Cultural distance as a determinant. immigrants counter the effect of cultural differences? Applied Economics Letters, 2007,??, 1 6

Similar documents
Cambridge International Examinations Cambridge International Advanced Subsidiary and Advanced Level

VISA POLICY OF THE REPUBLIC OF KAZAKHSTAN

APPENDIX 1: MEASURES OF CAPITALISM AND POLITICAL FREEDOM

Translation from Norwegian

GLOBAL RISKS OF CONCERN TO BUSINESS WEF EXECUTIVE OPINION SURVEY RESULTS SEPTEMBER 2017

PISA 2015 in Hong Kong Result Release Figures and Appendices Accompanying Press Release

The National Police Immigration Service (NPIS) forcibly returned 412 persons in December 2017, and 166 of these were convicted offenders.

2018 Social Progress Index

The National Police Immigration Service (NPIS) returned 444 persons in August 2018, and 154 of these were convicted offenders.

WORLDWIDE DISTRIBUTION OF PRIVATE FINANCIAL ASSETS

Delays in the registration process may mean that the real figure is higher.

Global Variations in Growth Ambitions

Return of convicted offenders

Trends in international higher education

The National Police Immigration Service (NPIS) forcibly returned 375 persons in March 2018, and 136 of these were convicted offenders.

The NPIS is responsible for forcibly returning those who are not entitled to stay in Norway.

The Multidimensional Financial Inclusion MIFI 1

Contracting Parties to the Ramsar Convention

BULGARIAN TRADE WITH EU IN JANUARY 2017 (PRELIMINARY DATA)

BULGARIAN TRADE WITH EU IN THE PERIOD JANUARY - MARCH 2016 (PRELIMINARY DATA)

QGIS.org - Donations and Sponsorship Analysis 2016

MIGRATION IN SPAIN. "Facebook or face to face? A multicultural exploration of the positive and negative impacts of

SEVERANCE PAY POLICIES AROUND THE WORLD

Dashboard. Jun 1, May 30, 2011 Comparing to: Site. 79,209 Visits % Bounce Rate. 231,275 Pageviews. 00:03:20 Avg.

The Conference Board Total Economy Database Summary Tables November 2016

Income and Population Growth

Contributions to UNHCR For Budget Year 2014 As at 31 December 2014

New York County Lawyers Association Continuing Legal Education Institute 14 Vesey Street, New York, N.Y (212)

World Refugee Survey, 2001

Figure 2: Range of scores, Global Gender Gap Index and subindexes, 2016

SCALE OF ASSESSMENT OF MEMBERS' CONTRIBUTIONS FOR 1994

92 El Salvador El Salvador El Salvador El Salvador El Salvador Nicaragua Nicaragua Nicaragua 1

Does Cultural Distance Hinder Trade in Goods? A Comparative Study of Nine OECD Member Nations

1994 No DESIGNS

HUMAN RESOURCES IN R&D

1994 No PATENTS

Collective Intelligence Daudi Were, Project

Shaping the Future of Transport

South Africa - A publisher s perspective. STM/PASA conference 11 June, 2012, Cape Town Mayur Amin, SVP Research & Academic Relations

VACATION AND OTHER LEAVE POLICIES AROUND THE WORLD

Analyzing the Location of the Romanian Foreign Ministry in the Social Network of Foreign Ministries

Mapping physical therapy research

Country pairings for the second cycle of the Mechanism for the Review of Implementation of the United Nations Convention against Corruption

Consumer Barometer Study 2017

Copyright Act - Subsidiary Legislation CHAPTER 311 COPYRIGHT ACT. SUBSIDIARY LEGlSLA non. List o/subsidiary Legislation

Education Quality and Economic Development

2016 Europe Travel Trends Report

Human Resources in R&D

On the Future of Criminal Offender DNA Databases

PISA 2009 in Hong Kong Result Release Figures and tables accompanying press release article

LIST OF CHINESE EMBASSIES OVERSEAS Extracted from Ministry of Foreign Affairs of the People s Republic of China *

