Direction of trade and wage inequality

Similar documents
ARTNeT Trade Economists Conference Trade in the Asian century - delivering on the promise of economic prosperity rd September 2014

What Explains the Job Creating Potential of Industrialisation in the Developing World? Kunal Sen Global Development Institute, University of

POLICY OPTIONS AND CHALLENGES FOR DEVELOPING ASIA PERSPECTIVES FROM THE IMF AND ASIA APRIL 19-20, 2007 TOKYO

Skill Classification Does Matter: Estimating the Relationship Between Trade Flows and Wage Inequality

Trade, Technology, and Institutions: How Do They Affect Wage Inequality? Evidence from Indian Manufacturing. Amit Sadhukhan 1.

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

Income Inequality and Trade Protection

OCCUPATIONAL wage inequality has increased in many developed countries in the last

Gendered Employment Data for Global CGE Modeling

Research Report. How Does Trade Liberalization Affect Racial and Gender Identity in Employment? Evidence from PostApartheid South Africa

Globalization and Poverty Forthcoming, University of

Trade Policy, Agreements and Taxation of Multinationals

The Effect of Globalization on Educational Attainment

An Empirical Analysis of Pakistan s Bilateral Trade: A Gravity Model Approach

Quantitative Analysis of Migration and Development in South Asia

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation

Trade, Employment and Inclusive Growth in Asia. Douglas H. Brooks Jakarta, Indonesia 10 December 2012

Introduction Alexandre Guilherme & W. John Morgan Published online: 26 Aug 2014.

Determinants of International Migration

CERDI, Etudes et Documents, E

Volume 36, Issue 1. Impact of remittances on poverty: an analysis of data from a set of developing countries

Rising Income Inequality in Asia

The Multidimensional Financial Inclusion MIFI 1

Trade Liberalization and Inequality: Re-examining Theory and Empirical Evidence

International Trade and Inequality

Asian Development Bank Institute. ADBI Working Paper Series INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND INEQUALITY. Shujiro Urata and Dionisius A.

How does international trade affect household welfare?

Assessing Barriers to Trade in Education Services in Developing ESCAP Countries: An Empirical Exercise WTO/ARTNeT Short-term Research Project

Development, Politics, and Inequality in Latin America and East Asia

Online publication date: 21 July 2010 PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE

HOW STRATIFIED IS THE WORLD? Openness and Development

REMITTANCES, POVERTY AND INEQUALITY

The Role of Internet Adoption on Trade within ASEAN Countries plus People s Republic of China

The globalization of inequality

title, Routledge, September 2008: 234x156:

The Effect of International Trade on Wages of Skilled and Unskilled Workers: Evidence from Brazil

Corruption and inequality of wealth amongst the very rich

A Panel Data Analysis of FDI, Trade Openness, and Liberalization on Economic Growth of the ASEAN-5

Do international migration and remittances reduce poverty in developing countries?

Trade led Growth in Times of Crisis Asia Pacific Trade Economists Conference 2 3 November 2009, Bangkok. Session 10

GLOBALIZATION AND THE GENDER WAGE GAP

Chapter 5: Internationalization & Industrialization

The construction sector and economic development: the Bon curve

FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT AND ECONOMIC GROWTH IN ASIA: ANALYSIS FOR ADVANCED ECONOMIES, EMERGING MARKETS &DEVELOPING ECONOMIES

Inequality in Asia: Trends, Drivers and Policy Implications

Explaining Asian Outward FDI

The Conference Board Total Economy Database Summary Tables November 2016

Manuscript ID: EER-D Public spending and growth: the role of government accountability. Online Appendix

The International Investment Index Report IIRC, Wuhan University

Earnings Inequality, Educational Attainment and Rates of Returns to Education after Mexico`s Economic Reforms

Skill classi cation does matter: estimating the relationship between trade ows and wage inequality

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach

Chapter 11. Trade Policy in Developing Countries

CHAPTER 2 LITERATURE REVIEWS

ANALYSIS OF THE EFFECT OF REMITTANCES ON ECONOMIC GROWTH USING PATH ANALYSIS ABSTRACT

THE EFFECT OF GLOBALIZATION ON INCOME INEQUALITY IN ASEAN-5

Trade, foreign investment, and wage inequality in developing countries

Trade and Inequality: From Theory to Estimation

Was Kuznets right? New evidence on the relationship between structural transformation and inequality

GENDER EQUALITY IN THE LABOUR MARKET AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT

Eugene A. Paoline III a & William Terrill b a Department of Criminal Justice, University of Central Florida, Hall, East Lansing, MI, 48824, USA

Workers Remittances. and International Risk-Sharing

BBVA EAGLEs. Emerging And Growth Leading Economies Economic Outlook. Annual Report 2014 Cross-Country Emerging Markets, BBVA Research March 2014

The impact of Chinese import competition on the local structure of employment and wages in France

APPENDIX 1: MEASURES OF CAPITALISM AND POLITICAL FREEDOM

Remittances and the Brain Drain: Evidence from Microdata for Sub-Saharan Africa

SEWING SUCCESS: EMPLOYMENT AND WAGES OF THE END OF THE MULTI- FIBRE ARRANGEMENT

Volume 30, Issue 1. Corruption and financial sector performance: A cross-country analysis

The interaction effect of economic freedom and democracy on corruption: A panel cross-country analysis

Market Briefing: Trade-Weighted Dollar

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US

Exploring relations between Governance, Trust and Well-being

CENTRO STUDI LUCA D AGLIANO DEVELOPMENT STUDIES WORKING PAPERS N April Export Growth and Firm Survival

Labor versus capital in trade-policy: The role of ideology and inequality

Impact of Globalization on Income Inequality in Selected Asian Countries

Round 1. This House would ban the use of zero-hour contracts. Proposition v. Opposition

Trade Liberalization and Wage Inequality in India: A Mandated Wage Equation Approach

Democracy and Changes in Income Inequality

Trends in inequality worldwide (Gini coefficients)

Income and Population Growth

Economic Freedom and Economic Performance: The Case MENA Countries

Total dimensions are the total world endowments of labor and capital.

Natural resources, electoral behaviour and social spending in Latin America

Part 1: The Global Gender Gap and its Implications

DISCUSSION PAPERS IN ECONOMICS

Researching structural change & inclusive growth

Inclusive global growth: a framework to think about the post-2015 agenda

PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE. Full terms and conditions of use:

TRADE IN SERVICES AND INCOME INEQUALITY IN DEVELOPING ECONOMIES

Growth and Poverty Reduction: An Empirical Analysis Nanak Kakwani

The Political Economy of Public Policy

2018 Social Progress Index

*

INCLUSIVE GROWTH AND POLICIES: THE ASIAN EXPERIENCE. Thangavel Palanivel Chief Economist for Asia-Pacific UNDP, New York

HUMAN RESOURCES IN R&D

Differences Lead to Differences: Diversity and Income Inequality Across Countries

Does One Law Fit All? Cross-Country Evidence on Okun s Law

FOREIGN FIRMS AND INDONESIAN MANUFACTURING WAGES: AN ANALYSIS WITH PANEL DATA

The effect of FDI on Inequality-adjusted HDI (IHDI) in Asian countries

Charting Cambodia s Economy, 1H 2017

Transcription:

This article was downloaded by: [California State University Fullerton], [Sherif Khalifa] On: 15 May 2014, At: 17:25 Publisher: Routledge Informa Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954 Registered office: Mortimer House, 37-41 Mortimer Street, London W1T 3JH, UK Applied Economics Letters Publication details, including instructions for authors and subscription information: http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/rael20 Direction of trade and wage inequality Sherif Khalifa a a Department of Economics, Steven G. Mihaylo College of Business and Economics, California State University, Fullerton, CA 92834, USA Published online: 03 Apr 2014. To cite this article: Sherif Khalifa (2014): Direction of trade and wage inequality, Applied Economics Letters, DOI: 10.1080/13504851.2014.896976 To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/13504851.2014.896976 PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE Taylor & Francis makes every effort to ensure the accuracy of all the information (the Content ) contained in the publications on our platform. However, Taylor & Francis, our agents, and our licensors make no representations or warranties whatsoever as to the accuracy, completeness, or suitability for any purpose of the Content. Any opinions and views expressed in this publication are the opinions and views of the authors, and are not the views of or endorsed by Taylor & Francis. The accuracy of the Content should not be relied upon and should be independently verified with primary sources of information. Taylor and Francis shall not be liable for any losses, actions, claims, proceedings, demands, costs, expenses, damages, and other liabilities whatsoever or howsoever caused arising directly or indirectly in connection with, in relation to or arising out of the use of the Content. This article may be used for research, teaching, and private study purposes. Any substantial or systematic reproduction, redistribution, reselling, loan, sub-licensing, systematic supply, or distribution in any form to anyone is expressly forbidden. Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at http:// www.tandfonline.com/page/terms-and-conditions

