TAMPERE ECONOMIC WORKING PAPERS NET SERIES

Similar documents
School of Economics Shandong University Jinan, China Pr JOSSELIN March 2010

Chapter 4 Specific Factors and Income Distribution

International Trade Theory College of International Studies University of Tsukuba Hisahiro Naito

3. Public Choice in a Direct Democracy

Course: Economic Policy with an Emphasis on Tax Policy

Chapter 4: Specific Factors and

Illegal Immigration, Immigration Quotas, and Employer Sanctions. Akira Shimada Faculty of Economics, Nagasaki University

International Remittances and Brain Drain in Ghana

Peer Group Effects, Sorting, and Fiscal Federalism

Labour market integration and its effect on child labour

Figure 1. Payoff Matrix of Typical Prisoner s Dilemma This matrix represents the choices presented to the prisoners and the outcomes that come as the

Theoretical Public Economics Syllabus (ECO 7536; Spring 2018)

On the Rationale of Group Decision-Making

1 Aggregating Preferences

Citation 經營と經濟, vol.90(4), pp.1-25; Issue Date Right.

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES

Innovation and Intellectual Property Rights in a. Product-cycle Model of Skills Accumulation

Unemployment and the Immigration Surplus

Spatial Inequality in Cameroon during the Period

Evolutionary Game Path of Law-Based Government in China Ying-Ying WANG 1,a,*, Chen-Wang XIE 2 and Bo WEI 2

Rural-urban Migration and Minimum Wage A Case Study in China

An example of public goods

The Economic Effects of Minimum Wage Policy

GRAVITY EQUATIONS IN INTERNATIONAL TRADE. based on Chapter 5 of Advanced international trade: theory and evidence by R. C. Feenstra (2004, PUP)

Tax Competition and Migration: The Race-to-the-Bottom Hypothesis Revisited

Notes on exam in International Economics, 16 January, Answer the following five questions in a short and concise fashion: (5 points each)

The Political Economy of State-Owned Enterprises. Carlos Seiglie, Rutgers University, N.J. and Luis Locay, University of Miami. FL.

Migration, Intermediate Inputs and Real Wages

The Transfer of the Remittance Fee from the Migrant to the Household

VOTING ON INCOME REDISTRIBUTION: HOW A LITTLE BIT OF ALTRUISM CREATES TRANSITIVITY DONALD WITTMAN ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA

CHAPTER 18: ANTITRUST POLICY AND REGULATION

Immigration Policy In The OECD: Why So Different?

IMPACT OF IMMIGRATION AND OUTSOURCING ON THE LABOUR MARKET A Partial Equilibrium Analysis

July, Abstract. Keywords: Criminality, law enforcement, social system.

The Provision of Public Goods Under Alternative. Electoral Incentives

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES

Are Second-Best Tariffs Good Enough?

Part I Immigration Theory and Evidence

Legal Change: Integrating Selective Litigation, Judicial Preferences, and Precedent

Incentives for separation and incentives for public good provision

Part I Immigration Theory and Evidence

P1: aaa SJNW N stylea.cls (2005/11/30 v1.0 LaTeX Springer document class) January 2, :37

Can We Reduce Unskilled Labor Shortage by Expanding the Unskilled Immigrant Quota? Akira Shimada Faculty of Economics, Nagasaki University

Enriqueta Aragones Harvard University and Universitat Pompeu Fabra Andrew Postlewaite University of Pennsylvania. March 9, 2000

Volume Author/Editor: Jagdish N. Bhagwati, editor. Volume URL:

THREATS TO SUE AND COST DIVISIBILITY UNDER ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION. Alon Klement. Discussion Paper No /2000

Market failures. If markets "work perfectly well", governments should just play their minimal role, which is to:

involving 58,000 foreig n students in the U.S. and 11,000 American students $1.0 billion. Third, the role of foreigners in the American economics

Section 1: Microeconomics. 1.1 Competitive Markets: Demand and Supply. IB Econ Syllabus Outline. Markets Ø The Nature of Markets

CHAPTER 19 MARKET SYSTEMS AND NORMATIVE CLAIMS Microeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.), 2 nd Edition

Definition: Institution public system of rules which defines offices and positions with their rights and duties, powers and immunities p.

