International Trade & Income Inequality in Japan

Similar documents
Wage inequality and skill premium

Chapter 5. Resources and Trade: The Heckscher-Ohlin

Chapter 5. Resources and Trade: The Heckscher-Ohlin Model

Chapter 4. Preview. Introduction. Resources, Comparative Advantage, and Income Distribution

Pao-Li Chang 90 Stamford Road, Singapore

ICT, Offshoring, and the Demand for Part-time Workers: The Case of Japanese Manufacturing

Globalization: What Did We Miss?

Midterm Exam Economics 181 PLEASE SHOW YOUR WORK! PUT YOUR NAME AND TA s NAME ON ALL PAGES 100 Points Total

International Business Economics

International Trade 31E00500, Spring 2017

Trade Liberalization and Inequality: Re-examining Theory and Empirical Evidence

International Trade EKN 804 2nd Semester 2017 Syllabus

Yukiko Abe. Current position Professor, Hokkaido University, 2009-

Globalisation and inequality: is Heckscher-Ohlin theory dead? Adrian Wood University of Oxford

INTERNATIONAL TRADE. (prepared for the Social Science Encyclopedia, Third Edition, edited by A. Kuper and J. Kuper)

W. J. Ethier April Feenstra, Advanced International Trade (Princeton, 2004). (denoted F below).

ADJUSTMENT TO TRADE POLICY IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES

EC 591. INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS Professor R Lucas: Fall 2018 Monday and Wednesday ROOM CAS 227

Migration and FDI Facts

Trends in inequality worldwide (Gini coefficients)

SIMON FRASER UNIVERSITY DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

ARTNeT Trade Economists Conference Trade in the Asian century - delivering on the promise of economic prosperity rd September 2014

First Midterm. Time allowed: 50 minutes. Please answer ALL questions. The total score is 100. Please budget your time wisely.

UNION COLLEGE DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, FALL 2004 ECO 146 SEMINAR IN GLOBAL ECONOMIC ISSUES GLOBALIZATION AND LABOR MARKETS

International Trade and Investment Economics Course Outline and Reading List

EC 591. INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS Professor R Lucas: Fall 2012 Monday & Wednesday SSW 315

The impact of Chinese import competition on the local structure of employment and wages in France

Is the American Middle Class Losing Out to China and India?

Yukiko Abe. Current position Professor, Hokkaido University, 2009-

Source: Piketty Saez. Share (in %), excluding capital gains. Figure 1: The top decile income share in the U.S., % 45% 40% 35% 30% 25%

RELATIVE WAGE PATTERNS AMONG SKILLED AND UNSKILLED WORKERS AND INTERNATIONAL TRADE: EVIDENCE FROM CANADA

Asian Development Bank Institute. ADBI Working Paper Series INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND INEQUALITY. Shujiro Urata and Dionisius A.

W. J. Ethier January The Literature

Trade Policy, Agreements and Taxation of Multinationals

International Trade Theory Professor Giovanni Facchini. Corse Outline and Reading List

International Trade and Inequality

ECON MACROECONOMIC PRINCIPLES Instructor: Dr. Juergen Jung Towson University. J.Jung Chapter 18 - Trade Towson University 1 / 42

AED ECONOMICS 6200 INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS AND POLICY. Additional Reading. 1. Trade Equilibrium, Gains from Trade; and Comparative Advantage

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach

The Impact of Immigration on Wages of Unskilled Workers

Pao-Li Chang 90 Stamford Road, Singapore

Income Inequality and Trade Protection

ERIA Research Project Report 2012, No. 4. Edited by CHIN HEE HAHN DIONISIUS A. NARJOKO

Globalisation and Labour Markets: Implications for Australian Public Policy

How Can Globalization Become More Pro-Poor?

Econ 340. Lecture 4 Modern Theories and Additional Effects of Trade

How does international trade affect household welfare?

