Quality of Institutions : Does Intelligence Matter?

Similar documents
Is Corruption Anti Labor?

Governance and Intelligence: Empirical Analysis from African Data

Intelligence and Corruption

Remittances and the Brain Drain: Evidence from Microdata for Sub-Saharan Africa

corruption since they might reect judicial eciency rather than corruption. Simply put,

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation

The interaction effect of economic freedom and democracy on corruption: A panel cross-country analysis

The effect of foreign aid on corruption: A quantile regression approach

The transition of corruption: From poverty to honesty

Working Paper. Why So Few Women in Poli/cs? Evidence from India. Mudit Kapoor Shamika Ravi. July 2014

The Impact of NREGS on Urbanization in India

Discussion Paper Series A No.533

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts

Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions. Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University. August 2018

Supplementary information for the article:

University of Groningen. Corruption and governance around the world Seldadyo, H.

Business Associations, Bureaucratic and Political Corruption: An Empirical Analysis of Lobby Group Membership. Eugene Kiselev.

Economic Freedom and Economic Performance: The Case MENA Countries

Corruption and Agricultural Trade. Trina Biswas

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US

Do We See Convergence in Institutions? A Cross- Country Analysis

UCD CENTRE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH WORKING PAPER SERIES. Open For Business? Institutions, Business Environment and Economic Development

Exporters and Wage Inequality during the Great Recession - Evidence from Germany

On Trade Policy and Wages Inequality in Egypt: Evidence from Microeconomic Data

Endogenous antitrust: cross-country evidence on the impact of competition-enhancing policies on productivity

Beyond legal origin and checks and balances: Political credibility, citizen information and financial sector development

Figure 2: Proportion of countries with an active civil war or civil conflict,

The Impact of the Interaction between Economic Growth and Democracy on Human Development: Cross-National Analysis

Quantitative Analysis of Migration and Development in South Asia

Interest Groups and Political Economy of Public Education Spending

The Eects of Immigration on Household Services, Labour Supply and Fertility. Agnese Romiti. Abstract

IQ in the Production Function: Evidence from Immigrant Earnings

Do Changes in Economic Freedom affect Well-Being?

IMMIGRATION AND PEER EFFECTS: EVIDENCE FROM PRIMARY EDUCATION IN SPAIN

Prediction of national wealth

Supplementary Material for Preventing Civil War: How the potential for international intervention can deter conflict onset.

Trade and the Spillovers of Transnational Terrorism

Differences Lead to Differences: Diversity and Income Inequality Across Countries

Immigration and the use of public maternity services in England

ADB Economics Working Paper Series

Understanding Subjective Well-Being across Countries: Economic, Cultural and Institutional Factors

Natural Resources & Income Inequality: The Role of Ethnic Divisions

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

Working Paper Series Department of Economics Alfred Lerner College of Business & Economics University of Delaware

Volume 36, Issue 1. Impact of remittances on poverty: an analysis of data from a set of developing countries

Do neighbors help nding a job? Social networks and labor market outcomes after plant closures

International Remittances and the Household: Analysis and Review of Global Evidence

Happiness and economic freedom: Are they related?

Trade led Growth in Times of Crisis Asia Pacific Trade Economists Conference 2 3 November 2009, Bangkok. Session 11

Foreign Aid and Economic Growth in the Developing Countries - A Cross-country Empirical Analysis *

ECON 450 Development Economics

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

Workers Remittances. and International Risk-Sharing

CORRUPTION AND THE SHADOW ECONOMY: AN EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS

THE DETERMINANTS OF CORRUPTION: CROSS-COUNTRY-PANEL-DATA ANALYSIS

Following monetary union with west Germany in June 1990, the median real monthly consumption wage of east German workers aged rose by 83% in six

Poverty, Inequality and Trade Facilitation in Low and Middle Income Countries

Health Consequences of Legal Origin

English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap

Research Report. How Does Trade Liberalization Affect Racial and Gender Identity in Employment? Evidence from PostApartheid South Africa

THE EFFECT OF GLOBALIZATION ON INCOME INEQUALITY IN ASEAN-5

Appendix: Uncovering Patterns Among Latent Variables: Human Rights and De Facto Judicial Independence

