Poverty, Inequality and Growth: Debates, Theories and Evidence

Similar documents
A poverty-inequality trade off?

Lecture 2: Poverty, Inequality and Growth: Debates, Concepts and Evidence

Inequality is Bad for the Poor. Martin Ravallion * Development Research Group, World Bank 1818 H Street NW, Washington DC

Growth, Inequality and Poverty: Looking Beyond Averages

Is Global Inequality Really Falling?

There is a seemingly widespread view that inequality should not be a concern

Poverty, growth and inequality

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

CHAPTER 2 LITERATURE REVIEWS

Economic Growth and Poverty Alleviation in Russia: Should We Take Inequality into Consideration?

Interrelationship between Growth, Inequality, and Poverty: The Asian Experience

China s (Uneven) Progress Against Poverty. Martin Ravallion and Shaohua Chen Development Research Group, World Bank

Growth, Inequality and Poverty: Looking Beyond Averages

How Have the World s Poorest Fared since the Early 1980s?

More Relatively-Poor People in a Less Absolutely-Poor World

The Poverty-Growth-Inequality Triangle

Have We Already Met the Millennium Development Goal for Poverty?

Application of PPP exchange rates for the measurement and analysis of regional and global inequality and poverty

Beyond Gini: Income Distribution and Economic Development. Pushan Dutt INSEAD, Corresponding author

Poverty and Inequality

A Rural Perspective on Inequality, Poverty and Policies

Competing Concepts of Inequality in the Globalization Debate

Poverty and inequality: Unequal challenges ahead

L8: Inequality, Poverty and Development: The Evidence

The debate on globalization, poverty and. inequality: why measurement matters

Poverty, Income Inequality, and Growth in Pakistan: A Pooled Regression Analysis

Does Inequality Matter for Poverty Reduction? Evidence from Pakistan s Poverty Trends

Growth and Poverty Reduction: An Empirical Analysis Nanak Kakwani

Competing Concepts of Inequality in the Globalization Debate

Asian Development Bank Institute. ADBI Working Paper Series. Income Distributions, Inequality, and Poverty in Asia,

How Much Should We Care About Changing Income Inequality in the Course of Economic Growth?

ERD. Working Paper. No. Interrelationship between Growth, Inequality, and Poverty: The Asian Experience. Hyun H. Son ECONOMICS AND RESEARCH DEPARTMENT

Economic Growth, Income Inequality, and Poverty Reduction in People s Republic of China BO Q. LIN

Global Inequality - Trends and Issues. Finn Tarp

Global Inequality Fades as the Global Economy Grows

Spatial Inequality in Cameroon during the Period

The Social Policy and Development Centre (SPDC)

New Evidence on the Urbanization of Global Poverty

Income Distributions, Inequality, and Poverty in Asia,

HOW ECONOMIES GROW AND DEVELOP Macroeconomics In Context (Goodwin, et al.)

THE POVERTY-GROWTH-INEQUALITY TRIANGLE: WITH SOME REFLECTIONS ON EGYPT. François Bourguignon DISTINGUISHED LECTURE SERIES 22

Pro-Poor Growth in Mozambique: An Exploration of its Income and Non-Income Dimensions

Poverty, Pro-Poor Growth and Simulated Inequality Reduction

Economic Growth and Inequality

Columbia University. Department of Economics Discussion Paper Series

The Politics of Global Poverty Diverse Perspectives on Measurement MARKUS LEDERER & ANDREA SCHAPPER REVIEW

vi. rising InequalIty with high growth and falling Poverty

Poverty in the Third World

Growth, Inequality, and Poverty: An Introduction Nanak Kakwani, Brahm Prakash, and Hyun Son

PERSISTENT POVERTY AND EXCESS INEQUALITY: LATIN AMERICA,

THE methods used to set poverty lines have differed radically

ESTIMATING INCOME INEQUALITY IN PAKISTAN: HIES TO AHMED RAZA CHEEMA AND MAQBOOL H. SIAL 26

Global Income Inequality by the Numbers: In History and Now An Overview. Branko Milanovic

The Relation of Income Inequality, Growth and Poverty and the Effect of IMF and World Bank Programs on Income Inequality

Inequality and economic growth

Reducing income inequality by economics growth in Georgia

Inclusive global growth: a framework to think about the post-2015 agenda

DOES INCOME INEQUALITY HAMPER OR FOSTER ECONOMIC GROWTH IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA?