INTERNATIONAL TRADE & ECONOMICS LAW: THEORIES OF INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND ECONOMICS

Readings for Ph.D. Students

UNIVERSITY OF COLORADO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS. Course Outline

title, Routledge, September 2008: 234x156:

Globalization, Technology and Inequality

Topics in Trade and Development

The Effect of International Trade on Wages of Skilled and Unskilled Workers: Evidence from Brazil

US Trade and Wages: The Misleading Implications of Conventional Trade Theory

Trade Liberalization and Wage Inequality in India: A Mandated Wage Equation Approach

Findings and Implications from Empirical Research in Economics

Chapter 10 Trade Policy in Developing Countries

WORKSHOPS. Proceedings of OeNB Workshops. International Trade & Domestic Growth: Determinants, Linkages and Challenges. September 27, 2007

Chapter Organization. Introduction. Introduction. Import-Substituting Industrialization. Import-Substituting Industrialization

The labor market in Japan,

International Trade Revised: November 8, 2012 Latest version available at

Organized by. In collaboration with. Posh Raj Pandey South Asia Watch on Trade, Economics & Environment (SAWTEE)

Free Trade Producers, Protectionist Consumers? Evidence from A Survey Experiment in Japan

The Growth and Patterns of International Trade

The task-specialization hypothesis and possible productivity effects of immigration

Cleavages in Public Preferences about Globalization

Chapter 11. Trade Policy in Developing Countries

Wage Inequality and Offshoring: Are They Related?

Notes on exam in International Economics, 16 January, Answer the following five questions in a short and concise fashion: (5 points each)

Trade, foreign investment, and wage inequality in developing countries

Curriculum Vitae. Keio Economic Observatory Mita, Minato-ku. Tel:

CARLETON UNIVERSITY Department of Economics. ECON 5603 Topics in International Economics (Winter 2018)

INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND LABOUR MARKET PERFORMANCE: MAJOR FINDINGS AND OPEN QUESTIONS

Wage Inequality in the United States and Europe: A Summary of the major theoretical and empirical explanations in the current debate

Advanced International Trade

Research Report. How Does Trade Liberalization Affect Racial and Gender Identity in Employment? Evidence from PostApartheid South Africa

Distributional Effects of Globalization. Devashish Mitra Syracuse University & NBER. April 11, 2005

International Economics Day 2. Douglas J Young Professor Emeritus MSU

Simon Fraser University Department of Economics. Econ342: International Trade. Mid-Term Examination

Growth in Open Economies, Schumpeterian Models

Skill Classification Does Matter: Estimating the Relationship Between Trade Flows and Wage Inequality

TRADE IN SERVICES AND INCOME INEQUALITY IN DEVELOPING ECONOMIES

Economics 791: Topics in International Trade Syllabus: Fall 2008

Econ 631 Advanced International Trade

The Comparative Advantage of Nations: Shifting Trends and Policy Implications

International Economics, 10e (Krugman/Obstfeld/Melitz) Chapter 2 World Trade: An Overview. 2.1 Who Trades with Whom?

Chapter Ten Growth, Immigration, and Multinationals

The China Syndrome. Local Labor Market Effects of Import Competition in the United States. David H. Autor, David Dorn, and Gordon H.

Raymundo Miguel Campos-Vázquez. Center for Economic Studies, El Colegio de México, and consultant to the OECD. and. José Antonio Rodríguez-López

COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE

Topics in International Trade Summer 2012

Course Outline for Economics 2300: International Trade Fall, 2003 Daniel Trefler

Can free-trade policies help to reduce gender inequalities in employment and wages?

Regional Economic Cooperation of ASEAN Plus Three: Opportunities and Challenges from Economic Perspectives.

Evaluating Stolper-Samuelson: Trade Liberalization & Wage Inequality in India

Globalisation and wage inequality

Trade Integration and Employment: A Theoretical and Empirical Overview Shipra Nigam

International Trade Theory MF 10:30 Fall Syllabus. (2) a mid-term exam Nov. 3 (3) a final exam, date TBA

Distributional Consequences of Trade and Technology

Transcription:

International Trade & Income Inequality in Japan By Ayumu Tanaka Author Ayumu Tanaka Introduction How international trade affects wage inequality is one of the major questions in international economics. This question is so important that many researchers have already examined it. It is closely related to another question how international trade affects income inequality since wage inequality can result in income inequality. This article reviews the previous studies and reexamines the old questions from a Japanese point of view. A remarkable feature of the Japanese labor market is that there is a dual market, in the sense that a labor market for temporary workers exists separately from that for permanent workers. The rapid growth in the number of temporary workers in Japan during the 2000s generated greater income inequality and greater job insecurity because temporary workers wages are lower and their jobs are more tenuous than those of permanent workers. This article examines whether globalization affects this situation. Traditional Trade Theory International trade theory began with David Ricardo s On the Principles of Political Economy and Taxation (1817). In his book, he described the hypothetical situation in which two countries, Britain and Portugal, traded wines and clothes with each other, based on their comparative advantage. In his theory of comparative advantage, both countries obtained gains from international trade. While his theory focused on country-level gains to abolish the Corn Laws, it says nothing about income inequality within a country. However, freer trade can create winners and losers in many cases. In order to produce benefits from free trade, Ricardo supported the abolition of the Corn Laws, which restricted imports of foods by tariffs to protect domestic food producers (the Corn Laws were eventually repealed in 1846, some 23 years after his death). Prof. Paul Krugman of the City University of New York, however, pointed out in his popular textbook International Economics: Theory & Evidence (2009) that imports of foods would have had negative impacts on landowners, while it would have had positive impacts on capitalists. The Ricardian model is too simple to examine the effects of international trade on income distribution. We need more complicated trade models to discuss the distributional effects of international trade (Table 1). In the early 20th century, two Swedish economists, Eli Heckscher and Bertil Ohlin, first presented the so-called Heckscher-Ohlin model. Heckscher published his paper The Effect of Foreign Trade on the Distribution of Income in 1919 and Ohlin published his book Interregional and International Trade in 1933. Their model was mathematically formulated by Paul Samuelson, Ronald W. Jones, and others in following years. The Heckscher-Ohlin model also explains trade patterns by the concept of comparative advantage but focuses on differences in factor endowments across countries rather than technological differences which the Ricardian model focuses on. The Ricardian model considers one production factor (labor) but the Heckscher- Ohlin model considers two production factors, for example, labor versus capital or skilled versus unskilled workers. The Heckscher- Ohlin model predicts that a labor-rich country exports labor-intensive goods, while a capital-rich country exports capital-intensive goods. It also predicts that developed countries where skilled workers are abundant export skill-intensive goods, while developing countries where unskilled workers are abundant export unskilled-intensive goods. The Stolper-Samuelson theorem, one of the theorems of the Heckscher-Ohlin model, was formulated in Wolfgang Stolper and Paul Samuelson s paper Protection and Real Wages in Review of Economic Studies (1941). It provided a theoretical prediction that international trade widened wage inequality in developed countries such as the United States, while it reduced wage inequality in developing countries. This is because the relative wage of skilled workers increases in developed countries that export skill-intensive goods, while the relative wage of unskilled workers increases in developing countries that export unskilled-intensive goods. TABLE 1 Comparison of traditional trade theories Ricardian model Heckscher-Ohlin model Source: Compiled by the author Source of comparative advantage Technological differences Production factor One factor Distributional effects of international trade No Factor endowment Two factors Yes Japan SPOTLIGHT November / December 2017 45