Chapter 2: The U.S. Economy: A Global View

Immigration and voting on the size and the composition of public spending

Political Economy of Institutions and Development. Lecture 1: Introduction and Overview

Economic Epistemology and Methodological Nationalism: a Federalist Perspective

19 ECONOMIC INEQUALITY. Chapt er. Key Concepts. Economic Inequality in the United States

The impact of Chinese import competition on the local structure of employment and wages in France

The Analytics of the Wage Effect of Immigration. George J. Borjas Harvard University September 2009

DRIVERS OF DEMOGRAPHIC CHANGE AND HOW THEY AFFECT THE PROVISION OF EDUCATION

When users of congested roads may view tolls as unjust

policy-making. footnote We adopt a simple parametric specification which allows us to go between the two polar cases studied in this literature.

Chapter 10 Worker Mobility: Migration, Immigration, and Turnover

Federalism, Freedom of Movement, and Fiscal Equalization

Income Mobility in India: Dimensions, Drivers and Policy

The New Institutional Economics Basic Concepts and Selected Applications

George Mason University

Ricardo: real or supposed vices? A Comment on Kakarot-Handtke s paper Paolo Trabucchi, Roma Tre University, Economics Department

Veto Players, Policy Change and Institutional Design. Tiberiu Dragu and Hannah K. Simpson New York University

CHAPTERB URBAN LABOUR AND MIGRATION

Brain Drain, Fiscal Competition, and Public Education Expenditure

WORKING PAPERS IN ECONOMICS & ECONOMETRICS. A Capital Mistake? The Neglected Effect of Immigration on Average Wages

Sincere Versus Sophisticated Voting When Legislators Vote Sequentially

Do not turn over until you are told to do so by the Invigilator.

Poverty and Inequality

ECON 1100 Global Economics (Section 05) Exam #1 Fall 2010 (Version A) Multiple Choice Questions ( 2. points each):

The Geography of Development: Evaluating Migration Restrictions and Coastal Flooding

Situational Analysis: Peterborough & the Kawarthas

Inequality, segregation, and redistribution

Common-Pool Resources: Over Extraction and Allocation Mechanisms

The Costs of Remoteness, Evidence From German Division and Reunification by Redding and Sturm (AER, 2008)

SECTION: REGIONAL DEVELOPMENT POLICIES AND STRATEGIES MIGRATION AND REGIONAL DEVELOPMENT

Introduction. Equilibrium in a Single Competitive Labor Market. (Pareto) Efficiency. Competitive Equilibrium Across Labor Markets.

Equity and efficiency defined and considered

Economics Of Migration

International Economic Geography Migration

Uncertainty and international return migration: some evidence from linked register data

Corruption and Supervision Costs in Hierarchies 1

Electing the President. Chapter 17 Mathematical Modeling

Optimal Voting Turnouts

Chapter 5. Labour Market Equilibrium. McGraw-Hill/Irwin Labor Economics, 4 th edition

Chapter 7. Urbanization and Rural-Urban Migration: Theory and Policy 7-1. Copyright 2012 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

ECONOMIC GROWTH* Chapt er. Key Concepts

Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series

Professor Christina Romer. LECTURE 13 LABOR AND WAGES March 1, 2018

Professor Christina Romer. LECTURE 11 LABOR AND WAGES February 28, 2019

THE POLITICS OF PUBLIC PROVISION OF EDUCATION 1. Gilat Levy

Butter and Guns: Complementarity between Economic and Military Competition

Globalization, Child Labour, and Adult Unemployment

Educational Investments in a Dual Economy

Department of Economics Working Paper Series

Transcription:

TAMPERE ECONOMIC WORKING PAPERS NET SERIES OPTIMAL FORMATION OF CITIES: POLICY CONSIDERATIONS Hannu Laurila Working Paper 58 August 2007 http://tampub.uta.fi/econet/wp58-2007.pdf DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS AND ACCOUNTING FI-33014 UNIVERSITY OF TAMPERE, FINLAND ISSN 1458-1191 ISBN 978-951-44-70-43-1

Optimal Formation of Cities: Policy Considerations 21.8.2007 Hannu Laurila Department of Economics and Accounting FI-33014 University of Tampere Abstract: Club theoretic analysis of migration between profoundly asymmetric cities shows that centralized policy intervention is necessary to ensure efficient allocation of people between cities. Quantity rationing and equalizing lump sum transfers are compared as the policy instruments of the central government. The instruments turn out to be different in their effects on residential allocation and welfare. This is because lump sum transfers pool up the welfare creating potentials of the cities thus affecting the optimality condition. Therefore, lump sum transfers are superior, and they accelerate rather than stabilize the spatial evolution. Key words: agglomeration economies, city size, club theory JEL Classification: H77, R51