2. Money Metric Poverty & Expenditure Inequality

Household Income inequality in Ghana: a decomposition analysis

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES GLOBAL INEQUALITY WHEN UNEQUAL COUNTRIES CREATE UNEQUAL PEOPLE. Martin Ravallion

19 ECONOMIC INEQUALITY. Chapt er. Key Concepts. Economic Inequality in the United States

Economic Growth and Poverty Reduction: Lessons from the Malaysian Experience

Intergenerational Mobility and the Rise and Fall of Inequality: Lessons from Latin America

Understanding global and local inequalities: an EU-AFD initiative. 15/01/2018 AFD, Paris

Outline: Poverty, Inequality, and Development

Development economics

The Debate on Globalization, Poverty, and Inequality

Global Inequality when Unequal Countries Create Unequal People

Economic growth, inequality, and poverty in Vietnam

Augustin Kwasi Fosu 1. December 2010

The impact of Chinese import competition on the local structure of employment and wages in France

Is the Great Gatsby Curve Robust?

Income Inequality and Economic Growth: An Analysis Using a Panel Data

Globalization and Poverty Forthcoming, University of

Asian Development Review

Pro-Poor Growth and the Poorest

AQA Economics A-level

Internal and international remittances in India: Implications for Household Expenditure and Poverty

Violent Conflict and Inequality

The Impact of the Interaction between Economic Growth and Democracy on Human Development: Cross-National Analysis

Inequality in Brazil

Human Capital and Income Inequality: New Facts and Some Explanations

Life is Unfair in Latin America, But Does it Matter for Growth?

This first collection of chapters considers the measurement and understanding

Development economics

Urbanization, Educational Expansion, and Expenditures Inequality in Indonesia in 1996, 1999, and 2002

Rising Income Inequality in Asia

Growth and inequality effects on poverty reduction in Italy

IV. Labour Market Institutions and Wage Inequality

POVERTY AND INEQUALITY IN SOUTH AFRICA AND THE WORLD

Working Paper Series. Inequality and globalization: A review essay. Martin Ravallion ECINEQ WP

Lecture 1. Introduction

Production, Inequality and Poverty linkages in South Africa 1

ABCDE Revised, July Poverty and Inclusion from a World Perspective 1. A B Atkinson, Nuffield College, Oxford. F Bourguignon, DELTA, Paris

INCLUSIVE GROWTH AND POLICIES: THE ASIAN EXPERIENCE. Thangavel Palanivel Chief Economist for Asia-Pacific UNDP, New York

Levels and Dynamics of Inequality in India: Filling in the blanks

The Challenge of Inclusive Growth: Making Growth Work for the Poor

Differences Lead to Differences: Diversity and Income Inequality Across Countries

CH 19. Name: Class: Date: Multiple Choice Identify the choice that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Transcription:

World Bank Lecture March 27 2013 Poverty, Inequality and Growth: Debates, Theories and Evidence Martin Ravallion Dept. Economics, Georgetown University Even though the world is incomparably richer than ever before, ours is also a world of extraordinary deprivation and staggering inequality. (Amartya Sen)

Debates about poverty and inequality in the world The extent of poverty and inequality in the world and how it is changing holds clues for some important ongoing debates about development policy. The longstanding debate about globalization is (in part) a debate about its distributional consequences.

One side of this debate: Growth really does help the poor: in fact it raises their incomes by about as much as it raises the incomes of everybody else.. globalization raises incomes, and the poor participate fully. (The Economist) Evidence suggests that no one has lost out to globalization in an absolute sense. Growth is sufficient. Period (Surjit Bhalla, Imagine There s No Country, Institute for International Economics, Washington DC) 3

The opposing view: There is plenty of evidence that current patterns of growth and globalization are widening income disparities and hence acting as a brake on poverty reduction. (Justin Forsyth, Oxfam UK..) Globalization policies have contributed to increased poverty, increased inequality between and within nations (International Forum for Globalization.) What are we to make of these differing views? Are they due to different data or different interpretations of the same data? 4

Outline of Lecture 1 Concepts and measures 2 Theories of distribution and growth 3 Evidence from cross-country comparisons 4 Some implications for policy 5

1. Concepts and measures Confusion galore! inequality pro-poor growth poverty 6

What do we mean by inequality? One can find different definitions in public debates and policy discussions 7

The standard axioms for an inequality measure are not universally accepted Axiom 1: Anonymity: it does not matter who has which income level. Axiom 2: The (Pigou-Dalton) Transfer Principle: transferring income from the poor to the rich must increase inequality. Axiom 3: Income scale independence: multiplying all incomes by a constant does not change the inequality measure. Axiom 4: Population replication independence; simply replicating the original population cannot increase inequality. Axiom 5: Decomposability: total inequality = inequality between groups + inequality within groups. Further reading: Frank Cowell s chapter in Atkinson and Bourguignon, Handbook of Income 8 Distribution, North-Holland, 2000.

