Does government decentralization reduce domestic terror? An empirical test

Similar documents
Does Government Ideology affect Personal Happiness? A Test

Supplementary Material for Preventing Civil War: How the potential for international intervention can deter conflict onset.

Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions. Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University. August 2018

Corruption and the shadow economy: an empirical analysis

Does terror increase aid?

the notion that poverty causes terrorism. Certainly, economic theory suggests that it would be

The interaction effect of economic freedom and democracy on corruption: A panel cross-country analysis

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

The Impact of the Interaction between Economic Growth and Democracy on Human Development: Cross-National Analysis

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts

The effect of foreign aid on corruption: A quantile regression approach

An Empirical Analysis of Pakistan s Bilateral Trade: A Gravity Model Approach

5. Destination Consumption

DOES TERROR THREATEN HUMAN RIGHTS? EVIDENCE FROM PANEL DATA

Relative Performance Evaluation and the Turnover of Provincial Leaders in China

Measuring the Shadow Economy of Bangladesh, India, Pakistan, and Sri Lanka ( )

The Trade Liberalization Effects of Regional Trade Agreements* Volker Nitsch Free University Berlin. Daniel M. Sturm. University of Munich

Presentation of Rise and Fall of Local Elections in China by Martinez-Bravo, Miguel, Qian and Yao

Does Inequality Increase Crime? The Effect of Income Inequality on Crime Rates in California Counties

A REPLICATION OF THE POLITICAL DETERMINANTS OF FEDERAL EXPENDITURE AT THE STATE LEVEL (PUBLIC CHOICE, 2005) Stratford Douglas* and W.

Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries)

Is Corruption Anti Labor?

Workers Remittances. and International Risk-Sharing

Commuting and Minimum wages in Decentralized Era Case Study from Java Island. Raden M Purnagunawan

Pork Barrel as a Signaling Tool: The Case of US Environmental Policy

Volume 36, Issue 1. Impact of remittances on poverty: an analysis of data from a set of developing countries

The transition of corruption: From poverty to honesty

Model of Voting. February 15, Abstract. This paper uses United States congressional district level data to identify how incumbency,

Happiness and economic freedom: Are they related?

FOREIGN FIRMS AND INDONESIAN MANUFACTURING WAGES: AN ANALYSIS WITH PANEL DATA

Weapon of Choice. Axel Dreher 1 and Merle Kreibaum 2 Paper presented at the 2015 CSAE Conference in Oxford

Political Decentralization and Legitimacy: Cross-Country Analysis of the Probable Influence

Figure 2: Proportion of countries with an active civil war or civil conflict,

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation

Trade and the Spillovers of Transnational Terrorism

Research Report. How Does Trade Liberalization Affect Racial and Gender Identity in Employment? Evidence from PostApartheid South Africa

Natural Resources & Income Inequality: The Role of Ethnic Divisions

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOMEOWNERSHIP IN THE IMMIGRANT POPULATION. George J. Borjas. Working Paper

International Journal of Humanities & Applied Social Sciences (IJHASS)

The Determinants of Low-Intensity Intergroup Violence: The Case of Northern Ireland. Online Appendix

Industrial & Labor Relations Review

Does Democracy Promote Transnational Terrorist Incidents?

Do People Pay More Attention to Earthquakes in Western Countries?

What Can We Learn about Financial Access from U.S. Immigrants?

Remittances and Poverty. in Guatemala* Richard H. Adams, Jr. Development Research Group (DECRG) MSN MC World Bank.

Terror Per Capita. Michael Jetter David Stadelmann

Uppsala Center for Fiscal Studies

Working Papers in Economics

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US

Allocating the US Federal Budget to the States: the Impact of the President. Statistical Appendix

Labor Market Adjustments to Trade with China: The Case of Brazil

Corruption and quality of public institutions: evidence from Generalized Method of Moment

Does the G7/G8 Promote Trade? Volker Nitsch Freie Universität Berlin

Following the Leader: The Impact of Presidential Campaign Visits on Legislative Support for the President's Policy Preferences

WAGE BARGAINING AND POLITICAL STRENGTH

Economic Freedom and Economic Performance: The Case MENA Countries

Rainfall, Financial Development, and Remittances: Evidence from Sub-Saharan Africa

Media and Political Persuasion: Evidence from Russia

The Effect of Ethnic Residential Segregation on Wages of Migrant Workers in Australia

Immigration, integration and terrorism: is there a clash of cultures?