A Partial Solution. To the Fundamental Problem of Causal Inference

Regional Scores. African countries Press Freedom Ratings 2001

Countries for which a visa is required to enter Colombia

Supplementary Material

BULGARIAN TRADE WITH EU IN THE PERIOD JANUARY - FEBRUARY 2017 (PRELIMINARY DATA)

2017 Social Progress Index

SKILLS, MOBILITY, AND GROWTH

India, Bangladesh, Bhutan, Nepal and Sri Lanka: Korea (for vaccine product only):

UNHCR, United Nations High Commissioner for Refugees

Migration and Integration

Diplomatic Conference to Conclude a Treaty to Facilitate Access to Published Works by Visually Impaired Persons and Persons with Print Disabilities

SEPTEMBER TRADE UPDATE ASIA TAKES THE LEAD

The Extraordinary Extent of Cultural Consumption in Iceland

Global Prevalence of Adult Overweight & Obesity by Region

BULGARIAN TRADE WITH EU IN THE PERIOD JANUARY - JUNE 2014 (PRELIMINARY DATA)

ASYLUM IN THE EU Source: Eurostat 4/6/2013, unless otherwise indicated ASYLUM APPLICATIONS IN THE EU27

Mechanism for the Review of Implementation of the United Nations Convention against Corruption: country pairings for the second review cycle

Networks and Innovation: Accounting for Structural and Institutional Sources of Recombination in Brokerage Triads

Charting Cambodia s Economy, 1H 2017

REPORT OF THE FOURTH SPECIAL SESSION OF THE CONFERENCE OF THE STATES PARTIES

geography Bingo Instructions

UNITED NATIONS FINANCIAL PRESENTATION. UN Cash Position. 18 May 2007 (brought forward) Alicia Barcena Under Secretary-General for Management

Emerging Asian economies lead Global Pay Gap rankings

AUSTRALIA S REFUGEE RESPONSE NOT THE MOST GENEROUS BUT IN TOP 25

Research Program on Access to Finance

A GLOBAL PERSPECTIVE ON RESEARCH AND DEVELOPMENT

REINVENTION WITH INTEGRITY

Asia Pacific (19) EMEA (89) Americas (31) Nov

Table A.1. Jointly Democratic, Contiguous Dyads (for entire time period noted) Time Period State A State B Border First Joint Which Comes First?

The Madrid System. Overview and Trends. Mexico March 23-24, David Muls Senior Director Madrid Registry

KINGDOM OF CAMBODIA NATION RELIGION KING 3 TOURISM STATISTICS REPORT. September 2010

Sex ratio at birth (converted to female-over-male ratio) Ratio: female healthy life expectancy over male value

Global Economic Trends in the Coming Decades 簡錦漢. Kamhon Kan 中研院經濟所. Academia Sinica /18

OECD Strategic Education Governance A perspective for Scotland. Claire Shewbridge 25 October 2017 Edinburgh

UNDER EMBARGO UNTIL 9 APRIL 2018, 15:00 HOURS PARIS TIME

TAKING HAPPINESS SERIOUSLY

Good Sources of International News on the Internet are: ABC News-

Equity and Excellence in Education from International Perspectives

The IMAGE Project - Comparing Internal Migration Around the GlobE: Data, Methods, Variations and Explanations

List of countries whose citizens are exempted from the visa requirement

IR 1 Visitors

1. Why do third-country audit entities have to register with authorities in Member States?

Mechanism for the Review of Implementation of the United Nations Convention against Corruption: country pairings for the second review cycle

The Anti-Counterfeiting Network. Ronald Brohm Managing Director

1 THICK WHITE SENTRA; SIDES AND FACE PAINTED TO MATCH WALL PAINT: GRAPHICS DIRECT PRINTED TO SURFACE; CLEAT MOUNT TO WALL CRITICAL INSTALL POINT

Asylum Levels and Trends in Industrialized Countries. First Quarter, 2005

The 2012 Global Entrepreneurship and Development Index (GEDI) Country Rankings Excerpt: DENMARK