The standard axioms for an inequality measure are not universally accepted Axiom 1: Anonymity: it does not matter who has which income level. But it does matter in reality! Axiom 2: The (Pigou-Dalton) Transfer Principle: transferring income from the poor to the rich must increase inequality. Axiom 3: Income scale independence: multiplying all incomes by a constant does not change the inequality measure. => Relative inequality measures; but absolute gaps also matter! Axiom 4: Population replication independence; simply replicating the original population cannot increase inequality. Axiom 5: Decomposability: total inequality = inequality between groups + inequality within groups. Group identities may matter more than this allows. Further reading: Frank Cowell s chapter in Atkinson and Bourguignon, Handbook of Income 9 Distribution, North-Holland, 2000.

Relaxing scale independence: Relative vs. absolute inequality Relative inequality is about ratios; absolute inequality is about differences. State A: two incomes $1,000 and $10,000 per year State B: these rise to $2,000 and $20,000 Ratio is unchanged but the rich can buy 10 times more from the income gains in state B than can the poor One is not right and the other wrong. Indeed, 40% of participants in surveys of students view inequality in absolute terms. Whether one thinks about inequality as absolute or relative matters greatly to one s views on the distribution of the gains from growth. 10

Two Gini indices of inequality Relative Gini index G r 1 2n 2 y i y y y j Absolute Gini index G a 1 2n 2 y i y j 11

Relaxing anonymity is harder Consider: State A: two incomes $1,000 and $10,000 per year State B: these are swapped to $10,000 and $1,000 Both relative and absolute inequality is the same. Yet the poorest person in State A has gained enormously, while the richest has become the poorest. Relaxing anonymity typically calls for longitudinal ( panel or retrospective) data observing incomes over time for the same people. 12

What do we mean by pro-poor growth? Again, two very different definitions found in recent literature and policy debates 13

Definition 1: Pro-poor growth= growth with pro-poor redistribution Changes in distribution are poverty reducing, i.e., poverty falls by more than one would have expected holding distribution constant (1). => A negative redistribution component in the Datt- Ravallion (2) decomposition for changes in poverty. Let P(µ,L) = poverty measure with mean µ and a vector of parameters, L, describing the Lorenz curve. The change in poverty between dates 1 and 2 (say) is pro poor if P(µ r,l 2 ) < P(µ r,l 1 ) for some fixed µ r Further reading: 1. Nanak Kakwani and E. Pernia, (2000), What Is Pro-Poor Growth? Asian Development Review. 18(1): 1-16. 2. Gaurav Datt and Martin Ravallion (1992), Growth and Redistribution Components of Changes in Poverty Measures: A Decomposition with Applications to Brazil and India in the 1980s, Journal of Development Economics, 38, 275-295. 14

However, By this definition, distributional changes can be propoor with no absolute gain to the poor, or even falling living standards for poor people. Equally well, pro-rich distributional shifts may have come with large absolute gains to the poor. 15

Definition 2: Pro-poor growth= growth that benefits poor people Growth is pro-poor if and only if it accompanies a reduction in an agreed measure of poverty.* But what measure of poverty? * Martin Ravallion and Shaohua Chen, Measuring Pro-Poor Growth, Economics Letters, 2003. 16

The Watts Index of poverty is the mean proportionate poverty gap of the poor: P W t E[ln( z / y ( p)) where: the headcount index is H t =F t (z), z=poverty line; y t (p) is the quantile function (inverse of p=f t (y t )). This satisfies all accepted axioms for poverty measurement including: focus axiom, monotonicity axiom; transfer axiom, transfer-sensitivity and subgroup consistency (2). t p H t ] Further reading: 1. Harold Watts, An Economic Definition of Poverty, in D.P. Moynihan (ed.), On Understanding Poverty. New York, Basic Books, 1968. 2. Buhong Zheng, Axiomatic Characterization of the Watts Index, Economics Letters 1993, 42, 81-86. 17

A measure of pro-poor growth consistent with the Watts index The rate of pro-poor growth is the mean growth rate of the poor: g H t E[ gt ( p) p Ht ] = area under the growth incidence curve (GIC) up to H normalized by H. The GIC: g t ( p) ln y ( p) / y 1( p) where y t (p) is the quantile function: y t =F t -1 (p) t t Further reading: Martin Ravallion and Shaohua Chen, Measuring Pro-Poor Growth, Economics Letters, 2003, 78(1): 93-99. 18

Interpreting the rate of pro-poor growth 1. Rate of pro-poor growth = ordinary growth rate times a distributional correction, given by the ratio of the actual change in the Watts index to a counterfactual with no change in inequality: g H t W dpt W* dpt g t dp H t gt p dp dt ( ) W* t H g Definition 1: Distribution correction > 1 Definition 2: Rate of pro-poor growth > 0 2. Rate of pro-poor growth = the growth rate giving the same rate of poverty reduction as observed but with no change in inequality. dp W t t t dt 19