Applied Economics Letters, 2014 http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/13504851.2014.896976 Direction of trade and wage inequality Sherif Khalifa Department of Economics, Steven G. Mihaylo College of Business and Economics, California State University, Fullerton, CA 92834, USA E-mail: skhalifa@fullerton.edu Contrary to the predictions of the 2 2 2 Heckscher Ohlin model, empirical evidence shows that the skill premium increased in some developing countries and decreased in others after trade liberalization. Khalifa (2014) attempts to reconcile the empirical evidence with the theoretical predictions by introducing a theoretical set-up that includes the additional aspect of South South trade. The model shows that South South trade openness can cause the skill premium to increase in the Southern country that is relatively more skill abundant, and to decrease in the Southern country that is relatively less skill abundant. This article introduces an empirical analysis to test the theoretical predictions of Khalifa (2014) using threshold estimation techniques introduced by Hansen (1999). The results suggest the presence of a statistically significant skill abundance threshold, below which the estimate of the coefficient of the relationship between South South trade openness and wage inequality is negative, and above which the point estimate is positive. Keywords: trade liberalization; wage inequality JEL Classification: F16; J31; O34 I. Introduction The 2 2 2 Heckscher Ohlin model predicts that trade openness induces countries to export the good that intensively uses the relatively abundant factor of production, and import the good that intensively uses the relatively scarce factor of production. Accordingly, skill abundant developed countries are expected to export the good that intensively uses skilled workers. This contributes to an increase in the relative price of the skilled-intensive good, a rise in the relative demand for skilled workers and consequently an increase in the skill premium. While skill scarce developing countries are expected to export the good that intensively uses unskilled workers. This contributes to an increase in the relative price of the unskilled-intensive good, a rise in the relative demand for unskilled workers and consequently a decrease in the skill premium. Theoretical predictions, however, are not supported by empirical evidence. Some developing countries experienced an increase in the skill premium, while others witnessed a decline after trade liberalization. The evidence is documented by Freeman and Oostendorp (2000), Hanson and Harrison (1995), Robbins (1996), Wood (1997) and Goldberg and Pavcnik (2004). Khalifa (2014) attempts to reconcile the empirical evidence with the theoretical predictions by introducing a model where the direction of trade can produce the observed patterns of skill premia in the South. The theoretical set-up developed includes the additional aspect of South South trade. The paper shows that South South trade openness can cause the skill premium to increase in the Southern country that is relatively more skill abundant, and to decrease in the Southern country that is relatively less skill abundant. 2014 Taylor & Francis 1