Immigration and International Prices

Why are the Relative Wages of Immigrants Declining? A Distributional Approach* Brahim Boudarbat, Université de Montréal

Relative Performance Evaluation and the Turnover of Provincial Leaders in China

Religious Diversity and Economic Development in Sub-Saharan Africa: So Far So Good

The Organization of European Multinationals

Does government decentralization reduce domestic terror? An empirical test

HOW MUCH DOES GOVERNANCE REALLY MATTER? THE EFFECTS OF GOVERNANCE ON WELL-BEING

Does a larger number of regulations concerning

THE EFFECT OF CONCEALED WEAPONS LAWS: AN EXTREME BOUND ANALYSIS

The Colonial and non-colonial Origins of Institutions in Latin America

Corruption and the shadow economy: an empirical analysis

Remittances and Poverty. in Guatemala* Richard H. Adams, Jr. Development Research Group (DECRG) MSN MC World Bank.

INSTITUTIONS AND GROWTH IN SAARC COUNTRIES

The impact of resident status regulations on immigrants' labor supply: evidence for France

Immigration, Information, and Trade Margins

The global financial crisis and remittances

An Empirical Analysis of Pakistan s Bilateral Trade: A Gravity Model Approach

The Acceleration of Immigrant Unhealthy Assimilation

Comparative Statics Quantication of Structural Migration Gravity Models

Small Employers, Large Employers and the Skill Premium

Does Paternity Leave Matter for Female Employment in Developing Economies?

Supporting Information for Representation and Redistribution in Comparative Perspective. Tiberiu Dragu and Jonathan Rodden

Corruption and Trade Protection: Evidence from Panel Data

Direction of trade and wage inequality

Trust, Economic Growth, and Political Stability. (Preliminary) Nathan Nunn Nancy Qian Jaya Wen Ÿ. January 10, Abstract

Election goals and income redistribution: Recent evidence from Albania

Does the G7/G8 Promote Trade? Volker Nitsch Freie Universität Berlin

Supplemental Results Appendix

DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

Terror Per Capita. Michael Jetter David Stadelmann

The Gravity Model on EU Countries An Econometric Approach

When Does Legal Origin Matter? Mohammad Amin * World Bank. Priya Ranjan ** University of California, Irvine. December 2008

Corruption s Effect on Growth and its Transmission Channels

Corruption and quality of public institutions: evidence from Generalized Method of Moment

Labor Market Performance of Immigrants in Early Twentieth-Century America

The Trade Liberalization Effects of Regional Trade Agreements* Volker Nitsch Free University Berlin. Daniel M. Sturm. University of Munich

Reforming the speed of justice: Evidence from an event study in Senegal

Human capital transmission and the earnings of second-generation immigrants in Sweden

Transcription:

Quality of Institutions : Does Intelligence Matter? Isaac Kalonda-Kanyama 1,2,3 and Oasis Kodila-Tedika 3 1 Department of Economics and Econometrics, University of Johannesburg, South Africa. 2 Department of Economics, University of Kansas, Lawrence, Kansas 66045, USA. 3 Faculté des Sciences Économiques et de Gestion, Université de Kinshasa, Rép. Dém. du Congo. Abstract We analyze the eect of the average level of intelligence on dierent measures of the quality of institutions, using a 2006 cross-sectional sample of 113 countries. The results show that average IQ positively aects all the measures of institutional quality considered in our study, namely government eciency, regulatory quality, rule of law, political stability and voice and accountability. The positive eect of intelligence is robust to controlling for other determinants of institutional quality. Key Words: governance, institutions, intelligence. JEL Codes: D73, I2 1 Introduction Numerous studies have documented the eect of national IQs not only on economic growth, but also on an important range of phenomena (Lynn and Vanhanen, 2012). Beside its direct eect on economic growth (Whetzel and McDaniel, 2006; Jones and Schneider, 2006, 2010; Weede and Kämpf, 2002), intelligence has signicant eect on other factors that directly aect economic growth, such as corruption (Potrafke, 2012) and governance (Kodila-Tedika, 2012), and therefore indirectly aect economic growth. Corresponding Author: University of Kansas, Snow Hall, Room 237, 1460 Jayhawk Blvd, Lawrence, Kansas 66045-7585, USA. E-mail: ikanyamat@ku.edu; Telephone: (785) 864-2887; Fax: (785) 864-5760 We wish to thank Niklas Potrafke for providing us with the dataset that we used in our analysis. 1