Note: g H is not the growth rate in the mean income of the poor which does not satisfy either the monotonicity or transfer axioms. If an initially poor person above the mean escapes poverty then the growth rate in the mean for the poor will be negative; yet poverty has fallen. This problem is avoided if one fixes H; but then the measure fails the focus and transfer axioms. 20

What do we mean by poverty? Yet again one can find two different definitions in public debates and policy discussions 21

Definition 1: Absolute poverty in the developing world At country level: all developing countries use poverty lines that aim to have the same real value at different dates and places. Typically anchored to nutritional requirements for good health and normal activities At the global level, the World Bank s widely-used $1- a-day line is absolute in that it aims to have the same purchasing power in different countries and at different dates.

Definition 2: Relative poverty in the developed world The more common practice in most OECD countries and Eurostat has been to set the poverty line as a constant proportion typically 40-60% of the (date and countryspecific) mean or median income: Poverty line Z i km i ( 0 k 1) Mean We can call this a strongly relative poverty line

Past arguments for strongly relative measures 1. Welfarist justification claims that people attach value to their income relative to the mean in a given society and that poverty lines should be interpreted as a money metric of utility. Relative deprivation. 2. Non-welfarist ( capabilities ) justification: poverty lines should allow for differences in the cost of social inclusion, This can be defined as the expenditure needed to cover certain commodities assuring that a person can participate with dignity in customary social and economic activities. Further reading: Martin Ravallion and Shaohua Chen, Weakly Relative Poverty, Review of Economics and Statistics, 2011, 93(4): 1251-1261.

Welfarist interpretation: Disutility of relative deprivation Welfare depends on relative income: U U( Y, Y / M) Y=own income; M=mean income; U Y >0; U Y/M >0 The poverty line (Z) is absolute in the welfare space, but relative in consumption space: U z U( Z, Z / M ) Inverting gives the poverty line as a function of the mean: Z Z M, U ) 0 = 1 ( z ln Z ln M 1 M. MRS (where MRS=U Y /U Y/M ) Elasticity of the poverty line to mean is in [0,1] interval η is increasing in M if (and only if) the elasticity of the MRS with respect to M is less than -1. 1 +

The perverse welfare assumption of strongly relative lines Strongly relative lines imply that people care only about relative income; no value on own income! U U( Y / M ) U z U( Z / M ) => Z f ( U ) M ( f ( U ) z z 0)

Non-welfarist interpretation: Capabilities and the cost of social inclusion Amartya Sen has argued that capabilities should be seen as absolute; an absolute approach in the space of capabilities translates into a relative approach in the space of commodities. Following Tony Atkinson and Francois Bourguignon we can think of poverty as having both absolute and relative aspects in the income space. The former is a failure to attain basic survival needs, with associated capabilities of being adequately nourished and clothed for meeting the physical needs of survival and normal activities. On top of this, a person must also satisfy social needs, which depend crucially on the prevailing living standards in the place of residence. Atkinson-Bourguignon: To be non-poor one needs to be neither absolutely poor ( survival capabilities) nor relatively poor (social inclusion capabilities).

It can be agreed that certain forms of consumption serve an important social role Famously, Adam Smith pointed to the social-inclusion role of a linen shirt in eighteenth century Europe:..a creditable day-labourer would be ashamed to appear in public without a linen shirt, the want of which would be supposed to denote that disgraceful degree of poverty which, it is presumed, nobody can well fall into without extreme bad conduct. Anthropologists have often noted the social roles played by festivals, celebrations, communal feasts, clothing Seemingly high expenditures on celebrations and festivals by very poor people in survey data for a number of countries (Rao, Banerjee-Duflo). Clothing can also serve a social role; conspicuous designer label, which he interpreted as status-seeking behavior. Qat in Yemen refusing to take qat is tantamount to accepting ostracisation (Milanovic, 2008, p.684)

However, the social role of consumption does not imply strongly relative poverty lines The key assumption of strongly relative measures is that the cost of inclusion is a constant proportion of mean income. That is hardly plausible. The social-inclusion needs of very poor people may well be low, but it is difficult to see why they would go to zero in the limit. Presumably a socially acceptable linen shirt would not have cost any less for the poorest person in eighteenth century Europe as for someone living at the poverty line. Very poor people are highly constrained in spending on things that facilitate their social inclusion, but that does not mean that their inclusion needs are negligible.

