A Dictionary Article on Axel Leijonhufvud s. On Keynesian Economics and the Economics of Keynes: A Study in Monetary Theory.

Similar documents
Figure 1.1 Output of the U.S. economy, Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 1-2

Modigliani and Keynes

Review of Michel de Vroey s A history of macroeconomics from Keynes to Lucas and beyond. New York: Cambridge University Press, 2016, 429 pp.

Alternative Explanations of How the Capitalist Economy in Which We Live Operates

1. At the completion of this course, students are expected to: 2. Define and explain the doctrine of Physiocracy and Mercantilism

IJOESS Year: 9, Vol:9, Issue: 33 SEPTEMBER 2018

Chapter 25. Rational Expectations: Implications for Policy

EC 454. Lecture 3 Prof. Dr. Durmuş Özdemir Department of Economics Yaşar University

4. Philip Cortney, The Economic Munich: The I.T.O. Charter, Inflation or Liberty, the 1929 Lesson (New York: Philosophical Library, 1949).

PAPER No. : Basic Microeconomics MODULE No. : 1, Introduction of Microeconomics

GENERAL INTRODUCTION FIRST DRAFT. In 1933 Michael Kalecki, a young self-taught economist, published in

As Joseph Stiglitz sees matters, the euro suffers from a fatal. Book Review. The Euro: How a Common Currency. Journal of FALL 2017

I would like to add my voice to the chorus in thanking President Fisher and the

Keynes Critique of Classical Economics

Economics and Reality. Harald Uhlig 2012

On the Irrelevance of Formal General Equilibrium Analysis

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

Readings in the History of Modern Macroeconomics

DECODING J. M. KEYNES' WORKS: AN ANALYSIS OF THE INTERPRETATIONS OF KEYNESIAN ECONOMICS MELINDA SIMONFFY. Senior Sophister

Which statement to you agree with most?

Introduction to New Institutional Economics: A Report Card

Thinkwell s Homeschool Economics Course Lesson Plan: 36 weeks

MACROECONOMIC POLICY AND COLLECTIVE ACTION. David Colander. June 2008 MIDDLEBURY COLLEGE ECONOMICS DISCUSSION PAPER NO

Macroeconomics and the Phillips Curve Myth by James Forder

A Comparison of the Theories of Joseph Alois Schumpeter and John. Maynard Keynes. Aubrey Poon

Axel Leijonhufvud and the Quest for Micro-foundations -- Some Reflections

Market failures. If markets "work perfectly well", governments should just play their minimal role, which is to:

Review of Roger E. Backhouse s The puzzle of modern economics: science or ideology? Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2010, 214 pp.

Systematic Policy and Forward Guidance

The Reformation in Economics

SCHOOLS OF ECONOMICS. Classical, Keynesian, & Monetary

10/7/2013 SCHOOLS OF ECONOMICS. Classical, Keynesian, & Monetary. as Neo- Classical Supply Side Trickle Down Free Trade CLASSICAL THEORY

Karl Brunner, Monetarist

The History of Macroeconomics Viewed Against the Background of the Marshall-Walras Divide

Prior to 1940, the Austrian School was known primarily for its contributions

Quotes from The Economic Consequences of Peace - (1920)

Samuelson, Keynes and the search for a general theory of economics Backhouse, Roger

Thomas Piketty Capital in the 21st Century

The General Theory after sixty years

Monetary Theory and Central Banking By Allan H. Meltzer * Carnegie Mellon University and The American Enterprise Institute

Economics Honors Exam 2009 Solutions: Macroeconomics, Questions 6-7

Dr Kalecki on Mr Keynes

The Rationale for Independent Monetary Policy

The Relationship between Real Wages and Output: Evidence from Pakistan

Teaching Macroeconomics

Unravelling the New Classical Counter Revolution

John Maynard Keynes v. Friedrich Hayek Part I: The Battle of Ideas (Commanding Heights) 2. What economic concepts did John Maynard Keynes invent?