1 Introduction Urban surroundings quite indisputably offer the most fertile soil for the modern market economy. This is because spatial proximity lowers transaction costs and creates externalities and other agglomeration economies that have direct and indirect effects on locally generated welfare. Therefore, welfare experienced in a city depends on city size. An increase in size yields benefits and cost savings, but eventually it also leads to falling benefits and increasing costs. Cities being so central in the market economy, it should be natural that the market also would steer the formation of the city structure in efficient manner. Free mobility of people based on local welfare differentials creates the main private element of the market mechanism of the formation of cities. However, as private choices of location cannot lead to optimal population in the cities, local governments must have an active role in this respect to complement the market mechanism. A common understanding is that collective optimization of city size by the local governments suffices to make the mechanism perfect in purely economic sense. Centralized policy intervention is needed only if there are notable inter-city spillovers. This paper aims to show, however, that centralized policy intervention may be necessary to secure efficiency in the formation of the city system even without inter-city spillovers. The paper studies the working of the market when the cities are profoundly asymmetric with respect to their long-term capability to create welfare. The paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 sets the club theoretic framework of the spatial evolution of the economy driven by systematic migration of people between two asymmetric cities. Section 3 investigates the need and effects of centralized policy and compares the administrative and economic policy instruments. Section 4 concludes. 1

2 Migration between asymmetric cities In practice, there are considerable differences in the cities absolute capability to create welfare for their residents. This is because of exogenous variation in geography and climate, natural resources, industrial structure, national infrastructure and networks, administrational hierarchy, transport and trade connections, etc. Therefore, the question about the working of the formation mechanism of the system consisting of asymmetric cities is most important. The welfare that a city generates to its individual residents can be described by the concept of average welfare derived as the net sum of private benefits and costs experienced in everyday life (Laurila, 2004). Agglomeration economies and diseconomies affect both the benefits and the costs so that the average welfare depends on city size. Average welfare reflects the welfare of a representative household and it can be actually monitored from the pattern of systematic migration. The decisions of the non-representative households belong to the purely stochastic element of migration. Assume that the economy consists of two cities, city A and city B. Fix the total population in the economy to unity so that the populations in A and B sum to 1. In Figure 1 below, the AW curves present the size dependent average welfares in the two cities. The curves are superimposed on each other so that the average welfare in city A denoted by AW A is presented from left to right and that in B denoted by AW B from right to left. (Figure 1 here) In Figure 1, the inverted U shape of the AW curve is because agglomeration diseconomies start to dominate agglomeration economies at the culmination point. It is also assumed that city A is more 2

prosperous than city B because it has an absolute advantage in generating welfare. Therefore, the AW A curve reaches a higher peak value than AW B both reflecting the long-term potential of the cities. The MW curves present the marginal effects of migration to individual welfare. They are also inverted U shaped, and they dissect the AW curves from above at their top points. In Figure 1, the AW curves are drawn to intersect in two points, a and b, in order to illustrate possible market solutions of equal welfare in cities A and B. Start by considering the situation around point a, where the population in city A is n a, that in city B is 1-n a and AW a A = AW a B. With this allocation of population, the small but prosperous city A benefits from agglomeration economies while the much bigger but less prosperous city B suffers from agglomeration diseconomies. Suppose now that a stochastic movement occurs from city A to city B, that is the allocation of population changes to the left from point a. If so, a welfare gap opens in favor of city B thus motivating systematic migration from A to B. On impact, the solution is drawn further to the left in accelerating speed until A becomes totally deserted. If the stochastic movement had occurred from B to A, that is if the allocation had changed rightwards from point a, the welfare gap would have opened in favor of city A. In this case systematic migration would draw the solution further to the right. Therefore, point a is not a stable solution and it thus cannot be an outcome of free migration. Follow the path rightwards from point a to see where the systematic migration based on the increasing welfare differential will lead. The next interesting position is at point d along AW A saying that welfare in city A is at its maximum. Assuming that the cities optimize on their population according to the within-club rule (Ng, 1973; Cornes & Sandler, 1999), the population allocation n d /(1-n d ) becomes a stable market solution by the local policy-making of city A. The policy is 3