The Origin of Terror: Affluence, Political Freedom, and Ideology

Supplementary information for the article:

Amman, Jordan T: F: /JordanStrategyForumJSF Jordan Strategy Forum

Globalization, Economic Freedom and Human Rights

Expressive Voting and Government Redistribution *

Remittances and the Brain Drain: Evidence from Microdata for Sub-Saharan Africa

CORRUPTION AND THE SHADOW ECONOMY: AN EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS

The Dynamic Response of Fractionalization to Public Policy in U.S. Cities

Does opportunism pay off?

Forms of Civic Engagement and Corruption

Violent Conflict and Inequality

The Electoral Cycle in Political Contributions: The Incumbency Advantage of Early Elections

Branko Milanovic* and John E. Roemer Interaction of Global and National Income Inequalities

1975 TO A Thesis. submitted to the Faculty of the. Graduate School of Arts and Sciences. of Georgetown University

Cross-Country Intergenerational Status Mobility: Is There a Great Gatsby Curve?

Size of Regional Trade Agreements and Regional Trade Bias

Appendix: Regime Type, Coalition Size, and Victory

REMITTANCES, POVERTY AND INEQUALITY

Is Government Size Optimal in the Gulf Countries of the Middle East? An Answer

Auburn University Department of Economics Working Paper Series

Dimitri Thériault 1. March 2018

English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap

Interest Groups and Political Economy of Public Education Spending

Living in the Shadows or Government Dependents: Immigrants and Welfare in the United States

Dimensions of the Wage-Unemployment Relationship in the Nordic Countries: Wage Flexibility without Wage Curves

IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE EASTERN DISTRICT OF PENNSYLVANIA

The Effect of Foreign Direct Investment, Foreign Aid and International Remittance on Economic Growth in South Asian Countries

The Impact of Economics Blogs * David McKenzie, World Bank, BREAD, CEPR and IZA. Berk Özler, World Bank. Extract: PART I DISSEMINATION EFFECT

Family Ties, Labor Mobility and Interregional Wage Differentials*

GENDER EQUALITY IN THE LABOUR MARKET AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT

Is neoliberalism to blame for Orbàn and Le Pen? A statistical analysis of populism and economic freedom Alexander Fritz Englund i ii

Direction of trade and wage inequality

Chapter 1. Introduction

Riccardo Faini (Università di Roma Tor Vergata, IZA and CEPR)

Residential segregation and socioeconomic outcomes When did ghettos go bad?

The Effect of Ethnic Residential Segregation on Wages of Migrant Workers in Australia

Do (naturalized) immigrants affect employment and wages of natives? Evidence from Germany

Transcription:

Does government decentralization reduce domestic terror? An empirical test Axel Dreher a Justina A. V. Fischer b November 2010 Economics Letters, forthcoming Abstract Using a country panel of domestic terror attacks from 1998 to 2004, we empirically analyze the impact of government decentralization on terror. Our results show that expenditure decentralization reduces domestic terror, while political decentralization has no impact. Keywords: Domestic Terrorism, Decentralization, Federalism, Autonomy JEL-Codes: D74; H70; H40, K40 a Georg-August University Goettingen, Platz der Goettinger Sieben 3, 37073 Goettingen, Germany, KOF Swiss Economic Institute, IZA and CESifo, mail@axel-dreher.de. b Stockholm School of Economics, Sweden, OECD, Paris, University of Hamburg, Germany, present address: German Institute for Economic Research (DIW Berlin), International Economics Department, Mohrenstr. 58, 10117 Berlin, Tel. +49 (30) 897 89-0, JAVFischer@gmx.de.