CHAPTER 19 MARKET SYSTEMS AND NORMATIVE CLAIMS Microeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.), 2 nd Edition

New macroeconomics teaching for a new era: instability, inequality, and environment

Economics after the financial crisis: Comments

CAMBRIDGE MONETARY THOUGHT

Honors General Exam Part 1: Microeconomics (33 points) Harvard University

References: Shiller, R.J., (2000), Irrational Exuberance. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Post Walrasian Macro Policy and the Economics of Muddling Through. David Colander. August 2003 MIDDLEBURY COLLEGE ECONOMICS DISCUSSION PAPER NO.

Post-Crisis Neoliberal Resilience in Europe

2. Scope and Importance of Economics. 2.0 Introduction: Teaching of Economics

Milton Friedman's Contributions to Macroeconomics and Their Influence

Influencing Expectations in the Conduct of Monetary Policy

Volume Title: NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2000, Volume 15. Volume URL:

New Macroeconomics Teaching for a New Era: Instability, Inequality, and Environment

Rules Versus Discretion: Assessing the Debate Over the Conduct of Monetary Policy

Post-Keynesian Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Theory

1 From a historical point of view, the breaking point is related to L. Robbins s critics on the value judgments

Overview of the Austrian School theories of capital and business cycles and implications for agent-based modeling

Axel A Weber: A central banker's interest in Phillips curves

General view of the economy The less the government is involved in the economy the better it will perform.

Three Revolutions in Macroeconomics: Their Nature and Influence

Portland State University Department of Economics

Designation : Associate Professor & HOD, Deptt. Of Commerce, Economics & Management

What was lost with IS-LM* Roger E. Backhouse University of Birmingham. and. David Laidler University of Western Ontario

THE KEYNESIAN REVOLUTION

A 13-PART COURSE IN POPULAR ECONOMICS SAMPLE COURSE OUTLINE

SERIE RESEARCH memorimdn

Adam Smith and Government Intervention in the Economy Sima Siami-Namini Graduate Research Assistant and Ph.D. Student Texas Tech University

Growth in Open Economies, Schumpeterian Models

involving 58,000 foreig n students in the U.S. and 11,000 American students $1.0 billion. Third, the role of foreigners in the American economics

THE ROLE OF FINANCIAL POLICY

Mehrdad Payandeh, Internationales Gemeinschaftsrecht Summary

SOCI 423: THEORIES OF SOCIAL DEVELOPMENT

ECONOMICS AND COMPARATIVE POLITICS FORM IV

UNEMPLOYMENT, DISCOURAGED

Keynes as an Interpreter of Classical Economics

The Minimum Wage. Introduction. Impacts on Employment

Pitfalls of a Minimax Approach to Model Uncertainty

The Analytics of the Wage Effect of Immigration. George J. Borjas Harvard University September 2009

Edmond Malinvaud s Criticisms to New Classical Economics: Restoring the Rationale of the Old Keynesians Stance

Idiosyncratic reflections on economics as a science

Ricardo: real or supposed vices? A Comment on Kakarot-Handtke s paper Paolo Trabucchi, Roma Tre University, Economics Department

Charles I Plosser: A progress report on our monetary policy framework

The Relevance of Keynesian Ideas in the Current Economic Crisis Context

The economics and political economy of Milton Friedman: An old Keynesian critique

Introduction: Seven Decades of the IS-LM Model

Post Walrasian Macro Policy and the Economics of Muddling Through. David Colander. December 2003

The Two Faces of Emergence in Economics Mark Kuperberg

What have central bankers learned from modern macroeconomic theory? *

KEYNES REVOLUTION AND COUNTER- REVOLUTION

Communicating a Systematic Monetary Policy

Edexcel Economics AS-level

Running Head: POLICY MAKING PROCESS. The Policy Making Process: A Critical Review Mary B. Pennock PAPA 6214 Final Paper

Keynes and the Birth of Modern Macroeconomics

Transcription:

A Dictionary Article on Axel Leijonhufvud s On Keynesian Economics and the Economics of Keynes: A Study in Monetary Theory by Peter Howitt Brown University January 29, 2002 Draft of an article to be translated into French and published in the Dictionnaire des grandes œuvres économiques, edited by Xavier Greffe, Jérôme Lallement and Michel devroey, to be published by Éditions Dalloz.