feasible, because an in-migration city can easily close doors for further immigrants by traditional policy measures such as city planning, dimensioning of service provision and social housing, public transport etc. even though there are willing immigrants attracted by the welfare gap AW d d A > AW B (Laurila, 2004). The welfare in city A is n d times AW d A and that in city B is 1-n d times AW d B. Thus, the social welfare of the local optimization solution is measured by SW d = n d AW A d + (1- n d )AW B d. However, if city A does not, for some reason, implement the optimal policy, systematic migration can continue in response to the welfare gap. The allocation of population eventually reaches the stage, where the average welfare in city B is at its maximum at point e..however, optimizing of population in city B is not feasible because out-migration cities seldom have ample policy instruments for stopping emigration. Because AW e A > AW e B it is quite plausible that migration will continue further. The welfare differential motivates migration from city B to city A until the second intersection point b with the allocation n b /(1-n b ) is reached. Around point b, the more prosperous city A is excessively congested while the less prosperous city B is small and would benefit from growth. Yet, the welfare equalizing solution b is stable: stochastic movement to the left from point b makes city A attractive for systematic immigration from city B drawing the solution towards b. The opposite is true on the right side of the point. Thus, point b is a genuine market equilibrium of free migration. Social welfare of the stable migration solution amounts to SW b = AW A b = AW B b. 4

Neither of the two market allocations considered above is socially optimal. The socially optimal solution is at point E, where the MW curves intersect reflecting the economy-widely optimal mix of utilization of agglomeration economies in city B and suffering of agglomeration diseconomies in city A. The population allocation is n E /(1-n E ), and the optimal social welfare is measured by SW E = n E AW A E + (1-n E )AW B E. Compared to the social optimum, the allocation n d /(1- n d ) is not efficient because of the welfare loss measured by the area cde in Figure 1. The stable market solution at point b is not efficient either because of the welfare loss Efg. Therefore, SW d < SW E > SW b, but no general conclusions can be made whether SW d is higher or lower than SW b. Because the socially optimal solution is reached neither by migration alone nor by migration complemented by local policy, and particularly because the optimum implies a sustaining welfare differential AW E A > AW E B, it is obvious that centralized policy intervention is needed on efficiency grounds. 3 Policy considerations The standard policy instruments consist of administrative and economic measures. Their difference is that administrative measures concern quantitative terms thus operating along the horizontal axis while economic instruments concern monetary issues thus operating along the vertical axis of Figure 1. The conventional wisdom concerning the instruments is that their effects should be equal horizontally and vertically so that the market solution is symmetrically affected. 5

The administrative quantity rationing uses rules, standards, constraints and other such legislative tools in order to make the social welfare maximizing allocation n E /(1-n E ) sustainable. Practical implementation of the policy means that people are allowed to move from city B to city A until the optimal allocation is reached. In this planning solution the welfare difference AW E A - AW E B > 0 between the cities is maintained at the optimal social welfare level SW E. This kind of a policy is feasible if the instruments for the optimization of population are in the hands of the central level so that it can nullify or rule out the local optimization policy. By the administrative instruments, the economy is divided into better-off and worse-off cities, thereby violating both the intertwined principles of free migration and regional equity. But if these principles should be respected, the administrative instruments are obviously out of the question. In stead, economic instrument could be used to level out the welfare differences thus making the market solution based on free migration sustainable. Assume now that the central government transfers income from the more prosperous to the less propserous city by undistortive lump sum transfers so as to equalize the welfare levels in city A and city B. In practice, the policy concerns transfers of income that is they affect through people s budget constraints and leave the benefit sides unaffected. In any case, the effect is that the welfare schedules are altered. Figure 2 illustrates the effects of such policy. (Figure 2 here) The policy is supposed to be implemented in two stages in Figure 2. First, a Pigouvian tax measured by the tax wedge is imposed on the citizens of city A thus pressing the AW A curve downwards. As a result, the migration solution is steered to the stable solution in point. Second, the tax income 6