LIST OF CONTRACTING STATES AND OTHER SIGNATORIES OF THE CONVENTION (as of January 11, 2018)

World Peace Index Its Significance and Contribution to the Scientific Study of World Peace

Transcription:

Applied Economics Letters, 2007,??, 1 6 Cultural distance as a determinant 5 of bilateral trade flows: do immigrants counter the effect of cultural differences? Bedassa Tadesse a, * and Roger White b a Department of Economics, University of Minnesota Duluth, 174 SBE, 10 Duluth, 55812, United States b Department of Economics, Franklin and Marshall College, Lancaster, United States We introduce cultural distance as a measure of the degree to which shared 15 norms and values in one country differ from those in another country, and employ a modified gravity specification to examine whether such cultural differences affect the volume of trade flows. Employing data for US statelevel exports to the 75 trading partners for which measures of cultural distance can be constructed, we find that greater cultural differences 20 between the United States and a trading partner reduces state-level exports to that country. This result holds for aggregate exports, cultural and noncultural products exports as well, but with significantly different magnitudes. Immigrants are found to exert a pro-export effect that partially offsets the trade-inhibiting effects of cultural distance. 25 I. Introduction Despite a voluminous literature on the immigranttrade relationship, the effects that cultural differences between immigrants home and host countries may have on trade flows and the extent to which 30 immigrants may counter these effects have received little attention. Cultural difference is defined as the degree to which shared norms and values differ from one country to another (Hofstede, 2001). Pronounced cultural differences may make it difficult to under- 35 stand, anticipate and predict the behavior of others (Elsass and Vieiga, 1994), and people from dissimilar cultures may have considerably different perceptions of the same situation or series of events (Doz and Hamel, 1998). As such, cultural differences can *Corresponding author. E-mail: btadesse@d.umn.edu complicate interactions, hinder the development of rapport and trust and, thus, carry the potential to increase transaction costs and reduce the likelihood that international trade will occur. In examining the influence of cultural differences, we use data for the year 2000 that represents US state-level exports to 75 countries for which cultural distances can be constructed. We extend the immigrant-trade link literature by relating cultural distance, immigration and trade flows for aggregate state-level exports and, separately, for two broad product classifications: cultural and noncultural products. Prior research documents the existence of an immigrant-trade link and reasons that immigrants influence trade via two direct channels: (i) their preferences for home country goods when desired 40 45 50 55 Applied Economics Letters ISSN 1350 4851 print/issn 1466 4291 online ß 2007 Taylor & Francis 1 http://www.tandf.co.uk/journals DOI: 10.1080/13504850701719983