On Keynesian Economics and the Economics of Keynes: A Study in Monetary Theory 1. Professor Leijonhufvud s book, which emerged from his PhD. Dissertation at Northwestern University, was published in 1968, a critical time in the development of macroeconomic theory. Keynesian Economics was at its zenith. Policymakers around the world had adopted it as their guide to conducting stabilization policy. American Keynesians, proudly pointing to the long economic expansion following the 1962 tax-cuts that they had advocated to close the deflationary gap, claimed that their New Economics had vanquished the business cycle. Keynesian ideas had won over all but the most willful advocates of laissez-faire, to the point where it was commonly agreed that we are all Keynesians now. Keynesian Economics dominated teaching and academic research as much as it did policy-making. The IS-LM model that Hicks and Hansen had extracted from Keynes s General Theory had become the reigning paradigm of macroeconomics. Theorists had developed choicetheoretic microfoundations for its major components - the consumption function, the demand function for investment and the demand function for money - informed by a huge volume of empirical research. The apparent success of the Keynesian research program had persuaded many that the broad outlines of macroeconomic theory were now settled, that there was nothing left for theorists to do but fill in the details. In hindsight it is easy to recognize pride before the fall. The claims of Keynesian economists were grossly inflated, and in reality there were many gaps in their research program, which were soon to be exposed. Within a few years the rational-expectations revolution would destroy the Keynesian consensus. But in 1968 it seemed to many that mainstream Keynesian economics was here to stay. Not even the most disaffected critics could see that a theoretical revolution was around the corner. Thus Milton Friedman and his followers were challenging 1

Keynesians policy views and their relative neglect of money, but not their underlying theoretical structure. Phelps, Alchian and the other contributors to the famous Phelps (1970) volume had recognized that IS-LM was in need of a stronger microfoundation, but their work was not yet widely known, and in any event they were trying to firm up the foundation of Keynesian economics, not to undermine it. 2. Leijonhufvud was one of the first to claim that mainstream Keynesian theory was in need of a fundamental reorientation. He argued that the theory of markets underlying IS-LM was fatally flawed and should be replaced. As evidence he cited the model s dependency on rigid wages. Patinkin (1948) had established that there always exists some hypothetical level of wages and prices low enough to generate a full-employment level of aggregate demand, even if the interestelasticity of aggregate demand is zero and the economy is in a liquidity trap. Orthodox Keynesianism (which at the time attributed little importance to price-level stickiness) maintained that involuntary unemployment is entirely attributable to a rigidity that prevents the wage rate from falling to that hypothetical level. Leijonhufvud pointed out that such a theory cannot explain how a free-market economic system could malfunction the way it did in many countries during the Great Depression, because the Depression had been accompanied not by rigid wages but by an unprecedented wage deflation. Something other than wage rigidity must have been involved, something that orthodox Keynesianism did not take into account. Actual market forces do not work the way IS-LM presumes. Specifically, he argued that wage and price adjustment, which economists generally portray as stabilizing market forces, can sometimes be destabilizing, and that there are other market forces, which are usually ignored in macro theory, that are destabilizing. Otherwise the 2

