars tend to speak and write in their own language which cannot be easily understood by scholars studying other countries. We have to change our academic culture to share Indonesia s experience with scholars from all over 11

the world, something that is particularly necessary in the studies of political culture. References Almond, Gabriel and Sidney Verba. 1989. The Civic Culture: Political Attitudes and Democracy in Five Nations. Newbury Park, CA: Sage Publications. Geertz, Clifford. 1973. The Interpretation of Cultures. New York: Basic Books. Kawamura, Koichi. Forthcoming. President Restrained: Effects of Parliamentary Rule and Coalition Government on Indonesia's Presidentialism, in Yuko Kasuya, ed., Presidents, Assemblies, and Policy Making in Asia. Palgrave. Koentjaraningrat. 2009. Gotong Rojong: Some Social-anthropological Observations on Practices in Two Villages of Central Java. Singapore: Equinox Publishing; 2009 (originally published by Cornell Southeast Asia Program, Cornell University, 1961). Koentjaraningrat, ed. 1967. Villages in Indonesia. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. Linz, Juan J. and Alfred Stepan. 1996. Problems of Democratic Transition and Consolidation: Southern Europe, South America, and Post-Communist Europe. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University Press. Logsdon, Martha G. 1978. Traditional Decision Making in Urban Neighborhoods, Indonesia, Vol. 26: 95-110. Mizuno, Kosuke. 2006 Gogi-Zen in Icchi to Tasuuketsu Genri no aidade [Between Deliberation-Unanimous Consent and Majoritarian Rule: Village Conference and Village Assembly] in Takashi Sugishima and Kiyoshi Nakamura, eds., Gendai Indonesia no Chiho Syakai [Local Society in Modern Indonesia: A Micrology Approach], Tokyo: NTT Publishing. Putnam, Robert. 1993. Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press. Soetardjo Kartohadikoesoemo. 1953. Desa. Jogjakarta. Ziegenhain, Patrick. 2008. The Indonesian Parliament and Democratization. Singapore: Institute of Southeast Asian Studies. 12