2 B. Tadesse and R. White products or acceptable substitutes are not available in their host countries (a transplanted home bias effect), and (ii) their connections to business or social networks and/or knowledge they may possess regard- 60 ing political and social obligations required to conduct business in their home countries (the exploitation of network connections). White (2007), Bandyopadhyay (2006) and Wagner et al. (2002) review the associated literature. We hypothesize that 65 immigrants also indirectly increase trade by counteracting the trade-inhibiting influence of cultural differences (distances) between their home and host countries. We contend that the initiation and conduct of transactions between individuals in different 70 countries depends, in part, on the extent to which shared norms and values differ across countries. To explore this notion, we estimate cultural distances between the United States and each trading partner in our data set based on two dimensions of culture: 75 Traditional vs. Secular-Rational authority (TSR) and Survival vs. Self-Expression values (SSE). Using mean values for the TSR and SSE dimensions, the cultural distance between each home country j and the United States (country i) is calculated as CD ¼ qffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi 80 2þ 2 TSR j TSR i SSEj SSE i. While the TSR dimension reflects a contrast between societies in which deference to the authority of a God, the nation or to the family is considered important or an expectation (Traditional authority) and societies in 85 which individualism and self-expression are stressed (Secular-Rational authority), the SSE dimension reflects differences between societies that emphasize hard work and self-denial (Survival values) and those that place greater emphasis on quality of life issues, 90 such as women s emancipation and equal status for racial and sexual minorities (Self-Expression values). II. Theoretical Framework, Empirical Model and Data Following the lead of prior studies, we employ the 95 gravity model of trade and derive our econometric specification by defining M, country j s imports from state i, as a function of income, geodesic distance and several trade-inhibiting (transaction costs) and tradefacilitating factors. In its basic form, the gravity 100 model posits that country j s imports from state iðm Þ increase with the trading partners combined economic mass, given as the product of the incomes of the exporting state (Y i ) and of the importing country (Y j ), and decrease as geodesic distance (GD ), 105 a proxy for transportation costs, increases. We also include a vector of variables, represented by the expression expðx 1 X 2Þ, that affects the likelihood of trade being initiated and/or an increase in the volume of transactions already taking place, where X 1 a vector of the ratio ðcd =IM Þ of cultural distance between the United States and country j and the stock of immigrants from country j living in state i, and X 2 is all other trade inhibiting/ facilitating factors described in the modified gravity model of Head and Ries (1998). Thus our theoretical model can be described as: M ¼ Y 1 i Y 2 j GD exp 3 CD! X 2 IM ð1þ Equation 1 postulates positive and negative effects on trade for the stock of immigrants and cultural distance, respectively. It also indicates that the extent to which cultural distance affects trade may be influenced by the stock of immigrants from country j living in state i. In addition, it predicts strictly positive realizations of imports. Since trade data often contain numerous cases of zero imports and exports, following Eaton and Tamura (1994) and Head and Ries (1998), we modify Equation 1 to obtain a specification that allows for zero realization of trade values. M ¼ Y 1 i Y 2 j CD! GD exp 3 IM X 2 þ " ð2þ The subscript k is the constant of proportionality, " is an assumed identically and independently distributed error term, and is the fixed amount of trade that is subtracted from the level predicted by Equation 1. When the latent import value is negative, observed imports will be zero. Thus, the observed data on country j s import from state i can be described as: M ¼ max½m ;0Š. Substituting this identity, rearranging the resulting expression, expanding the vector X 2, and taking natural logarithms where appropriate, results in our estimation equation. ln M þ ¼ þ 1 ln Y i þ 2 ln Y j 3 ln GD 1 ln CD þ 2 ln IM þ 3 ln CD ln IM þ 1 ln Y i þ 2 ln Y j POP i POP j þ 3 ln OPEN j þ 4 ln EXRATE þ 5 FTA þ 6 LLOCK j þ 7 ENGLISH j þ " ð3þ 110 115 120 125 130 135 140