Weakly vs. strongly relative lines Poverty line Absolute line Weakly relative Strongly relative (Atkinson-Bourguignon) Social inclusion cost for poorest; e.g., Adam Smith s linen shirt, which costs just as much for the poorest. Mean

3. Theories of growth and distribution 31

The two-way relationship: Growth=>distributional change (higher inequality initially +lower poverty) High poverty and inequality =>low growth => slow progress against poverty 32

Growth=>Distribution Does growth come with rising inequality? Does growth reduce poverty? 33

The Kuznets Hypothesis Relative inequality increases in the early stages of growth in a developing country but begins to fall after some point, i.e., the relationship between inequality (on the vertical axis) and average income (horizontal) is predicted to trace out an inverted U. Further reading: Sudhir Anand and Ravi Kanbur, The Kuznets Process and the Inequality- Development Relationship, Journal of Development Economics 1993, Vol. 40:25-52. 34

Implications for poverty and growth Under the Kuznets Hypothesis, absolute poverty will tend to fall with growth. Stage 1: Rising inequality, but this will not be sufficient to eliminate gains to the poor from growth, given that it comes through higher incomes (with no losses, i.e., first-order dominance). Stage 2: Falling inequality will magnify the impact of growth on poverty. 35

High poverty and inequality =>Low growth? Does inequality impede growth? Does poverty impede growth? Is poverty self-perpetuating? 36

Theories of distribution-dependent growth Inequality restricts efficiency-enhancing cooperation amongst people, such that public goods needed for growth are underprovided or efficiency-enhancing policy reforms are blocked (Bardhan et al., 2000; Rajan, 2009). Political-economy models of redistribution argue that high inequality leads democratic governments to implement distortionary redistributive policies, e.g., Alesina and Rodrik (1994). 37

Theories based on credit-market failures Market failure attributed to information asymmetries, notably that lenders are imperfectly informed about borrowers. Key analytic feature: a suitably nonlinear relationship between an individual s initial wealth and her future wealth (the recursion diagram ). With diminishing marginal products of capital, the mean future wealth will be a quasi-concave function of the distribution of current wealth Thus higher current inequality implies lower future mean wealth at a given value of current mean wealth, i.e., lower growth. Examples: Galor and Zeira (1993), Benabou (1996), Aghion and Bolton (1997) and Banerjee and Duflo (2003). 38

A neglected implication of such models: Poverty also impedes growth Some theoretical models => Poverty itself can impede growth and (hence) poverty reduction 1. Lasting (adverse) productivity effects of poor nutrition, esp., in childhood (Dasgupta and Ray, 1986; Cunha and Heckman, 2007). 2. Lopez and Servén (2009) introduce a subsistence consumption requirement into the utility function in the model of Aghion et al. (1999) and show that higher poverty incidence (failure to meet the subsistence requirement) implies lower growth. 39

Implications of borrowing constraints 3. Banerjee and Duflo (2003 *) provide a simple but insightful growth model with a borrowing constraint. Those with sufficient wealth will reach their unconstrained optimum, equating the marginal product of capital with the interest rate. But the wealth poor, for whom the borrowing constraint is binding, will not be able to do so. Banerjee and Duflo show that higher inequality in such an economy implies lower growth. However, their model also implies that higher current wealth poverty for a given mean also implies lower growth (**). In the Banerjee-Duflo model an unambiguously higher initial headcount index of poverty holding the initial mean constant implies a lower growth rate. 40 Further reading: * Banerjee, Abhijit and Esther Duflo, 2003, Inequality and Growth: What Can the Data Say? Journal of Economic Growth 8(3): 267-99. ** Martin Ravallion, Why Don t we See Poverty Convergence? Policy Research Working Paper 4974, World Bank.

Nonlinear dynamics: Inequality and poverty handicap growth w t 1 w t 1 w ( w ) t 1 t w ( w ) t 1 t wt Unique equilibrium wt Multiple equilibria 41

4. Evidence from cross-country comparisons Does growth come with rising inequality? Does growth reduce poverty? Does high inequality and/or high poverty impede growth? What is happening to aggregate poverty and inequality? 42

Testing the Kuznets Hypothesis Common formulation: Gini it 2 0 1 lnyit 2(ln Yit ) Z it it If the KH holds then we expect β 1 >0 and β 2 <0 and that -β 1 /(2β 2) is within the range of the data. Typical control variables (Z) in the literature: socialist dummy, government transfers, share of state sector employment, external openness, age structure of population. 43

20 30 40 50 60 70 A simple quadratic relationship between Gini and GDI per capita, 1950-2000 6 8 10 12 ln(gdpppp) GiniW + giniwy Fitted values 95% CI Pooled countries and dates; n=1,000 44