This paper analyzes the eect of national IQs on government institutions. We argue that institutional quality serves as a channel through which intelligence aect economic growth. Specically, high population IQ improves institutional quality and positively aects economic growth through high-quality government institutions. We consider the relationship between ve measures of institutional quality and national IQ. These measures are the following: government eectiveness/eciency, political stability, and regulatory quality, rule of law and voice and accountability. We nd that, after controlling for other determinants of institutional quality, national IQ positively aect each of the ve measures of institutional quality. The paper is organized in six sections, including this introduction. The second section focuses on a graphical analysis and on the results from simple regressions of the relationship between each of the ve measures of institutional quality and national IQ. The empirical model is discussed in section 3 and regression results are presented in section 4. Section 5 discusses the robustness of the ndings while section 6 concludes. 2 A graphical Analysis Figures 1 and 2 portray the relationship between each of the ve measures of institutional quality (y-axis) and IQ (x-axis) for the countries included in our sample. In Figure 1, government eectiveness/eciency is plotted against IQ. It clearly appears from this gure that countries with higher IQ enjoy higher government eectiveness. We also represent the tted line for the simple regression model Ge i = α + βiq i + ɛ i where Ge is government eectiveness/eciency. The estimated coecient for β is positive (+0.060) and strongly signicant (p-value = 0.000), showing that high IQ improve government eciency. 2

The same conclusion obtains when analyzing the relationship between each of the four remaining measures of institutional quality and IQ. All the four graphs in Figure 2 exhibit a positive relationship between the relevant measure of institutional quality and intelligence. The estimated coecient of β from the simple linear regression model is positive and strongly signicant. In panel (a), ˆβ = 0.042 (p-value = 0.000) for voice and accountability; in panel (b), ˆβ = 0.42 (p-value = 0.000) for political stability; in panel (c) ˆβ = 0.054 (p-value = 0.000) for regulatory quality; and in panel (d) ˆβ = 0.055 (p-value = 0.000) for the rule of law. In each of the simple regression models, IQ explains more than one-third of the variations in the the institutional quality variable: 51.8% of the variations in government eectiveness, 30.5% of the variations in voice and accountability, 30.2% of the variations in politival stability; 48.5% of the variations in regulatory quality and 44.1% of the variations in rule of law. In addition, the correlation coecients between IQ and each of the ve measure of institutional quality are respectively 0.752 (p-value = 0.000) for government eciency, 0.552 (p-value = 0.000) for voice and accountability, 0.550 (pvalue = 0.000) for political stability, 0.699 (p-value = 0.000) for regulatory quality, and 0.664 (p-value = 0.000) for rule of law. However, institutional quality cannot solely be explained by average IQ, and the relationship between the two variables cannot be claimed only based on the above simple regression models. Our aim is to show that the signicant relationship between each of the considered measures of institutional quality and average IQ does remains signicant and robust when we control for other factors. To do so, we shall next specify and estimate a model that accounts for other determinants of institutional quality. 3