Cultural distance, immigrants and trade 3 Table 1. Descriptive statistics Dependent variables Mean (SD) Aggregate exports 148 407 678 (1 008 056 826) Non-cultural products exports 144 788 823 (990 537 894) Cultural products exports 3 618 855 (29 441 546) Geodesic distance (in miles) 8886.02 (3019.398) Cultural distance 1.3477 (0.5112) Stock of immigrant population 6300.71 (74 743.11) Gross domestic product (GDP) 271 189 386 173 (632 845 671 676) GDP per capita 13 028.41 (11 154.74) State gross domestic product (GSP) 191 158 901 961 (227 921 025 648) GSP per capita 34 387.96 (11 356.62) ln exchange rate 0.113 (0.1554) Open 0.8445 (0.4801) English 0.3733 (0.4838) FTA 0.04 (0.196) Llock 0.20v (0.4001) N 3825v (51 states 75 home countries) Following Eaton and Tamura (1994), we estimate 145 our model as a tobit specification where aggregate exports and exports of cultural and noncultural products, measured at the state-level, are interchanged as dependent variables. Export data are from the World Trade Atlas (GTI, 2006), and 150 our classification of exports into cultural and noncultural products follows UNESCO (2005). State-level immigrant population data are from the 2000 decennial census (US Census, 2006a). Our measure of cultural distance is constructed using 155 World Values Survey and European Values Survey data (Inglehart et al., 2004). Home country income and population data are from the World Bank (2006), while Gross State Product (GSP) data are from the US Bureau of Economic Analysis (2006). GSP per 160 capita is constructed as GSP divided by state population (US Census, 2006b). Monetary values have been normalized to constant 1995 US dollars. The remaining explanatory variables are standard in most studies that employ the gravity model. 165 OPEN j, the sum of each country s imports and exports divided by its GDP, measures a country s propensity to trade. The change in the annual US-home country exchange rate captures terms of trade effects. Expressed as foreign currency units per 170 US dollar, an increase in the variable is expected to decrease US exports. Capturing the effects of trade agreements, FTA is equal to one if country j is party to an agreement with the US during 2000. As common language has been identified as an important deter- 175 minant of trade flows (Dunlevy, 2006; Hutchinson, 2002), we include a dummy variable which is equal to one if English is commonly used in country j (CIA, 2006). Finally, to represent a potentially important geographic impediment to trade, we include a dummy variable which is equal to one if country j is landlocked. Table 1 presents descriptive statistics. III. Empirical Results Table 2 presents the marginal effects of the explanatory variables in our empirical model. In each set of results, the first model presents the basic specification where we account only for the effect of immigrants. The second model augments the basic specification by including the cultural distance variable, and the third model includes cultural distance and an interaction term between the immigrant stock and cultural distance variables. The effects of immigrants from country j residing in state i on state-level exports are given, jointly, by the coefficients on the immigrant stock variable (IM ) and the term which interacts the immigrant stock with the measure of cultural distance (CD IM ). Consistent with earlier studies, results from our basic specification indicate that immigrants exert significant pro-export effects. Given that we employ the tobit estimation technique and we have the parameter, the resulting coefficients are not true elasticities. However, as the values of relative to median state exports levels are small, we can heuristically interpret the coefficients as elasticities. Accordingly, a 1% increase in the immigrant stock from country j increases aggregate exports from that 180 185 190 195 200 205