A weak inverted U relationship (more than 1000 Ginis) Huge variability in inequality; R 2 only 0.08 The upward sloping part of the curve particularly hard to discern Turning point is quite unstable; here about $PPP 2,000 (level of Senegal or Zimbabwe) Even this weak inverted U vanishes with country fixed effects. The most serious critique: With greater time series evidence, we find that very few developing countries have followed the prediction of KH.* Further reading: * Bruno, Michael, Martin Ravallion and Lyn Squire (1998), Equity and Growth in Developing Countries: Old and New Perspectives on the Policy Issues, in Income Distribution and High-Quality Growth (edited by Vito Tanzi and Ke-young Chu), Cambridge, Mass: MITPress. 45

Changes in relative inequality are uncorrelated with growth 1. Across 120 spells (between two surveys), virtually zero correlation between changes in inequality (the log Gini index) and economic growth (change in the log of the survey mean or PCE).* Figure=> 2. Mean income of the poorest 20% (say) has a regression coefficient of about one on the overall growth rate** Further reading: * Martin Ravallion, Inequality is Bad for the Poor, in Inequality and Poverty Re-Examined, edited by John Micklewright and Steven Jenkins, Oxford: Oxford University Press, forthcoming. **David Dollar and Aart Kraay, Growth is Good for the Poor, Journal of Economic Growth, 2002, 7(3): 195-225. 46

Difference in log Gini index.8.6 r = 0.13.4.2.0 -.2 -.4 -.6 -.8-1.6-1.2-0.8-0.4 0.0 0.4 0.8 1.2 Difference in log mean 47

Proportionate change in the $1/day poverty rate So growth is typically pro-poor by definition 2 1.0 0.5 0.0 Slope = -2-0.5-1.0-0.3-0.2-0.1 0.0 0.1 0.2 Proportionate change in survey mean 48

Proportionate change in the $1/day poverty rate The extent to which growth is pro-poor has varied enormously between countries and over time A 1% rate of growth will bring anything from a modest drop in the poverty rate of 0.6% to a more dramatic 3.5% annual decline (95% CI). There have been plenty of cases of rising inequality during spells of growth. Indeed, inequality increases about half the time 1.0 0.5 0.0-0.5-1.0-0.3-0.2-0.1 0.0 0.1 0.2 Proportionate change in survey mean Further reading: Martin Ravallion, Growth, Inequality and Poverty: Looking Beyond Averages, World Development, Vol. 29(11), November 2001, pp. 1803-1815. 49

Distribution-neutrality on average does not mean that distribution is unchanging; in fact, it changes a lot Large fluctuations in measured inequality even when no long-run trend Some of this is measurement error; noise in inequality data But even seemingly small changes in a Gini index (say) can mean large welfare changes for the poor 50

Diverse impacts on poverty coexist with aggregate distribution neutrality What is happening to average household income between the surveys? Falling Rising What is happening to relative inequality?* Rising 16% of spells Poverty is rising at a median rate of 14.3% per year 30% of spells Poverty is falling at a median rate of 1.3% per year * Relative Gini index Falling 26% of spells 27% of spells Poverty is rising at Poverty is falling a median rate of at a median rate 1.7% per year of 9.6% per year 51

Distribution-neutrality does not mean that incomes of the poor rise by about as much as everybody else Given existing inequality, the rich will capture a much larger share of the gains from growth than the poor. The income gain to the richest 10% in India will be four times higher than the gain to the poorest 20%; 15+ times higher in South Africa. Further reading: Martin Ravallion, Growth, Inequality and Poverty: Looking Beyond Averages, World Development, Vol. 29(11), November 2001, pp. 1803-1815. 52

Annualized change in relative Gini index Annualized change in absolute Gini index Same data, but very different pictures 10 Relative Gini 15 Absolute Gini 5 10 5 0 0-5 -5-10 -10-0.2-0.1 0.0 0.1 0.2 Annualized change in log mean -15-0.2-0.1 0.0 0.1 0.2 Annualized change in log mean Further reading: Martin Ravallion, Competing Concepts of Inequality in the Globalization Debate, Brookings Trade Forum 2004, Edited by Susan Collins and Carol Graham, Washington DC: Brookings Institution, pp.1-38. 53

A less unequal world? Absolute vs relative inequality 200 175 150 Absolute Gini index Gini index Mean logarithmic deviation 125 100 75 50 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 'Source: Atkinson and Brandolini (2004). Source: Atkinson, Anthony and Andrea Brandolini. 2004. Global Income Inequality: Absolute, Relative or Intermediate?, Paper presented at the 28th General Conference of the International Association for 54 Research on Income and Wealth.