2 S. Khalifa This article introduces an empirical analysis to test the theoretical predictions of Khalifa (2014) using threshold estimation techniques introduced by Hansen (1999). The results suggest the presence of a statistically significant skill abundance threshold, below which the estimate of the coefficient of the relationship between South South trade openness and wage inequality is negative, and above which the point estimate is positive. This implies that South countries with a relatively low level of skill abundance experience a decrease in the skill premium after trade openness with other South countries, while South countries with a relatively high level of skill abundance experience an increase in the skill premium after trade openness with other South countries. Thus, the empirical analysis provides evidence that supports the theoretical conclusion. The remainder of the article is organized as follows: Section II includes the data description, Section III includes the empirical estimation and Section IV concludes. References, tables and figures are included thereafter. II. Data The estimation uses a balanced panel of annual data that covers the period from 1980 to 2000 for 25 developing countries, namely Algeria, Bangladesh, Bolivia, Cameroon, Chile, Colombia, Cyprus, Ecuador, Hong Kong, Hungary, India, Indonesia, Israel, Jordan, Korea, Malawi, Malaysia, Mauritius, Philippines, Poland, Senegal, Singapore, Sri Lanka, Uruguay and Zimbabwe. The variables used in the estimation are the skill premium, skill abundance, real GDP per capita and trade. The skill premium or wage inequality data set used is compiled by the University of Texas Inequality Project. 8 >< Premium it ¼ >: The original data comes from United Nations Industrial Development Organization (UNIDO) statistics, which provide average manufacturing pay by industry. From these average industrial wages, a Theil index of inequality is calculated and used in this analysis as a measure of wage inequality. Detailed definition of this variable is included in Galbraith and Kum (2005). As a proxy for the relative supply of skilled labour, we follow Forbes (2001) in using the average years of total education in the population aged over 15 years, as reported in Barro and Lee International Data on Educational Attainment. As the data is available only for the years 1980, 1985, 1990, 1995 and 2000, we use linear interpolation to derive the years-in-between. The data for real GDP per capita (Laspeyres) is extracted from the Penn World Tables 6.3, which is obtained by adding up consumption, investment, government and exports, and subtracting imports in any given year. The given year components are obtained by extrapolating the 1996 values in international dollars from the Geary aggregation using national growth rates. The data for trade flows, and the direction of trade, is extracted from the UN COMTRADE which is the pseudonym for the United Nations Commodity Trade Statistics Database. Reporter countries provide the United Nations Statistics Division with their annual international trade statistics data detailed by commodities and partner countries. Commodity values are converted from national currency into US dollars using exchange rates supplied by the reporter countries. The data that we use are the Standard International Trade Classification (SITC) rev.2. III. Estimation In this section, the proposition that trade openness between developing countries at different levels of skill abundance can cause some countries to experience a decrease in the skill premium, while others to experience an increase in the skill premium is tested empirically using threshold estimation techniques developed in Hansen (1999). The threshold estimation allows for an endogenous classification between countries based on the differences in their skill abundance. The threshold estimation model is given by μ i þ β 1 SouthSouth it þ f 1 SouthNorth it þ f 2 RGDP it þ f 3 Abundance it þ e it ifabundance it σ μ i þ β 2 SouthSouth it þ f 1 SouthNorth it þ f 2 RGDP it þ f 3 Abundance it þ e it ifabundance it > σ where the subscript i indexes the country and the subscript t indexes time. The dependent variable Premium it denotes the skill premium in country i in year t. The variable SouthSouth it is the share of South South trade out of total trade in country i in year t. Thevariable SouthNorth it is the share of South North trade out of total trade in country i in year t. The threshold variable Abundance it is a measure of skill abundance in country i in year t. The variable RGDP it denotes real GDP per capita in country i in year t and is added to control for macroeconomic developments which might impact (1)

Trade and inequality 3 wage inequality. The trade data is used instead of tariff data, as the analysis distinguishes between South South trade and South North trade. This distinction is made clear with trade data, but not with tariff data. In this context, we follow Forbes (2001, p. 180) in using trade flow data rather than tariffs or price data due to the difficulty in obtaining accurate measures of prices across countries and time. In this context, the observations are divided into two regimes depending on whether the threshold variable Abundance it is smaller or larger than the threshold σ. The regimes are distinguished by differing regression slopes, β 1 and β 2. Therefore, the threshold regression model allows the level of skill abundance to determine the existence and significance of a threshold level in the relationship between South South trade and wage inequality rather than imposing a priori an arbitrary classification scheme. The threshold skill abundance determines whether the coefficient on South South trade openness is positive or negative. According to the predictions of the model, the coefficient β 1 is expected to be negative, while the coefficient β 2 is expected to be positive. As in Hansen (1999), another way of writing the equation of interest is Premium it ¼ μ i þ β 1 SouthSouth it IðAbundance it σþ þ β 2 SouthSouth it IðAbundance it > σþ þ f 1 SouthNorth it þ f 2 RGDP it þ f 3 Abundance it þ e it (2) where I ðþis : the indicator function. A balanced panel annual data is used for 25 developing countries and cover the period from 1980 to 2000. Summary statistics of the variables used in the estimation are provided in Table 1. To determine the number of thresholds, the model is estimated by least squares allowing for zero, one, two and three thresholds. There is evidence that there are two thresholds in the regression relationship. For the remainder of the analysis, we work with the double threshold model as follows Premium it ¼ μ i þ β 1 SouthSouth it IðAbundance it σ 1 Þ þ β 2 SouthSouth it Iðσ 1 < Abundance it σ 2 Þ þ β 3 SouthSouth it Iðσ 2 < Abundance it Þ þ f 1 SouthNorth it þ f 2 RGDP it þ f 3 Abundance it þ e it (3) The point estimates of the two thresholds are 3:311120 and 6:236180, and their asymptotic 99% confidence intervals Likelihood Ratio 20 18 16 14 12 10 8 6 4 2 0 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 Second Theshold Parameter Fig. 1. Confidence interval construction in double threshold model (second threshold parameter) Likelihood Ratio 35 30 25 20 15 10 5 0 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 First Threshold Parameter Fig. 2. Confidence interval construction in double threshold model (first threshold parameter) Table 1. Summary statistics Minimum 25% quantile Median 75% quantile Maximum Premium it 0.003600 0.029700 0.049700 0.073700 0.278200 RGDP it 824.165236 2668.607781 5178.874354 10432.726030 35 792.282790 SouthSouth it 0.099401 0.277659 0.366735 0.502009 0.704429 Abundance it 2.246700 4.768400 6.877080 8.293260 11.200600