Table 2. Estimated immigrant effect by product type Aggregate exports Cultural products exports Noncultural products exports (1.1) (1.2) (1.3) (2.1) (2.2) (2.3) (3.1) (3.2) (3.3) Immigrantst 0.0469*** (0.0093) 0.0439*** (0.0093) 0.0538*** (0.010) 0.0325*** (0.0090) 0.0256*** (0.0090) 0.0508*** (0.0099) 0.0457*** (0.0095) 0.0429*** (0.0095) 0.0530*** (0.011) Cultural Distance 0.286*** (0.076) 0.0935 (0.12) 0.494*** (0.072) 0.0781 (0.12) 0.266*** (0.077) 0.0692 (0.12) Immigrantst ln 0.0329** (0.016) 0.0901*** (0.016) 0.0335** (0.016) Cultural Distance Geodesic Distance 1.052*** (0.065) 0.999*** (0.066) 0.978*** (0.067) 0.589*** (0.060) 0.489*** (0.062) 0.432*** (0.062) 1.055*** (0.066) 1.005*** (0.067) 0.984*** (0.068) State Gross 1.335*** (0.023) 1.338*** (0.023) 1.333*** (0.023) 0.992*** (0.024) 0.998*** (0.024) 0.977*** (0.024) 1.342*** (0.024) 1.344*** (0.023) 1.340*** (0.024) Domestic Productjt State GDP 0.594*** (0.095) 0.589*** (0.095) 0.589*** (0.095) 0.361*** (0.096) 0.379*** (0.095) 0.368*** (0.094) 0.643*** (0.096) 0.638*** (0.096) 0.638*** (0.096) per capitajt Gross Domestic 0.999*** (0.025) 1.003*** (0.025) 0.998*** (0.025) 0.644*** (0.025) 0.654*** (0.025) 0.632*** (0.025) 1.003*** (0.026) 1.007*** (0.026) 1.001*** (0.026) Productjt GDP per capitajt 0.162*** (0.036) 0.0920** (0.040) 0.117*** (0.042) 0.339*** (0.036) 0.213*** (0.040) 0.279*** (0.041) 0.150*** (0.037) 0.0848** (0.041) 0.110*** (0.043) Exchange Ratet 1.588*** (0.16) 1.610*** (0.16) 1.591*** (0.16) 1.206*** (0.21) 1.328*** (0.21) 1.272*** (0.21) 1.572*** (0.16) 1.592*** (0.16) 1.573*** (0.16) Openjt 0.585*** (0.057) 0.618*** (0.058) 0.597*** (0.058) 0.216*** (0.055) 0.267*** (0.055) 0.207*** (0.056) 0.590*** (0.058) 0.621*** (0.059) 0.599*** (0.059) Englishj 0.782*** (0.051) 0.675*** (0.058) 0.685*** (0.058) 0.556*** (0.050) 0.362*** (0.057) 0.389*** (0.056) 0.781*** (0.052) 0.682*** (0.059) 0.692*** (0.059) FTA t 0.410*** (0.13) 0.306** (0.13) 0.234* (0.14) 0.523*** (0.12) 0.348*** (0.12) 0.190 (0.12) 0.411*** (0.13) 0.315** (0.14) 0.241* (0.14) Landlockedjt 0.243*** (0.062) 0.232*** (0.062) 0.236*** (0.062) 0.126* (0.066) 0.108* (0.065) 0.0904 (0.064) 0.246*** (0.063) 0.236*** (0.063) 0.239*** (0.063) Constant 40.85*** (1.32) 40.80*** (1.31) 41.03*** (1.32) 42.53*** (1.35) 42.65*** (1.35) 42.78*** (1.33) 40.51*** (1.34) 40.46*** (1.34) 40.70*** (1.34) Sigma 1.339*** (0.016) 1.336*** (0.016) 1.334*** (0.016) 1.177*** (0.017) 1.167*** (0.017) 1.155*** (0.017) 1.359*** (0.016) 1.357*** (0.016) 1.355*** (0.016) Number of 3825 3825 3825 3825 3825 3825 3825 3825 3825 Observations McFadden 0.321 0.322 0.322 0.325 0.329 0.332 0.316 0.316 0.317 Pseudo R 2 2 5.907*** 5.921*** 5.925*** 4.153*** 4.200*** 4.232*** 5.805*** 5.817*** 5.821*** (DF) (11) (12) (13) (11) (12) (13) (11) (12) (13) Note: SE in parentheses. *** p50.01, ** p50.05, * p50.1. Values of all continuous variables are in natural logarithm.