massive wage adjustments that took place during the Depression would have restored full employment rather than leading to an escalation of unemployment. Leijonhufvud proposed a radical reform of macroeconomic theory that would focus more clearly on the adjustment processes of actual economies. The IS-LM model is essentially a walrasian general equilibrium model that has been tampered with by preventing the money wage rate from adjusting to its market-clearing value. But walrasian general equilibrium theory is illsuited for studying the problems of depression and involuntary unemployment, or for addressing the question of whether market forces can be relied on to restore equilibrium. This is because walrasian theory was designed specifically to study ideal states of perfect coordination, states in which all markets are in equilibrium and the concept of involuntary unemployment is meaningless. All the behavioral assumptions of the theory are based on the presumption that markets will always clear. It contains nothing to represent the market forces that might drive the system to such a coordinated state, other than an unconvincing story about a mysterious auctioneer. Moreover, to assume that the auctioneer is prevented from adjusting one of the prices in the system (the wage rate) is to contradict the rest of the model. Instead of this walrasian approach, Leijonhufvud proposed what he called a cybernetic approach, one with no presumption that the system is in an equilibrium state. Such an approach would model the economy as an algorithm that determines how the state evolves from any given initial position. The state includes the transactors initial information, beliefs, expectations, established trading relationships (especially in the labor market), endowments, debts and other contractual obligations, financial and real assets, and so forth. The approach would specify the set of possible actions that each transactor could undertake in a given situation, and behavioral rules for choosing among them. It would also specify the institutional framework within which exchange and production take place, and that framework would imply outcome functions 3

determining what happens given any set of actions selected, in any given situation. Included among those outcomes would be changes in the variables defining the state of the system. According to the cybernetic approach an economy, like biological evolution or any other algorithm, operates myopically, with no long-run goal. It constitutes a dynamical system whose behavior over time can be studied regardless of whether or not it approaches any particular reference point. Like many other algorithms it might exhibit a strong attraction to certain reference points, but there will be circumstances under which it will not converge, or will converge slowly or non-monotonically. The central question Leijonhufvud was trying to get the profession to address was how, and under what circumstances, the algorithm of a decentralized market economy might exhibit attraction to a state of full employment equilibrium. Leijonhufvud also argued that in broad outline Keynes s own theory was a cybernetic one. Hence the title of the book. Keynesian economics, as embodied in the rigid-wage IS-LM model, is not the Economics of Keynes. On the contrary the view that wage rigidity is the cause of unemployment was the hallmark of the classical tradition, running from Thornton through Marshall, that Keynes was trying to refute. Thus on page 27 of the General Theory Keynes states that the classical theory has been accustomed to rest the supposedly self-adjusting character of the economic system on an assumed fluidity of money-wages; and, when there is rigidity, to lay on this rigidity the blame of unemployment. In the famous passage (on page 16) where he ridiculed the classical economists as being like Euclidean geometers in a non-euclidean world who rebuke their lines for not keeping straight, he was referring to their conclusion, perfectly logical on their assumption, that apparent unemployment (apart from the admitted exceptions) must be due at bottom to a refusal by the unemployed to accept a reward which corresponds to their marginal productivity. 4

Keynes of course believed that as a factual matter wages were indeed not very flexible, and had much to say about why that is the case. But on the whole he believed that that was a good thing because, as he argued in Chapter 19 of the General Theory, wage and price adjustment, if given full rein, would probably lead a depressed economy even further into depression. More specifically, a general decrease in wages and prices would produce debt deflation (to use Fisher s term, which Keynes did not), destabilizing expectations of further price decreases, and adverse distributional effects, all of which would serve to amplify the deficiency of aggregate demand that was the root cause of the problem. Keynes was technically not up to the challenge of convincingly demonstrating this alleged failure of market forces to cure mass unemployment. The best he could do was deploy a static equilibrium model to address what is essentially a dynamic question. His followers understandably decided to skip the problematical dynamic analysis of Chapter 19 and focus on the relatively tractable static IS-LM model. Since it was commonly agreed that wages were far from perfectly flexible, why not assume that they are fixed? Leijonhufvud argued that we should take Keynes more seriously than this, making use of more up-to-date analytical concepts and tools than Keynes had at his disposal in the 1930s. One such concept was Clower s (1965) dual decision hypothesis. Clower argued that when an economic system is not in equilibrium people formulate their market demands differently than in walrasian theory. Specifically, they respond not just to changes in the prices they face but also in the quantities they are able to buy and sell in various markets. Thus excess supply in one market can lead frustrated sellers to curtail their demands in other markets, causing the excess supply to spread, in what Leijonhufvud called an income-constrained process, much like Keynes s multiplier process. The algorithm of an actual economy should take into account that this process will tend to amplify deviations from full employment equilibrium rather than 5