Growth elasticity of poverty reduction High inequality is an impediment to pro-poor growth 20 10 0-10 Mean elasticity close to zero in high inequality countries -20 20 30 40 50 60 70 Initial Gini index (%) 55

High inequality is an impediment to pro-poor growth Even when inequality is not changing, it matters to the rate of poverty reduction It is not the rate of growth that matters, but the distribution-corrected rate of growth Rate of poverty reduction = [constant x (1 - inequality) 2 ] x growth rate Higher levels of inequality have progressively smaller impacts on the elasticity as inequality rises Further reading: Martin Ravallion, Inequality is Bad for the Poor, in Inequality and Poverty Re-Examined, edited by John Micklewright and Steven Jenkins, Oxford: Oxford University 56 Press, forthcoming.

Rate of poverty reduction with a 2% rate of growth in per capita income and a headcount index of 40% Low-inequality country (Gini=0.30): the headcount index will be halved in 11 years. High inequality country (Gini=0.60): it will then take 35 years to halve the initial poverty rate. Note: the argument works in reverse: high inequality protects the poor from negative macro shocks. 57

Does high inequality and/or high poverty impede growth? 58

Past evidence on growth and inequality Empirical support from cross-country growth regressions for the view that a Gini index of inequality impedes growth at country level. Alesina and Rodrik (1994), Persson and Tabellini (1994), Birdsall et al., (1995), Clarke (1995), Perotti (1996), Deininger and Squire (1998) and Knowles (2005) However, not all the evidence has been supportive; also see Li and Zou (1999), Barro (2000) and Forbes (2000). The main reason why these studies have been less supportive appears to be that they have allowed for countrylevel fixed effects. Limited power for FE models with these data. 59

But is it inequality or poverty that matters? Recall that some growth theories suggest that it is high initial poverty at given mean that matters rather than inequality per se. Theories based on borrowing constraints Theories postulating a lasting (adverse) productivity effect of poor nutrition, esp., in childhood 60

Benchmark regression: g i ( ) where it Poverty and growth 0.262 0.039ln (8.470) g i ( it it it ( 8.410) ) ln( / ) / it 0.020ln ( 5.513) H it ˆ it Note: The regression is consistent with a derivative of current mean with respect to lagged mean that is less than unity, but fades toward zero at sufficiently long gaps between survey rounds. 61

Benchmark regression: Growth rate g i ( ) where it Poverty and growth 0.262 0.039ln (8.470) g i ( it it it ( 8.410) ) ln( / ) / it Initial mean 0.020ln ( 5.513) H it ˆ it Initial poverty rate ($2/day) Note: The regression is consistent with a derivative of current mean with respect to lagged mean that is less than unity, but fades toward zero at sufficiently long gaps between survey rounds. 62

Encompassing regressions (1) (2) (3) (4) Growth rates based on: Consumption Survey from national Means accounts Survey Means Consumption from national accounts gi( it ) ln it ln Hit X it it Complete specification: Dropping weak predictors: Intercept 0.446 0.623 0.259 0.635 (0.831) (1.255) (1.318) (1.298) Initial mean ( for (1) and (3) -0.057*** -0.034*** -0.050** -0.034*** and for (2) and (4)) (-6.139) (-4.307) (-12.107) (-4.374) Poverty rate ($2 a day) -0.027*** -0.018*** -0.025** -0.017*** (-5.536) (-3.239) (-5.991) (-3.310) Gini index -0.018-0.076* - -0.078* (-0.372) (-1.727) (-1.800) Income share of middle three -0.117-0.167** -0.084** -0.169** quintiles (-1.505) (-2.183) (-4.245) (-2.244) Share of population in Western -0.127-0.154*** -0.144** -0.152*** middle class (-2.781) (-3.545) (-3.005) (-3.572) The miser index (x100) 0.066 0.018 - - (1.108) (1.038) Primary school enrolment rate 0.007 0.002 - - (log) (0.729) (0.253) Life expectancy (log) 0.112*** 0.147*** 0.110** 0.151*** (2.795) (3.894) (3.122) (4.164) Price of investment (log) -0.013*** -0.015*** -0.014** -0.017*** (-2.482) (-3.099) (-2.827) (-3.246) N 0.539 0.503 0.531 0.502 63 R 2 89 85 89 85

Given these country experiences: What has been happening to inequality poverty in the developing world? 64

Rising inequality in many developing countries Overall decline in inequality in the developing world, but not within countries Inequality increases about half the time during spells of growth. Rising inequality on average (more so in some regions than others). This is attenuating gains to the poor from growth..8.7.6.5.4.3.2.1 Inequality (as measured by Mean Log Deviation).0 1980 1983 1986 1989 1992 1995 1998 2001 2004 2007 2010.35.30.25.20.15.10.05 Average inequality (pop. weighted MLD) Middle-East & North Africa East Asia Developing world as a whole Total inequality.00 1980 1983 1986 1989 1992 1995 1998 2001 2004 2007 2010 Within-country inequality Between-country inequality 65