Cultural distance, immigrants and trade 5 state to the immigrants home countries, on average, by 0.047%. The corresponding influences of immi- 210 grants on state-level exports of cultural and noncultural products are estimated to be 0.033 and 0.046%, respectively. A Chow test (at p50.001) rejects the null hypothesis of the equality of coefficients across cultural and noncultural product 215 classifications. This indicates that the pro-export effect of immigrants on noncultural products is greater than the influence of immigrants on cultural products. Given that we are dealing with exports (rather than imports) and that noncultural products 220 account nearly for 97% of the average state s exports, this finding is not surprising. Supporting our hypothesis, results obtained when estimating Model 2 (where we augment the basic gravity specification with the cultural distance vari- 225 able) imply that greater cultural distance between the United States and its trading partners reduces aggregate state-level exports by 0.29%. This effect is significantly larger (0.49%) on exports of cultural products as compared to exports of non-cultural 230 products (0.27%). The pro-export effects of immigrants, however, remain robust. Turning to the results from the third specification (Model 3), in which we examine whether immigrants can help overcome the negative effects of differences in shared norms and 235 values on trade, differentiating the results with cultural distance and multiplying the coefficients with mean of immigrant stock (in log), we find that the trade inhibiting effects of cultural distance is reduced to 0.141% on aggregate exports, and 0.386 and 0.144% 240 on the exports of cultural and noncultural products, respectively implying that immigrants reduce the negative effects of cultural distance on trade flows; however, the effect is not sufficiently large to completely eliminate the negative effects of cultural 245 distance. IV. Conclusion Our results indicate that immigrants promote US state-level exports to their home countries at the aggregate level and for both cultural and noncultural 250 product classifications. Consideration of cultural distance as a determinant of trade flows reveals that greater cultural differences between immigrants host and home countries inhibit international trade. While the pro-export effect of immigrants does act to offset 255 the influence of cultural distance, it is not sufficiently large to completely counteract the export-inhibiting effects of cultural distance. References Doz, Y. L. and Hamel, G. (1998) Alliance Advantage: The Art of Creating Value through Partnering, Harvard Business School Press, Boston, MA. Eaton, J. and Tamura, A. (1994) Bilateralism and regionalism in Japanese and U.S. trade and foreign direct investment patterns, Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, 8, 478 510. Elsass, P. M. and Viega, J. F. (1994) Acculturation in acquired organizations: a force-field perspective, Human Relations, 47, 431 53. Global Trade Information Services, Inc. (GTI) (2006) World Trade Atlas, State Export Edition. Available at http:// www.gtis.com/state (accessed November 2006). Head, K. and Ries, J. (1998) Immigration and trade creation: econometric evidence from Canada, Canadian Journal of Economics, 31, 47 62. Hofstede, G. (2001) Culture s Consequences: Comparing Values, Behaviors, Institutions, and Organizations, Across Nations, 2nd edn, Sage Publications, Thousand Oaks, CA. Inglehart, R., Basanez, M., Diez-Medrano, J., Halman, L. and Lukx, R. (Eds) (2004) Human Beliefs and Values: A Cross-cultural Sourcebook based on the 1999 2002 Values Surveys, Siglo Veintiuno Editores, S.A. de C.V., Mexico City. United Nations (UNESCO) (2005) International Flows of Selected Cultural Goods and Services, 1994 2003: Defining and Capturing the Flows of Global Cultural Trade, UNESCO Institute for Statistics, UNESCO Sector for Culture, Montreal. United States Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census (2006a) Statistical Abstract of the United States: 2006, 126th edn, United States Government Printing Office, Washington, DC. United States Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census (2006b) Foreign-Born Profiles STP-159. Available at http://www.census.gov/population/www/ socdemo/foreign/stp-159-2000tl.html US Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis (2006) Regional Economic Accounts. Available at http://www.bea.gov/regional/gsp/ United States Central Intelligence Agency (CIA) (2006) CIA World Fact Book. Available at https://www.cia. gov/cia/publications/factbook/index.html Wagner, D., Head, K. and Ries, J. (2002) Immigration and the trade of provinces, Scottish, Journal of Political Economy, 49, 507 25. White, R. (2007) Immigrant-trade links, transplanted home bias and network effects, Applied Economics, 39, 839 52. World Bank (2006) World Development Indicators: CD- ROM Version, Washington, DC, Development Data Group of the World Bank s International Economics Department. 260 265 270 275 280 285 290 295 300 305 310

6 B. Tadesse and R. White Appendix Country Listing 315 Albania, Algeria, Argentina, Armenia, Australia, Austria, Azerbaan, Bangladesh, Belarus, Belgium, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Brazil, Bulgaria, Canada, Chile, China, Colombia, Croatia, Czech Republic, Denmark, Dominican Republic, Egypt, El Salvador, 320 Estonia, Finland, France, Georgia, Germany, Greece, Hungary, Iceland, India, Indonesia, Iran, Ireland, Israel, Italy, Japan, Jordan, Korea (South), Latvia, Lithuania, Luxembourg, Macedonia, Malta, Mexico, Moldova, Morocco, Netherlands, New Zealand, Nigeria, Norway, Pakistan, Peru, Philippines, Poland, Portugal, Romania, Russia, Singapore, Slovakia, Slovenia, South Africa, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, Tanzania, Turkey, Uganda, Ukraine, United Kingdom, Uruguay, Venezuela, Vietnam, Zimbabwe. 325 330