dampening them, so that even if wage and price adjustment are stabilizing forces that tend to counteract deviations, the overall behavior of the system may exhibit a sustained cumulative rise in unemployment following a drop in aggregate demand. Alchian s (1970) analysis of price formation with costly information (which was available to Leijonhufvud in working-paper form at the time) was another important component of the argument. Alchian argued that a transactor trying to sell something will try to gather information about potential trading opportunities, and this takes time. In the process he will not sell to the first bidder he finds. Instead he will formulate a reservation price and wait until either he finds someone willing to pay that price or the experience of being unable to find such a person persuades him to lower the price. Thus even in the absence of unexplained institutional rigidities, wages will adjust only gradually over time following a drop in aggregate demand, giving scope for Clower s deviation-amplifying process to kick in before unemployed workers have acquired enough information to induce them to moderate their wage demands. More generally, getting to an equilibrium state is largely a question of having people acquire mutually consistent information and beliefs about trading opportunities. Clower and Alchian had provided important clues as to how the algorithm of a market economy affects prices and quantities when information and beliefs are not fully coordinated. The task of macroeconomists should be to fill in the rest of the algorithm s details. This was the book s central message, at least as interpreted by those who were inspired by it, although it contains much else of value relating to various controversies in the Keynesian literature, to monetary policy, and especially to intertemporal coordination failures in which people s expectations about long-term interest rates and about the marginal efficiency of capital are mutually incompatible. 6

3. The book was an instant success, and was widely hailed as an intellectual tour de force. Critics of Keynesian economics, especially Milton Friedman, praised its breadth of vision and its devastating attack on IS-LM. Together with Clower s contribution, it inspired young economists with no stake in IS-LM to start developing a disequilibrium approach to macroeconomics, of which the most cited work was the Barro-Grossman (1971) article. It is remarkable that a book without a single equation could have such a major influence on a discipline dominated by mathematical modeling. More generally, the book introduced the economics of information into macroeconomic theory. Shortly after its appearance the Phelps volume was published, containing not only Alchian s paper but also several other contributions studying the disequilibrium dynamics of economies with costly information. One of those contributions was Phelps s introduction, in which he outlined the conceptual framework of the island parable. In this parable people are located on informationally isolated islands, each with its own local auctioneer, so that if a fall in aggregate demand causes a downward shift in the demand for labor, workers must travel to another island before getting any signal about whether this is a purely local relative-price effect, in response to which they might prefer to relocate and sell elsewhere, or a global fall in nominal prices in response to which, in the absence of money illusion, they would want to continue trading as before. Phelps and company were laying the foundation for a cybernetic approach much like the one Leijonhufvud had been advocating. The island parable was the starting point of Robert Lucas (1972), who added to it the seemingly natural and innocuous assumption of rational expectations. The result was a rationalexpectations revolution that quickly overthrew IS-LM as the dominant paradigm in macroeconomics. Soon the leading journals were soon filled with search theory, the economics of information, and various other elements of Leijonhufvud s proposed research agenda. 7