What has been happening to poverty in the aggregate? With aggregate economic growth in the developing world since 1980 we have seen a trend decline in the incidence of poverty. Falling absolute numbers of extreme poor (<$1.25 a day) but rising numbers living between $1.25 and $2, and less progress in reducing the number living under $2. Why $1.25 a day? 66

National poverty line ($/month at 2005 PPP) National poverty lines for developing countries plotted against mean consumption using consumption PPPs for 2005 300 OLS elasticity=0.66 200 100 $1.25 a day 0 3 4 5 6 7 Log consumption per person at 2005 PPP Note: Fitted values use a lowess smoother with bandwidth=0.8

Progress for the poorest in the aggregate The % below $1.25 a day was halved, falling from 52% to 22% over 1981-2008. Trend decline of one % point per year. At this rate, the developing world as a whole has achieved the first Millennium Development Goal. 70 60 50 40 30 20 Headcount index of poverty (% below poverty line) $2 per day $2 per day (less China) $1.25 per day $1.25 per day (less China) Number of poor fell by 600 million, from 1.9 billion to 1.3 billion Poverty rate fell in all years Robust to choice of poverty line 10 0 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 Further reading: Chen and Ravallion, QJE, 2010, 125(4), pp. 1577-1625. 68

Population living under $1.25/day (millions) The regional picture: uneven progress 2000.0 Numbers of poor by region ($1.25 a day) Number of poor by region 1800.0 1600.0 Rest of the World 1400.0 1200.0 East Asia 1000.0 800.0 Sub-Saharan Africa 600.0 400.0 South Asia 200.0 0.0 1981 1984 1987 1990 1993 1996 1999 2002 2005 2008 69

What about relative poverty? Global (weakly) relative poverty lines Z i max[$ 1.25, $0.60 M i /3] $0.60 max[$0.65, M i /3] Poverty line ($ per day; 2005 PPP) Weakly relative Slope=1/3 $1.25/day $0.60/day Excellent fit with data on national lines

Absolute and relative poverty in the developing world 70 Headcount index (% below poverty line) 60 50 Weakly relative poverty 40 Absolute poverty 30 20 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005

Not just about success in China! Since 2000 we have seen a marked acceleration in poverty reduction outside China. Ratification of MDGs at Millennium Summit of 2000? Maybe, but very hard to say. 50 40 30 20 Headcount index (% below $1.25 a day; excluding China) MDGs? 0.4% point per year 1.0% point per year 10 0 1980 1983 1986 1989 1992 1995 1998 2001 2004 2007 2010 72

A tale of three regions 80 Headcount index (% below $1.25 a day) East Asia 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 Africa Africa South Asia East Asia 0 1980 1983 1986 1989 1992 1995 1998 2001 2004 2007 2010 73

Optimistic trajectories going forward Maintaining the new path of poverty reduction since 2000: Lower bound (absolute poverty): 19% this year (1.1 billion) 14% in five years (0.9 billion) 9% in 10 years (0.6 billion) 3% by 2027 1 billion people lifted out of poverty! Upper bound (absolute + relative): 46% this year (2.7 billion) 44% in five years (2.7 billion) 42% in 10 years (2.7 billion) The increase in numbers of relatively poor is expected to stabilize. 74

5. Conclusions: Some implications for attacking poverty 75

Poverty Absolute versus relative? Policy makers should not frame the problem of measuring poverty as a choice between absolute and relative measures. Rather they should be thought of as lower and upper bounds to the (unknown) absolute measure in the space of welfare. Both measures are needed. Inequality Recognize that some people understand inequality differently to others. Absolute vs relative inequality. Debates often reflect these differences; ships passing in the night. 76

Should policy-makers be worried about rising inequality? Possibly it is inevitable to some degree. Arthur Lewis: Development must be inegalitarian because it does not start in every part of the economy at the same time. However, policy makers aiming for pro-poor economic growth should be concerned about those inequalities that impede prospects for poverty reduction. 77

How to achieve more pro-poor growth? Literature and policy discussions point to the need to: Develop human and physical assets of poor Help make markets work better for the poor, esp., for credit and labor Removing biases against the poor in public spending, taxation, trade and regulation Promote agriculture and rural development; invest in local public goods in poor areas Provide an effective safety net; short term palliative or key instrument for long-term poverty reduction? 78

Growth is sufficient misses the point Those who say that growth is not enough are not saying that growth does not help. Heterogeneity in the impact of growth on poverty holds clues as to what else needs to be done on top of promoting economic growth. Rapid poverty reduction requires a combination of: growth-promoting economic reforms with the right social-sector programs and policies to help the poor participate fully in the opportunities unleashed by growth However, the political economy can make both sets of reforms difficult, especially in highly unequal societies. This is also true in democracies. 79