1. Introduction According to the theory of Frey and Luechinger (2004), decentralization reduces terror. Frey and Luechinger argue that decentralized countries are politically and administratively more stable than more centralized states, and have more efficient markets a polity with many different centers of decisionmaking and implementation is difficult, if not impossible, to destabilize (ibidem, p.512). Thus, decentralization may stabilize the polity by reducing the damage terror can exert on a country s ability to govern its affairs, letting countries with strong local governments and administrations recover more quickly. 1 Consequently, terrorists perceived benefits of attacks decrease with government decentralization. Similarly, according to traditional public choice arguments (Brennan and Buchanan 1980, Tiebout 1961), decentralization can yield efficiency gains in government activities and increase the effectiveness of deterring terror through national security policies: Decentralization permits residents to express their disagreement with local security policies by moving to a different jurisdiction in a Tiebout fashion (Tiebout 1961), indirectly exerting control over local decision-makers by inducing incentives for competing local governments to innovate, to work efficiently and to target their security policies effectively (Brennan and Buchanan 1980). As a consequence, the marginal costs of terrorism are increased. Assuming that terrorists are rational decision-makers who weigh the expected costs against the benefits of their terrorist activities (see Lichbach 1987), less terror should occur in countries with stronger local governments and administrations. 2 This hypothesis has been confirmed with data on transnational terror in Dreher and Fischer (2010). In principle, it should also hold for domestic terror, as the goals of destabilizing the polity and economy are common to both transnational and domestic terrorists (Frey and Luechinger 2004). 3 In this paper, we test the hypotheses proposed by Frey and Luechinger (2004) for the effect of government decentralization on domestic terrorism, extending work on transnational terror in Dreher and Fischer (2010). To anticipate our results, we find that expenditure decentralization reduces domestic terror, while political autonomy does not. 1 Gassebner et al. (2008) show that terrorists are at least to some extent successful in destabilizing the political system, as terror attacks increase the probability of cabinet dissolutions. 2 3 Sandler and Enders (2004) present an application of the rational choice model. Media attention is a possible third goal. The predicted effect of decentralization on terrorism through influencing media attention is, however, ambiguous (for a discussion, see Dreher and Fischer 2010). 2

2. The opportunity costs argument Referring to domestic terror terror attacks by the local population targeted at their home country Frey and Luechinger (2003, 2004) and Li (2005) stress the importance of opportunity costs in fighting terror. Opportunity costs of domestic terrorist activities refer to alternative legal activities (e.g., regular employment or political engagement) potential domestic terrorists may derive utility from. According to Frey and Luechinger (2004), terrorists ultimately pursue long-term political goals, which they attempt to achieve through their destabilization efforts. However, decentralized structures may well allow potential terrorists to realize their political goals in a legal way instead as decentralization gives the citizenry control over government spending activities and political decision-making. Similarly, Li (2005) argues with respect to political participation rights that a more satisfied citizenry is less likely to support terrorism. Consequently, Frey and Luechinger (2004) propose that strong local governments can increase the opportunity costs of domestic terrorists by making terror less attractive as compared to alternative legal activities. Taken all together, these arguments suggest that government decentralization improves not only security policies, stabilizes the market economy and the political system, but also increases domestic terrorists opportunity costs. Hence, we expect decentralization to reduce the optimal level of domestic terror, expressed in the following testable hypothesis: 4 Government decentralization reduces the number of domestic terrorist incidents. 3. Measuring decentralization and terror We employ two measures of government decentralization. First, fiscal decentralization is measured as the share of expenditures of all sub-federal government tiers in total expenditures by all levels of government, based on the IMF s Government Finance Statistics (GFS). One version includes grants in expenditures, while the other subtracts grants prior to dividing sub-federal expenditures by general government expenditures. These data are available for the 1990-2004 period for about 70 countries. 5 Among the countries in our sample, spending decentralization is in the range of 0%-54%, with a mean of 18%, and a median of 16%. Second, to account for the distribution of political power among the central and sub-national governments, we use a dichotomous indicator of political autonomy of second tier governments 4 Arguably, decentralization might also imply drawbacks, implying more rather then less terrorist activity. For a summary of the arguments see Dreher and Fischer (2010). 5 The data can be downloaded from http://www.axel-dreher.de/decentralization.xls. 3

obtained from Treisman (2002). This indicator takes on unity if according to the federal constitution (1) laws of the second tier cannot be overruled by federal legislation or (2) the federal legislation is restricted to framework regulation. In our sample, about 20% of the countries are coded as having politically autonomous sub-federal tiers. Turning to our dependent variable, we employ the measure of domestic terrorist activity from the MIPT Terrorism Knowledge Base. 6 Terror is defined as violence, or the threat of violence, calculated to create an atmosphere of fear and alarm. A domestic terror act is committed if terror groups are domestic (neither transnational nor foreign-based, like Al Qaeda), and if their targets are also domestic (as opposed to transnational, such as airports and embassies). The number of domestic terror events per country and year are available from 1998 on; we assign zeros to all countries and years with no records. 7 Figure 1 shows the overall number of domestic and transnational terror events for our sample over time. While both are decreasing over the sample period, the number of domestic events is substantially higher. The highest number of domestic attacks over the whole sample period appears in Colombia (404), India (340), Russia (202), and Nepal (106). The highest numbers of transnational events occur in Colombia (26), Israel (16), and Indonesia (15). 4. Method We estimate pooled time-series cross-section two-way fixed effects regressions. As our data on terror events are strongly skewed to the right and display significant overdispersion, we employ the Negative Binomial estimator. Our basic equation takes the following form: terror it = α + β decent + β X + λ + θ + ε ' 1 it 2 it i t it, (1) where terror it represents the number of domestic terror events in country i in year t, and decent it is one of our measures of decentralization. X it is the vector of control variables, λ i represents the country fixed effects, and θ t the time fixed effects, while ε it represents the disturbance. Standard errors are clustered at the country level. In choosing our control variables, we follow Dreher and Fischer s (2010) analysis of transnational terror our focus on domestic rather than transnational terrorism affects only the interpretation of the control variables, while they arguably remain relevant in the domestic context. We 6 7 Available at: http://www.mipt.org (20 Feb 2009). Territories are assigned to the country formally governing the territory. Kashmir and the Persian Gulf are excluded as it is not obvious to which country they should be assigned to. 4