TABLE 2 Trade theories versus data The Stolper-Samuelson theorem The data Feenstra and Hanson (1997) Developed country (US) Developing country (Mexico) workers decreases. TABLE 3 Three effects of offshoring on domestic workers wages The productivity effect The relative-price effect The labor-supply effect Low-skilled workers wage High-skilled workers wage No Source: Compiled by the author based on the theory of Grossman and Rossi-Hansberg (2008) Source: Compiled by the author Many empirical works have revealed that the Stolper-Samuelson theorem s prediction was inconsistent with the real world in both developed and developing countries. In developed countries like the US, the price movement of goods was inconsistent with the theory. Most economists considered that skill-biased technological change was the more plausible explanation for the rise in wage inequality. In many developing countries including Mexico, India, and China, wage inequality rises, against the prediction of the Stolper-Samuelson theorem. Inconsistency between the Stolper-Samuelson theorem and the empirical evidence strongly suggested that globalization in the form of freer international trade was not the primary source of rises in wage inequality (Table 2). Offshoring & Inequality The failure to explain the empirical facts resulted in new models which aimed to reconcile trade theory with the data. Prof. Robert Feenstra of the University of California, Davis, and Prof. Gordon Hanson of the University of California, San Diego, presented one such new model. Their 1997 paper in Journal of International Economics, Foreign Direct Investment and Relative Wages: Evidence from Mexico s Maquiladoras, presented a theoretical model that could explain the rise in wage equality in both developed and developing countries such as the US and Mexico. Their model took the possibility of foreign outsourcing into account to explain the rise in wage inequality in the US and Mexico. It featured the fact that firms in the US outsourced less skilled activities to Mexico where the outsourced activities were more skill-intensive than any other activities previously done. This type of foreign outsourcing brought about an increase in demand for more skilled workers in both the US and Mexico, resulting in the rise in wage inequality in both countries. How foreign outsourcing affect wage inequality was further examined by many subsequent studies. Prof. Gene Grossman and Prof. Esteban Rossi-Hansberg, both of Princeton University, presented a simple and general model of offshoring in their 2008 paper Trading Tasks: A Simple Theory of Offshoring in American Economic Review. They also explained their model in The Rise of Offshoring: It s Not Wine for Cloth Anymore (2006). They argued that offshoring could have three effects on wages for low-skilled workers: (1) productivity effect, (2) relative-price effect, and (3) labor-supply effect. The relative-price effect and labor-supply effect give rise to a decrease in wages for low-skilled workers. The productivity effect is important for low-skilled workers because it indicates that offshoring can increase low-skilled workers wages. This effect is caused by the mechanism that offshoring enhances firm productivity and raises demand for low-skilled workers. Because of the productivity effect, offshoring can generate gains for low-skilled workers as well as high-skilled workers. However, the sign of the overall effects on lowskilled workers wages depends on whether the positive productivity effect surpasses two negative effects: the relative-price effect and labor-supply effect (Table 3). Prof. David Hummels of Purdue University and others empirically examined the wage effects of offshoring in their paper The Wage Effects of Offshoring: Evidence from Danish Matched Worker-Firm Data which appeared in American Economic Review in 2014. They utilized the large-sized data covering the population of Danish workers and the universe of private Danish firms. They also merged their firm-worker matched data with the product-level trade data, to investigate the wage effects of offshoring. They concluded that offshoring decreased wages for the low-skilled workers and increased wages for the high-skilled workers in the case of Denmark. Their study does not imply international trade is bad for low-skilled 46 Japan SPOTLIGHT November / December 2017

workers because it also pointed out that exporting increased wages for the low-skilled workers as well as high-skilled workers. Even though international trade affects wages for both types of workers, its magnitude is relatively small. The wage elasticity of offshoring for low-skilled workers is about -0.022 and that of exporting is about 0.05. Dr. Daniel Baumgarten of the University of Munich and others studied the effects of offshoring on wages using German data. Their empirical results are shown in their paper Offshoring, Tasks, and the Skill-wage Pattern in European Economic Review (2013). They found negative effects of offshoring on wages for both low- and high-skilled workers. They also found that the effects depend on the degree of offshorability. The wage reduction due to offshoring tends to be more severe for workers whose occupational tasks are less interactive and have higher routine content. They argued that workers whose tasks were less interactive faced larger wage reductions because of a higher degree of offshorability. Dr. Avraham Ebenstein of Hebrew University of Jerusalem and others studied the case of the US in their paper Estimating the Impact of Trade and Offshoring on American Workers Using the Current Population Surveys in Review of Economics and Statistics (2014). Their analysis indicates that workers who changed their jobs due to international trade experienced real wage loss of 12 to 17 percentage points between 1983 and 2002. They, therefore, insisted that labor market frictions were not negligible. This conclusion is similar to another empirical work by Prof. David H. Autor of the Massachusetts Institute of Technology and others, Trade Adjustment: Worker-Level Evidence in Quarterly Journal of Economics (2014). Autor employed longitudinal data on individual earnings by employers and examined the impacts of import competition on earnings and employment in the US between 1992 and 2007. Their analysis revealed that worker-level adjustment costs to import shocks were significant. To summarize, there are mixed empirical results for the wage effects of offshoring. On the one hand, some studies claimed that the negative effects of trade and offshoring are negligible. On the other hand, other studies presented significantly negative effects of trade and offshoring. Grossman and Rossi-Hansberg s famous theoretical model predicts that there are both negative and positive effects of offshoring for low-skilled workers since offshoring brings about possible positive effects for low-skilled workers due to improvement of firm productivity. Whether offshoring widens wage inequality remains an unsolved question. More empirical studies are required to clarify the wage effects of offshoring. Wage & Income Inequality in Japan Studies by labor economists show us the distinctive features of the Japanese labor market. In their influential paper Wage Distribution in Japan, 1989-2003 (Canadian Journal of Economics, 2008), Prof. Ryo Kambayashi of Hitotsubashi University, Prof. Daiji Kawaguchi of the University of Tokyo, and Dr. Izumi Yokoyama of Hitotsubashi University stated that while the debate about the reason for broadened inequality is heating up, the premise of the debates that Japan has experienced widening inequality has not yet been decisively confirmed. There was a famous debate between two leading labor economists, Prof. Toshiaki Tachibanaki of Kyoto University and Prof. Fumio Ohtake of Osaka University. While Tachibanaki insisted that income inequality widened in the 1980s and 1990s, Ohtake argued that the aging of the population mechanically widened income inequality since the degree of income inequality is high among elderly people. To answer this unsettled question, in their above paper Kambayashi and the others investigated how wage distribution in Japan evolved. To do so, they employed detailed wage data from the Basic Survey on Wage Structure (1989-2003, Chingin Kozo Kihon Tokei Chosa in Japanese). They pointed out that the between-group wage inequality was declining during their sample period if the group was defined by education, experience, tenure, and firm/ establishment size. The reason for the declining trend of betweengroup wage inequality was the decline of the return to education and job tenure. The authors suggested that the increase in the supply of college-educated and long-tenured workers resulted in a lower return to education and job tenure. Their results contrast with the situation in the US where a larger return to education brought about wider wage inequality. Kawaguchi and Dr. Yuko Mori tried to answer why wage inequality has not increased in Japan unlike in the US. Their paper in Economics of Education Review (2016) pointed out that the college wage premium, i.e. wage gap between high-school graduates and college graduates, decreased in Japan between 1986 and 2008, while it increased in the US during the same period. They analyzed the micro data from the Basic Survey on Wage Structure as well as the Labor Force Survey (Roudou Ryoku Chosa in Japanese) and made a comparison between Japan and the US. They found that the number of college graduates increased more rapidly in Japan than in the US. While Prof. David Card of the University of California, Berkeley, and Prof. Thomas Lemieux of the University of British Columbia, in their famous paper in the Quarterly Journal of Economics (2001), argued that the reason for the rising college wage Japan SPOTLIGHT November / December 2017 47