3 Empirical Model We estimate the following empirical model: IQI i = α + βiq i + Z iδ + ɛ i (1) where IQI i is the institutional quality index for country i, IQ i is its average IQ, Z = (z 1, z 1... z k ) is the vector of control variables, and ɛ i is the error term that is assumed to be normally and independently distributed. Finally, α is the intercept, β captures the eect of average IQ on institutional quality while δ = (δ 1,, δ 2,..., δ k ) is the parameter vector for the control variables. Our parameter of interest is thus β. As control variables, we include openness to trade, natural resources exports, the log of GDP per capita, legal origin and geographical location. Following the trend in the literature, legal origin is captured by distinguishing between the English, French, German, Scandinavian and socialist legal heritages (see for example Islam and Montenegro (2002), Potrafke (2012), and Kodila-Tedika (2012)). For geographical factors, we use dummy variables for East Asia and the Pacic, Latin America and Caribbean, Middle East and North Africa, Sub-Saharan Africa and South Asia. We capture the eect of natural resources by using the share of primary commodities in total exports of goods. This variable accounts for the eect of the rent-seeking opportunities due to the presence of natural resources. Finally, openness to trade is measured by the GDP share of the value of total exports and imports. The model in equation (1) is estimated by means of 2SLS, to account for possible endogeneity that results from the inclusion of openness to trade. In fact, while greater openness increases the demand for better institutions, it may be true that countries with better institutions may be more open (Islam and Montenegro, 2002). We measure countries intelligence by average IQ index (Lynn and Vanhanen, 2002, 2006). Dummies 4

for legal origins come from La Porta et al. (1999). The data on GPD per capita, trade come from Pen World Tables 6.3. 4 Regression Results The regression results are presented in Table 1. Each of the columns (2) (6) displays the estimated model for one of the ve institutional quality variables. Our coecient of interest, ˆβ, is positive and signicant at the 1% level in the regressions where the dependent variable is the rule of law, and at the 5% level in the other regressions. We thus nd that the positive eect of average IQ remains signicant after accounting for other determinants of institutional quality. Therefore, countries with higher IQ enjoy better government institutions. We now turn to the performance of the other determinants of institutional quality when IQ is accounted for. First, Table 1 shows that GDP per capita and natural resources have the expected eect on institutional quality. Their coecients are strongly signicant and have the expected signs in all the ve regressions, meaning that countries with high GDP per capita enjoy better institutions while the presence of natural resources negatively aects the quality of government institutions. Second, the eect of each regional and legal-origin dummy on dierent measures of institutional quality is not the same. Finally, openness to trade has an unexpected sign in Table 1. In addition, the coecient of this variable is signicant only for the rule of law and for voice and accountability. This results seems puzzling. However Kalonda-Kanyama and Kodila-Tedika (2012) show that, when national IQ is accounted for, the relationship between institutional quality and trade may not be linear. For example, they nd an increasing but diminishing relationship between the rule of law and trade on the one hand, and between 5

voice and accountability on the other hand. 5 Robustness Checks To test for the robustness of our ndings, we run the same regressions in Table 1 with data for 2002. The results are reported in Table 2. Our coecient of interest, ˆβ is positive and signicant in all the regressions that we report in Table 2. All the control variables performed in the same way as in the regressions in Table 1. For further robustness checks, we run the regressions in Table 1 with dierent control variables. First, we used the KOF index of economic globalization (Dreher, 2006; Dreher et al., 2008) instead of trade openness. We use a dummy variable for high income countries instead of GDP per capita. We motivate the use of this dummy variable by the fact that citizen in countries with high income would demand better institutions. Finally, we use dummies for continents instead of the regional classication of countries. Table 3 shows that our variable of interest is signicant for all institutional quality variables, except for voice and accountability. 6 Conclusion This paper was mainly concerned with the eect of national level of IQ on dierent aspects of institutional quality. The main nding is that intelligence positively aect each of the ve measures of the quality of government institutions that we considered. Therefore, countries with higher average IQ enjoy better government institutions. An important implication of the nding is that institutional quality is a crucial channel through which intelligence indirectly positively aects economic growth, in addition to its direct positive eect that is already documented in the literature. More specically, high population IQ positively aects institutional quality which, in turn, positively 6