Leijonhufvud s book was less successful as a contribution to the history of economic thought than as a contribution to positive theory. Several critics complained that its interpretation of Keynes was based on questionable textual evidence, that something much like IS-LM can indeed be found in the General Theory, and that Keynes actually took an equilibrium approach to modeling the market for aggregate output. Leijonhufvud defended himself against these charges, but he also insisted, as he had in the book, that his primary aim had not been to write doctrinal history but to present a vision of an alternative approach to macro theory. In that sense the book was indeed a success. 4. Leijonhufvud s influence on the course of macroeconomic theory was long-lasting, in the sense that IS-LM has never recovered its position in macro theory. In other ways, however, the book s lasting influence has been almost negligible. For although IS-LM has been largely displaced from the academic journals it continues to be widely used in the more practical realms of policy-making and professional forecasting, and to form the basis of most undergraduate teaching of macroeconomics. Leijonhufvud may have helped persuade a generation of theorists that the foundations of IS-LM are too flimsy to take the model seriously, but clearly he has not persuaded the people that use it for earning a living. In addition, the rational-expectations revolution that Lucas started when he adopted the island parable has taken macroeconomics on a far different course than Leijonhufvud was advocating. For it displaced not only IS-LM but also the Economics of Keynes. Instead of leading to further work on disequilibrium adjustment mechanisms it induced the leaders of disequilibrium analysis to abandon their research program. Soon the journals were filled with macro models postulating that the economy is always in a state of rational-expectations equilibrium, with no reference to market forces that might bring about such a state. 8

To some extent the rise of new-classical economics and the waning popularity of all things related to Keynes can be attributed to the neo-conservative movement that gained force throughout the western world in the 1970s. It became less fashionable to discuss the problematical aspects of capitalism, and more acceptable to sweep the difficulties of disequilibrium adjustment under the rug. But in retrospect it is clear that there were also internal scientific reasons for the disappearance of the cybernetic approach to macroeconomics. Lucas had been able to account for the long-run neutrality of money as well as its short-run nonneutrality, and he had also provided a compelling research agenda free from the arbitrariness of mechanical expectational assumptions. Thus it is hardly surprising that young economists were attracted en masse to his agenda regardless of their ideological orientation. Moreover, it was not apparent that there was any conflict between rational expectations and Keynesian economics. Soon even mainstream Keynesians learned how to include the assumption into their models, while retaining the key assumption of wage-rigidity, at no risk to their core belief in the need for activist stabilization policy. As it turns out, however, the assumption of rational expectations is not nearly as innocuous as it first seemed. That is, rather than being just an assumption of individual rationality, it amounts to assuming that the economic system is always in a state of perfect coordination, in the sense that everyone s beliefs are mutually compatible. The question of how the algorithm of an actual economic system might lead it to such a state from an arbitrary initial state cannot be addressed in such a framework because it does not allow the system to begin anywhere else. Thus the rational-expectations revolution, which started from a parable that nicely embodies Leijonhufvud s cybernetic vision, ended up taking the central issue Leijonhufvud was addressing almost completely out of the realm of professional discourse. 9

The rational-expectations approach is as dominant in theoretical macroeconomics today as IS-LM was in 1968. However, recent developments in the theory of disequilibrium learning in macroeconomics (see Sargent, 1993; and Evans and Honkapohja, 2001) show that at least some macroeconomists are still aware of the problems that Leijonhufvud raised, and are following the cybernetic approach that is antithetical to rational expectations. Moreover, no one who remembers how quickly the reigning orthodoxy fell after 1968 can rationally expect that the current orthodoxy is here to stay. Peter Howitt Brown University Providence, Rhode Island 10

BIBLIOGRAPHY Barro, R., and H. Grossman, A General Disequilibrium Model of Income and Employment, American Economic Review, 61, March, pp. 82-93. Clower, R. (1965), The Keynesian Counter-revolution: A Theoretical Appraisal in F. Hahn and F. Brechling (eds.) The Theory of Interest Rates, London: Macmillan. Evans, G., and S. Honkapohja (2001) Learning and Expectations in Macroeconomics, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Leijonhufvud, A. (1968), On Keynesian Economics and the Economics of Keynes: A Study in Monetary Theory, New York: Oxford University Press. Lucas, R. (1972), Expectations and the Neutrality of Money, Journal of Economic Theory, 4, April, pp. 103-24. Patinkin, D. (1948), Price Flexibility and Full Employment, American Economic Review, 38, September, pp. 543-64. Phelps, E. et al. (1970), Microeconomic Foundations of Employment and Inflation Theory, New York: Norton. Sargent, T. (1993), Bounded Rationality in Macroeconomics, Oxford: Clarendon Press. 11