premium was the slowdown in the relative supply of college graduates in the US, Kawaguchi and Mori argued that the same mechanism worked in Japan in the opposite way and that the rapid growth in the supply of college graduates could explain the decrease in the college wage premium in Japan. Globalization & Inequality in Japan Lack of adequate data has prevented trade economists from investigating how international trade affects wage inequality in Japan. Very few studies examined the case of Japan on the relationship between international trade and wage inequality. Prof. Keith Head and Prof. John Ries, both of the University of British Columbia, are well-known experts in the field of the Japanese economy because they have intensively studied Japanese trade and FDI. One of their early studies, Offshore Production and Skill Upgrading by Japanese Manufacturing Firms in Journal of International Economics (2002), investigated how Japanese firms offshore production affected onshore skill intensity. They found that an increase in foreign employment due to offshore production in low-income countries raised skill intensity in Japan. Higher demand for skilled workers can potentially increase the relative wages of skilled workers and widen wage inequality. Recently some trade economists have started studying the impacts of globalization on wage and income inequality in Japan, using new data. Prof. Masahiro Endoh of Keio University conducted the first study to examine the impact of offshoring and exports at the worker-level in Japan, in his unpublished paper entitled The Effect of Offshoring on Skill Premiums: Evidence from Japanese Matched Worker-Firm Data. He made a first set of Japanese matched employer-employee data to examine the impact of offshoring and exports. Using the instrument variable technique, his study found that offshoring and exports had significant impacts on the wages of Japanese workers. It provided evidence that offshoring had positive impacts on Japanese workers wages, while exporting had negative impacts. This result is surprising and difficult to explain. More studies are required to analyze the impacts of offshoring and exports in Japan. Region which was led by Prof. Theresa Greaney and Prof. Baybars Karacaovali, both of the University of Hawai i at Mānoa, and was mainly financed by the Japan Foundation Center for Global Partnership. The project aimed at investigating the linkages between international trade and investment, economic growth, and economic inequality in the Asia-Pacific region and consisted of economists from China, Japan, South Korea, and the US. The conferences were held at University of Hawai i at Mānoa and Keio University in 2016. The resulting research papers were included in a special issue of Journal of Asian Economics (2017). Policy implications were presented in a short paper by Greaney and Karacaovali in Journal of Economics and Political Economy (2017). In their paper, Greaney and Karacaovali concluded that relationships between international trade, foreign direct investment (FDI), economic growth and inequality are extremely complicated, so no single theory should be relied upon for policy guidance. (Photo) In the project, I focused on the remarkable feature of the Japanese labor market that temporary workers receive less wages and lower job security than permanent workers. The Labor Force Survey shows that temporary workers such as part-time workers and contingent workers account for more than one-third of the labor force as of 2011. The increase in the share of temporary workers can result in the rise in income inequality. In fact, the Japanese government regards the growth in the share of temporary workers among total workers as a major cause of rising income inequality. In the Annual Report on the Japanese Economy and Public Finance 2009, the Cabinet Office analyzed data from the Employment Structure Survey Photo: Author The Trade, Growth & Economic Inequality Project In 2016, Prof. Kozo Kiyota of Keio University, Prof. Fukunari Kimura of Keio University, and I joined the international research project Trade, Growth and Economic Inequality in the Asia-Pacific Venue for the meeting of the project on the University of Hawai i at Mānoa in January, 2016 48 Japan SPOTLIGHT November / December 2017