aects economic growth. The results in this paper line up with recent ndings of the eect of intelligence on political institutions (Jones, 2011), corruption (Potrafke, 2012) and governance (Kodila-Tedika, 2012). References Dreher, A. (2006). Does globalization aect growth? evidence from a new index of globalization. Applied Economics, 38:10911110. Dreher, A., Gaston, N., and Martens, P. (2008). Measuring globalization Consequences. Springer, Berlin. Gauging its Islam, R. and Montenegro, C. E. (2002). What determines the quality of institutions? Background Paper for the World Development Report: Building Institutions for Markets. Jones, G. (2011). National IQ and national productivity: The hive mind across asia. Asian Development Review, 28:5871. Jones, G. and Schneider, W. (2006). Intelligence, human capital, and economic growth: A bayesian averaging of classical estimates (bace) approach. Journal of Economic Growth, 11(1):7193. Jones, G. and Schneider, W. J. (2010). IQ in the production function: evidence from immigrant earnings. Economic Inquiry, 48(3):743755. Kalonda-Kanyama, I. and Kodila-Tedika, O. (2012). A new look at the determinants of institutional quality. Working Paper. Kodila-Tedika, O. (2012). Gouvernance et intelligence: Analyse empirique sur données africaines. Université de Kinshasa Working Papers. La Porta, R., de Silanes, F. L., Shleifer, A., and Vishny, R. (1999). The quality of government. The Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 15(1):222279. Lynn, R. and Vanhanen, T. (2002). IQ and the Wealth of Nations. Praeger Publishers, Westport, CT. Lynn, R. and Vanhanen, T. (2006). IQ and Global Inequality. Washington Summit Publishers, Augusta, GA. Lynn, R. and Vanhanen, T. (2012). National IQs: A review of their educational, cognitive, economic, political, demographic, sociological, epidemiological, geographic and climatic correlates. Intelligence. doi:10.1016/j.intell.2011.11.004. 7

Potrafke, N. (2012). Intelligence and corruption. Economic Letters, 114:109112. Weede, E. and Kämpf, S. (2002). The impact of intelligence and institutional improvements on economic growth. Kyklos, 55(3):361380. Whetzel, D. L. and McDaniel, M. A. (2006). Prediction of national wealth. Intelligence, 34:449458. 8

Figure 1: Government eciency and IQ 9

Figure 2: Institutional indicators and IQ (a) (b) (c) (d) 10

Table 1: Main Regression (Year = 2006) Government Political Regulatory Rule of law Voice and Variables eectiveness stability quality Accoutability Intelligence (IQ), ˆβ 0.017** 0.035** 0.021** 0.032*** 0.032** (0.032) (0.032) (0.026) (0.001) (0.034) Openness -0.002-0.008* -0.001-0.005** -0.009*** (0.324) (0.094) (0.497) (0.020) (0.001) Natural resources -0.005*** -0.005-0.006*** -0.007*** -0.010*** (0.000) (0.111) (0.007) (0.001) (0.001) Log GDP per capita 0.593*** 0.542*** 0.559*** 0.501*** 0.602*** (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) East Asia and Pacic -0.190-0.243-0.395** -0.436** -0.461 (0.172) (0.500) (0.017) (0.028) (0.216) Europe and Central Asia -0.581*** -0.662** -0.390** -0.627*** -0.365 (0.000) (0.013) (0.023) (0.002) (0.248) Latin America & Carrib. -0.431*** -0.094-0.292* -0.702*** 0.311 (0.000) (0.634) (0.091) (0.000) (0.148) South Asia -0.495** -1.385*** -0.429* -0.688** -0.572 (0.020) (0.001) (0.050) (0.033) (0.195) Sub-Saharan Africa 0.194 0.958*** 0.320 0.237 0.771** (0.258) (0.002) (0.199) (0.279) (0.026) English legal origin -0.344** 0.176 0.015-0.067 0.215 (0.020) (0.537) (0.921) (0.589) (0.359) French legal origin -0.641*** -0.197-0.183-0.446*** -0.244 (0.000) (0.391) (0.217) (0.005) (0.241) German legal origin -0.495*** -0.484** -0.297* -0.554** -0.599** (0.000) (0.012) (0.065) (0.010) (0.020) Socialist legal origin -0.586*** 0.410-0.091-0.608*** 0.029 (0.000) (0.173) (0.565) (0.002) (0.924) Constant -5.577*** -7.058*** -6.138*** -5.981*** -6.950*** (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) Observations 113 113 113 113 114 R-squared 88.8 36.1 79.8 77.1 51.0 Robust p-values in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 11