4 S. Khalifa Table 2. Regression estimates Regressor Coefficient estimate OLS SE White SE RGDP it 0.000001 0.000000 0.000000 Abundance it 0.013752 0.001809 0.002204 SouthNorth it 0.004883 0.000000 0.016087 SouthSouth it I(Abundance it 3.311120) 0.002930 0.000000 0.009717 SouthSouth it I(3.311120 < Abundance it 6.236180) 0.041992 0.000000 0.005694 SouthSouth it I(Abundance it > 6.236180) 0.014648 0.000000 0.005524 are ½2:700200; 3:766260Š and ½6:180420; 6:473540Š, respectively. More information can be learned from plots of the concentrated likelihood ratio function displayed in Figs 1 and 2. To examine the first-step likelihood ratio function, we see that the first-step threshold estimate is the point where the likelihood function equals zero, which occurs at σ 1 ¼ 3:311120. Figure 2 shows the second threshold at σ 2 ¼ 6:236180. The thresholds determine the average years of total education in the population aged over 15 years. This allows the comparison between countries below and above these threshold average years of education in terms of the response of their skill premium to trade openness. The regression slope estimates, conventional OLS SEs and white-correlated SEs are reported in Table 2. All the coefficient estimates are strongly significant with conventional OLS and white SEs. Real GDP does not have a significant effect on wage inequality. Skill abundance has apositiveimpactonwageinequalitywithacoefficient of almost 0:013752. South North trade has a negative impact on wage inequality, with a coefficient of 0:004883. The estimates of primary interest are those on South South trade openness. South South trade openness has a negative impact on wage inequality with a coefficient of 0:002930, if skill abundance is below the first threshold skill abundance. On the other hand, South South trade openness has a positive impact on wage inequality if skill abundance is between the first and the second thresholds, with a coefficient of 0:041992. Above the second threshold skill abundance, the point estimate is insignificant. This can be explained as the countries with a high level of skill abundance are close to North countries in terms of educational attainment. IV. Conclusion This article introduces an empirical analysis to test the theoretical predictions of Khalifa (2014) using threshold estimation techniques introduced by Hansen (1999). The results suggest the presence of a statistically significant skill abundance threshold, below which the estimate of the coefficient of the relationship between South South trade openness and wage inequality is negative, and above which the point estimate is positive. This implies that South countries with a relatively low level of skill abundance experience a decrease in the skill premium after trade openness with other South countries, while South countries with a relatively high level of skill abundance experience an increase in the skill premium after trade openness with other South countries. Acknowledgement I thank Firat Demir and Sherine El Hag. Remaining errors are my own. References Forbes, K. (2001) Skill classification does matter: estimating the relationship between trade flows and wage inequality, The Journal of International Trade & Economic Development, 10, 175 209. doi:10.1080/09638190110039046 Freeman, R. and Oostendorp, R. (2000) Wages around the world: pay across occupations and countries, NBER Working Paper 8058. Galbraith, J. and Kum, H. (2005) Estimating the inequality of household incomes: a statistical approach to the creation of a dense and consistent global data set, Review of Income and Wealth, 51, 115 43. Goldberg, P. and Pavcnik, N. (2004) Trade, inequality and poverty: what do we know? Evidence from recent trade liberalization episodes in developing countries, NBER Working Paper No. 10593. Hansen, B. (1999) Threshold effects in non-dynamic panels: estimation, testing, and inference, Journal of Econometrics, 93, 345 68. doi:10.1016/s0304-4076(99) 00025-1 Hanson, G. and Harrison, A. (1995) Trade, technology and wage inequality, NBER Working Paper 5110. Khalifa, S. (2014) South-South Trade and Skill Premia, Manuscript, California State University, Fullerton, CA. Robbins, D. (1996) Evidence on trade and wages in the developing world, OECD Development Centre Working Paper No. 119. Wood, A. (1997) Openness and wage inequality in developing countries: the Latin American challenge to East Asian conventional wisdom, The World Bank Economic Review, 11, 33 57. doi:10.1093/wber/11.1.33