CHART Impacts of FDI in Asia on employment share of temporary workers 115.0 110.0 105.0 100.0 100.0 106.6 106.5 106.8 105.5 103.3 105.0 106.2 (Shugyo Kozo Kihon Chosa in Japanese) and argued that the wage income gap continues to expand and that the increase in the share of temporary workers (non-regular workers) among total workers has largely contributed to the expansion of the wage income gap between 1997 and 2007. My study in the special issue of Journal of Asian Economics, Foreign Direct Investment and Temporary Workers in Japan, investigated the relationship between Japanese firms globalization in the form of outward FDI into Asian countries and domestic growth in the temporary workforce in manufacturing industries. I used firmlevel data between 2001 and 2013 from the Basic Survey of Japanese Business Structure and Activities (Kigyo Katsudo Kihon Chosa in Japanese) and employed standard econometric techniques. In Japan, the share of temporary workers rose during the 2000s. In 2004, deregulation accelerated their rising numbers by enabling manufacturers to employ temporary workers indirectly through employment services (dispatched workers). During the sample period, Japanese firms increased vertical FDI or offshoring. Offshoring enables firms to employ workers in low-wage countries. Whether offshoring substitutes for employing temporary workers is, however, a less explored question. Using Italian firm-level data, Dr. Andrea F. Presbitero of the International Monetary Fund and others examined whether the employment share of temporary workers affected offshoring in their paper in International Economics (2015). They found that firms with higher ratios of temporary 111.5-2 -1 0 1 2 3 t FDI Starters Non-Starters (Matched: N1) Source: Tanaka (2017) in Journal of Asian Economics Non-Starters (Unmatched) workers exhibited reduced tendencies to offshore but that this relationship vanishes after controlling for endogeneity. My study focused on four industries in Japan s machinery manufacturing sector noted for vertical FDI. It particularly investigated the causal effects of vertical FDI on wages and employment shares of temporary workers (Chart). My study found that there were positive effects of vertical FDI on the wages and employment share of temporary workers one year after starting FDI but they vanished in subsequent years. Therefore, it concluded that the relationship between temporary workers and vertical FDI was complementary in the early stage of FDI and that no persistent effect of vertical FDI occurred. Offshoring might result in widening income inequality by increasing the share of low-wage temporary workers. However, my study found no evidence that FDI in Asia induced firms to increase the employment share of temporary workers. In other words, it found little evidence for the contention that vertical FDI results in greater income inequality and greater job insecurity through increasing the share of temporary workers. Conclusion Prof. Elhanan Helpman of Harvard University, in his Keynes Lecture in Economics delivered at the British Academy in 2016, summarized previous studies and concluded that international trade played an important role in increasing wage inequality, but that its cumulative effect has been modest. However, most studies in the field of international trade and wage inequality have focused on the US. The Japanese situation is very different from that of the US. First, labor economists suggested that wage inequality has not increased in Japan unlike in the US because the wage gap between high-school graduates and college graduates decreased in Japan due to increased supply of college graduates. Second, the Japanese government considered that the increase in the share of temporary workers among total employment widened income inequality. These two facts require trade economists to further investigate how globalization in the form of trade, FDI, and offshoring affect the share of temporary workers in Japan. My own studies suggest that globalization did not play any persistent role in the rise in income inequality in Japan. Ayumu Tanaka is an associate professor at Chuo University in Tokyo and research associate at the Research Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry (RIETI). He holds a Ph.D. in economics from Kyoto University. Japan SPOTLIGHT November / December 2017 49