Table 2: Robustness regression 1 (Year = 2002) Government Political Regulatory Rule of law Voice and Variables eectiveness stability quality Accoutability Intelligence (IQ), ˆβ 0.0222*** 0.038** 0.029*** 0.035*** 0.026** (0.006) (0.019) (0.006) (0.001) (0.037) Openness -0.003-0.011* -0.001-0.006** -0.008*** (0.242) (0.087) (0.658) (0.035) (0.003) Natural resources -0.006*** -0.008** -0.008*** -0.008*** -0.012*** (0.001) (0.022) (0.004) (0.000) (0.000) Log GDP per capita 0.583*** 0.588*** 0.482*** 0.516*** 0.648*** (0.000) (0.001) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) East Asia and Pacic -0.194-0.178-0.468*** -0.421** -0.440 (0.185) (0.670) (0.003) (0.045) (0.212) Europe and Central Asia -0.523*** -0.604* -0.317* -0.583*** -0.285 (0.000) (0.050) (0.058) (0.006) (0.331) Latin America & Carrib. -0.450*** -0.171-0.315* -0.747*** 0.267 (0.000) (0.435) (0.0681) (0.000) (0.176) South Asia -0.521*** -1.542*** -0.494** -0.711** -0.424 (0.009) (0.000) (0.014) (0.024) (0.264) Sub-Saharan Africa 0.200 0.905** 0.256 0.205 0.710** (0.260) (0.011) (0.222) (0.398) (0.023) English legal origin -0.276* 0.301 0.015-0.035 0.040 (0.054) (0.367) (0.927) (0.819) (0.828) French legal origin -0.635*** -0.172-0.257-0.469** -0.347* (0.000) (0.547) (0.101) (0.011) (0.086) German legal origin -0.600*** -0.727*** -0.431** -0.705*** -0.711*** (0.000) (0.002) (0.010) (0.001) (0.002) Socialist legal origin -0.477*** 0.577-0.101-0.519** 0.043 (0.005) (0.172) (0.557) (0.033) (0.888) Constant -5.593*** -7.329*** -5.961*** -6.166*** -6.692*** (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) Observations 110 110 110 110 110 R-squared 86.0 17.8 78.7 74.8 56.5 Robust p-values in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 12

Table 3: Robustness Regressions 2 (Year = 2006) Government Political regulatory Rule Voice Variables eectiveness stability quality of law and acc. Intelligence (IQ), ˆβ 0.037*** 0.030*** 0.030*** 0.42*** 0.14 (0.000) (0.007) (0.001) (0.000) (0.323) Economic globalization 0.015** 0.020* 0.067** 0.007 0.007 (0.043) (0.050) (0.016) (0.498) (0.497) Natural resources -0.005*** -0.007** -0.007*** -0.008*** -0.009*** (0.002) (0.010) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) High income 0.562*** 0.477** 0.534*** 0.605*** 0.494*** (0.001) (0.015) (0.000) (0.001) (0.000) Africa -0.074 0.206-0.121-0.117-0.516 (0.826) (0.432) (0.7550 (0.755) (0.295) America -0.378-0.419-0.337-0.610-0.021 (0.257) (0.103) (0.3780 (0.106) (0.960) Asia -0.482-1.124*** -0.534-0.639* -0.868** (0.114) (0.000) (0.129) (0.061) (0.035) Europe -0.243-0.695** -0.170-0.186 0.143 (0.690) (0.016) (0.636) (0.631) (0.738) English legal origin -0.317** -0.442** 0.048-0.237-0.079 (0.039) (0.017) (0.705) (0.178) (0.665) French legal origin -0.726*** -0.580*** -0.225** -0.617*** -0.414*** (0.000) (0.000) (0.037) (0.000) (0.003) German legal origin -0.219-0.008 0.062-0.226 0.056 (0.186) (0.968) (0.706) (0.320) (0.776) Socialist legal origin -1.002*** -0.209-0.368*** -1.088*** -0.602*** (0.000) (0.283) (0.003) (0.000) (0.000) Constant -3.149*** -3.021*** -3.047*** -3.105*** -0.821 (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.503) Observations 113 113 113 113 113 R-squared 83.0 64.9 80.0 80.7 72.8 Robust p-values in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 13