use (log) per capita GDP and (log) population size from the World Bank (2006), government fractionalization from Beck et al. (2001), the index of political freedom and civil liberties (Freedom House, 2009), and a country s voting coincidence with the United States in the United Nations General Assembly. Since some of the data are not available for all countries or years, the panels are unbalanced with regression samples covering up to 743 observations from 110 countries, over the 1998-2004 period. 5. Results Table 1 shows the results for our two indicators of expenditure decentralization. Columns 1 and 2 show that fiscal decentralization reduces the number of domestic terror events. This is in line with our a priori hypothesis that decentralized structures may increase the opportunity costs and direct costs of domestic terrorists, on the one hand, but equally that it may decrease the marginal benefit from such a terror act, as decentralization stabilizes the polity and the economy. Calculating the marginal effect (at the sample mean, with the country and year dummies equal to zero), the results in column 1 show that the number of terror events in a country declines by 0.001 as decentralization increases by ten percentage points. The calculated elasticity of almost 2.5% is socially relevant. Regarding the vector of control variables, the number of domestic terror events decreases with political and civil freedom, at the 5 percent level at least, consistent with Li s (2005) hypothesis. In column 1, voting with the United States is positively associated with the number of domestic terror events (significant at the ten percent level). The remaining control variables are not significant at conventional levels. In column 3 we exclude cases indicated as zero decentralization by our indicator (including grants, as in column 1), as these mostly refer to very small countries where there is no distinction between the central and the state/communal level (e.g., San Marino). In column 3, the coefficient on fiscal decentralization remains significant at the five percent level. In this sample, political freedom equally reduces domestic terror, also significant at the five percent level. In column 4 we include the time-invariant political autonomy variable (and estimate a pooled model which excludes the country dummies). While its negative coefficient would be in support of our hypothesis, it is far from being significant at conventional levels. 8 In columns 5 and 6 we distinguish between severe and less severe terror events. 9 However, the regression focusing on less severe events (column 6) does not converge when the year dummies are 8 When fiscal decentralization is added to the empirical model in column 3, political autonomy remains insignificant (while the number of observations is substantially reduced). Political autonomy also stays insignificant when the number of severe or, respectively, less severe terror events are employed as dependent variables. 5

included, so we omit them. As can be seen, our previous results have been driven by severe events only. Severe terror events decrease with decentralization at the one percent level of significance, while less severe events are not affected by decentralization. 6. Summary and conclusion This paper empirically analyzes the impact of a decentralized governance structure on the occurrence of domestic terror using data for a maximum of 110 countries over the years 1998-2004. Following Frey and Luechinger (2003, 2004) and Li (2005), we argue that decentralization may affect the costs, benefits, and opportunity costs of terrorists, and thus decrease the optimal level of domestic terrorist activity. Indeed, we find that expenditure decentralization reduces the number of domestic terror events. In contrast, local political autonomy exerts no impact. Acknowledgement: We thank Stefan Keitel for help in compiling the expenditure decentralization data. 9 We define a terror event as severe when at least one person has been injured or killed. 6

Figure 1: Domestic and Transnational Terror over Time Number of terror events 0 100 200 300 400 1998 2000 2002 2004 year domestic international 7