is returned evenly ) to people in city A and city B so that the AW A and AW B curves shift both upwards crossing at point. The lump-sum transfers from city A to city B press the AW A curve flatter and to the right and the AW B curve taller and to the left. The transfers being equalizing in nature the result is a joint average welfare curve, which is presented by the dashed AW AB curve just between the original AW A and AW B curves in Figure 2. Between points a and b the transfers go from city A to city B, and beyond the points the other way round. The marginal welfare curves shift accordingly to MW A for city A and to MW B for city B. The curves strike through the joint average welfare curve at at the top of AW AB. That the transfers shift the marginal welfare curves means that the optimality condition given by the intersection of the MW curves is affected. In Figure 2, the policy makes the intersection point shift leftwards from E to. The optimal allocation is thus different from that without policy - city A should be smaller and city B bigger than without policy. The optimal allocation of people is n /(1-n ), and the social welfare is SW = AW A = AW B, which is the highest attainable welfare level. In particular, SW >SW E. This is because the equalizing lump sum transfer in effect redistributes prosperity in the economy so that the existing resources and other preconditions come to be utilized more efficiently. The reshaping of the AW curves means that agglomeration economies are increased and diseconomies decreased in the economy and that both cities are of optimal size in this respect in the equilibrium. 7

4 Conclusions In the practically relevant case of profoundly asymmetric cities, a stable and efficient market solution is not achievable even with collective optimization of population by the local governments. The first conclusion of the paper is that centralized policy intervention is necessary to ensure efficiency in practice. Two instruments of centralized policy are studied, namely administrative measures in the form of quantity rationing and economic measures in the form of equalizing lump sum transfers. The paper shows that both measures produce a superior outcome to that yielded by migration alone or by migration complemented by local level policy-making. The use of administrative policy measures implies that the efficient allocation of people is maintained in spite of the existing welfare differentials between cities. The principle of regional equity is thus violated. Such measures may also be difficult to implement in a market economy because they necessitate constraints on free mobility. Lump sum transfers from more prosperous to less prosperous cities can be used to equalize the welfare differentials thus making the free migration solution sustainable. The final result of the paper is that lump sum transfers yield both different allocation of population and higher social welfare than quantity rationing. The result contradicts the conventional wisdom that administrative and economic measures should have symmetric effects, and that inter-regional transfers should, as they level out the welfare differentials, stabilize migration. In this model equalizing lump-sum transfers rather accelerate than stabilize migration. This is because the policy effectively pools up the welfare creating potentials of the cities thus changing the efficient residential pattern from that without transfers. 8

Reading: Atkinson, A. & J. Stiglitz (1980): Lectures on Public Economics. McGraw-Hill, London. Bailey, S. (1999): Local Government Economics. Principles and Practice. MacMillan Press Ltd, Houndmills. Cornes, R. & T. Sandler (1986): The Theory of Externalities, Public Goods, and Club Goods. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. Fujita, M. & J-F. Thisse (2002): Economics of Agglomeration. Cities, Industrial Location, and Regional Growth. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. Henderson, J.V. (1985): Economic Theory and the Cities. 2 nd ed. Academic Press, Orlando. Laurila, H. (2004): Urban Governance, Competition and Welfare. Urban Studies, Vol 41, Number 3, March 2004. Mills, E. & B. Hamilton (1984): Urban Economics. Harper Collins College Publishers, New York. Ng, Y-K. (1973): The Economic Theory of Clubs: Pareto Optimality Conditions. Economica, vol. 4, no. 159, August. Richardson, H. (1973): The Economics of Urban Size. Saxon House/Lexington Books, Westmead. Rubinfeld, D. (1987): The Economics of the Local Public Sector. In: Handbook of Public Economics, A. Auerbach and M. Feldstein (eds.). Elsevier Science Publishers B.V. (North Holland) Stiglitz, J. (1977): The Theory of Local Public Goods. In: The Economics of Public Services, M. Feldman and R. Inman (eds.), MacMillan Press, London. Tiebout, C. (1956): A pure theory of local expenditures. Journal of Political Economy 64, October. Topham, N. (1983): Local Government Economics. In: Public Sector Economics, Millward et. al. (eds.). Longman, New York. 9

Figure 1: Possible solutions of allocation of residents between cities d W A E f W A b c e E b E W B b W B a MW B g MW A W B AW A O A n a n d n E n b O B 10

Figure 2: Equalizing lump-sum transfers between cities MW A d MW B AW AB E b a MW B MW A AW B AW A O A n d n n E n b O B 11