Table 1: Decentralization and Domestic Terror, Negative Binomial Regression, 1998-2004 (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Fiscal decentralization -0.142-0.173 0.060 (3.51)*** (3.39)*** (0.50) Fiscal decentralization (no grants) -0.107 (3.33)*** Fiscal decentralization (>0) -0.109 (2.48)** Political autonomy -0.050 (0.08) (log) GDP per capita -2.977-3.556-2.581 0.232-0.500-4.329 (1.03) (1.10) (0.78) (1.09) (0.10) (1.03) (log) Population 3.785 3.199 3.961 1.101 5.855-4.010 (0.68) (0.55) (0.73) (8.34)*** (0.65) (0.20) Political freedom -0.349-0.413-0.355-0.223-0.374 0.895 (2.22)** (2.74)*** (2.30)** (1.55) (1.54) (2.02)** Government fractionalization -0.146 0.089-0.223 1.187-0.224-0.847 (0.41) (0.26) (0.56) (1.72)* (0.38) (0.70) Voting with U.S. 4.484 4.759 4.064 6.796 6.240 0.758 (1.66)* (1.43) (1.39) (4.95)*** (1.33) (0.20) Number of observations 233 233 191 743 233 233 Number of countries 59 59 52 110 59 59 Country fixed effects yes yes yes no yes yes Year fixed effects yes yes yes yes yes no Dependent variable all terror all terror all terror all terror severe terror less severe terror Notes: The dependent variable is the number of domestic terror events in a particular year and country. Column 5 (6) focuses on severe (less severe) events. A terror event is defined as severe when at least one person has been injured or killed. Absolute value of z statistics in parentheses.* significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1% 8

References Brennan, G., Buchanan, J. M., 1980. The power to tax. Analytical foundations of a fiscal constitution., Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. Dreher, A., Fischer, J.A.V., 2010. Government decentralization as a disincentive for transnational terror? An empirical analysis. IER forthcoming. Frey, B. S., Luechinger, S., 2003. How to fight terrorism: alternatives to deterrence. Def. Peace Econ. 14, 237 249. Frey, B. S., Luechinger, S., 2004. Decentralization as a Disincentive for Terror, EJPE 20. 590-515. Gassebner, M., Jong-A-Pin, R., Mierau, J., 2008. Terrorism and electoral accountability: One strike, you re out!. EL 100, 126-129. Li, Q., 2005. Does Democracy Promote or Reduce Transnational Terrorist Incidents? J. Confl. Resolut. 49, 278-297. Lichbach, M. I., 1987. Deterrence or escalation? The puzzle of aggregate studies of repression and dissent, J.Confl.Resolut. 31, 266 297. Sandler, T., Enders, W., 2004. An economic perspective on transnational terrorism. EJPE 20, 301-316. Tiebout, C. M., 1961. An Economic Theory of Fiscal Decentralization, in: National Bureau Of Economic Research (Ed.), Public Finances: Needs, Sources and Utilization. Universities- National Bureau,, 79-96. Treisman, D., 2002, Decentralization and the quality of government, Working paper, Department of Political Science, University of California, Los Angeles. 9

Appendix A: Definitions and Sources Variable Definition Source Number of domestic terror events Fiscal decentralization Fiscal decentralization (no grants) Political autonomy (log) GDP per capita (log) Population Political freedom Government fractionalization Voting with U.S. Number of domestic terror events for each country and year, defined as violence, or the threat of violence, calculated to create an atmosphere of fear and alarm. Total expenditure of sub-national (local and state) government tiers divided by total spending by all levels of government. Total expenditure of sub-national government tiers less grants divided by total spending by all levels of government less grants. Under the constitution, subnational governments have residual powers (to legislate on areas not explicitly assigned to other levels). Gross domestic product divided by midyear population. Data are in constant U.S. dollars. Total population is based on the de facto definition of population, which counts all residents regardless of legal status or citizenship, except for refugees not permanently settled in the country of asylum. Average value of political rights and civil liberties, ranging from -7 to -1, where higher values reflect greater freedom. Probability that two deputies picked at random from among the government parties will be of different parties( low(0)-high(1)). Votes in agreement with the US are coded as 1, votes in disagreement as 0, and abstentions or absences as 0.5. The resulting numbers are then divided by the total number of votes in each country and year. MIPT Terrorism Knowledge Base IMF s Government Finance Statistics IMF s Government Finance Statistics Treisman (2008) World Bank (2006) World Bank (2006) Freedom House (2009) Beck et al. (2001) Dreher and Sturm (2010) Appendix B: Descriptive Statistics (estimation sample, Table 1, column 1) Variable Mean Std. Dev. Min Max Number of domestic terror events 6.61 20.89 0.00 184.00 Fiscal decentralization 17.56 14.73 0.00 54.36 Fiscal decentralization (no grants) 19.26044 16.44748 0 60.1 Political autonomy 0.20 0.40 0.00 1.00 (log) GDP per capita 7.88 1.31 4.68 10.50 (log) Population 16.09 1.82 12.52 20.98 Political freedom -3.00 1.64-6.50-1.00 Government fractionalization 0.36 0.32 0.00 1.00 Voting with U.S. 0.31 0.14 0.00 0.80 1