Measuring a Gerrymander

Similar documents
Chapter 3. The Evidence. deposition would have to develop to generate the facts and figures necessary to establish an

A Fair Division Solution to the Problem of Redistricting

Case 3:13-cv REP-LO-AD Document Filed 10/07/15 Page 1 of 23 PageID# APPENDIX A: Richmond First Plan. Dem Lt. Dem Atty.

The Effect of Electoral Geography on Competitive Elections and Partisan Gerrymandering

MATH 1340 Mathematics & Politics

Examples that illustrate how compactness and respect for political boundaries can lead to partisan bias when redistricting. John F.

Guide to 2011 Redistricting

Chapter 34. Unintentional Gerrymander Hypothesis: Conventional Political Analysis

Redistricting: Nuts & Bolts. By Kimball Brace Election Data Services, Inc.

A STATISTICAL EVALUATION AND ANALYSIS OF LEGISLATIVE AND CONGRESSIONAL REDISTRICTING IN CALIFORNIA:

Introduction to the declination function for gerrymanders

The League of Women Voters of Pennsylvania et al v. The Commonwealth of Pennsylvania et al. Nolan McCarty

The Social Policy & Politics Program. August 13, 2012

arxiv: v1 [physics.soc-ph] 13 Mar 2018

AMICUS CURIAE BRIEF OF PHILIP P. KALODNER IN SUPPORT OF NEITHER PARTY

IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE MIDDLE DISTRICT OF NORTH CAROLINA LEAGUE OF WOMEN VOTERS PLAINTIFFS OPENING STATEMENT

Testimony of FairVote The Center for Voting and Democracy Jack Santucci, Program for Representative Government. October 16, 2006

State redistricting, representation,

CALIFORNIA ELECTIONS DATA ARCHIVE INTRODUCTION

Case: 3:15-cv bbc Document #: 79 Filed: 02/16/16 Page 1 of 71 IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE WESTERN DISTRICT OF WISCONSIN

In The Supreme Court of the United States

Fair Division in Theory and Practice

REVEALING THE GEOPOLITICAL GEOMETRY THROUGH SAMPLING JONATHAN MATTINGLY (+ THE TEAM) DUKE MATH

APPORTIONMENT Statement of Position As announced by the State Board, 1966

The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate

What is fairness? - Justice Anthony Kennedy, Vieth v Jubelirer (2004)

Redistricting in Louisiana Past & Present. Regional Educational Presentation Baton Rouge December 15, 2009

What to Do about Turnout Bias in American Elections? A Response to Wink and Weber

Origin of the problem of prison-based gerrymandering

Redistricting 101 Why Redistrict?

Putting an end to Gerrymandering in Ohio: A new citizens initiative

Who Would Have Won Florida If the Recount Had Finished? 1

QUANTIFYING GERRYMANDERING REVEALING GEOPOLITICAL STRUCTURE THROUGH SAMPLING

IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE WESTERN DISTRICT OF WISCONSIN. v. Case No. 15-cv-421-bbc

Experiments: Supplemental Material

Election Day Voter Registration

COMPACTNESS IN THE REDISTRICTING PROCESS

WHERE WE STAND.. ON REDISTRICTING REFORM

Exhibit 4. Case 1:15-cv TDS-JEP Document Filed 09/15/17 Page 1 of 8

What is The Probability Your Vote will Make a Difference?

Measures of Partisan Bias for Legislating Fair Elections

Redistricting in Louisiana Past & Present. Regional Educational Presentation Monroe February 2, 2010

Case 1:17-cv TCB-WSD-BBM Document 94-1 Filed 02/12/18 Page 1 of 37

AP UNITED STATES GOVERNMENT AND POLITICS 2008 SCORING GUIDELINES

EG WEIGHTED DISTRICTS

House Apportionment 2012: States Gaining, Losing, and on the Margin

FAIR DIVISION AND REDISTRICTING

Partisan Advantage and Competitiveness in Illinois Redistricting

No Adults Allowed! Unsupervised Learning Applied to Gerrymandered School Districts

Analysis of AV Voting System Rick Bradford, 24/4/11

Partisan Gerrymandering and the Construction of American Democracy

Iowa Voting Series, Paper 4: An Examination of Iowa Turnout Statistics Since 2000 by Party and Age Group

2010 CENSUS POPULATION REAPPORTIONMENT DATA

Board on Mathematical Sciences & Analytics. View webinar videos and learn more about BMSA at

Random tie-breaking in STV

Forecasting the 2018 Midterm Election using National Polls and District Information

ILLINOIS (status quo)

Rounding decimals or fractions to whole numbers might seem to be one of the most boring subjects ever.

Proposal for the 2016 ANES Time Series. Quantitative Predictions of State and National Election Outcomes

MEMO: The Folmer Redistricting Commission: Neither Independent Nor Nonpartisan

Chapter 4. Modeling the Effect of Mandatory District. Compactness on Partisan Gerrymanders

Personhuballah v. Alcorn, No. 3: 13-cv-678

Lesson 2.4 More Apportionment Models and Paradoxes

A Statistical Test for Partisan Gerrymandering

REFORMING THE ELECTORAL FORMULA IN PEI: THE CASE FOR DUAL-MEMBER MIXED PROPORTIONAL Sean Graham

Enriqueta Aragones Harvard University and Universitat Pompeu Fabra Andrew Postlewaite University of Pennsylvania. March 9, 2000

New Jersey s Redistricting Reform Legislation (S.C.R. 43/A.C.R. 205): Republican Gerrymanders, Democratic Gerrymanders, and Possible Fixes

HOW DUAL MEMBER PROPORTIONAL COULD WORK IN BRITISH COLUMBIA Sean Graham February 1, 2018

Non-Voted Ballots and Discrimination in Florida

Partisan Gerrymandering

Public choice principles of redistricting

Redistricting Reform in the South

Cooper v. Harris, 581 U.S. (2017).

CENTER FOR URBAN POLICY AND THE ENVIRONMENT MAY 2007

Redistricting Matters

Election Day Voter Registration in

Redrawing the Map: Redistricting Issues in Michigan. Jordon Newton Research Associate Citizens Research Council of Michigan

Chapter Four: Chamber Competitiveness, Political Polarization, and Political Parties

Systematic Policy and Forward Guidance

CITIZEN ADVOCACY CENTER

Assessing California s Redistricting Commission

Same Day Voter Registration in

WHAT IS REDISTRICTING. AND WHAT IS THE IMPACT ON MY COUNTY?

Do two parties represent the US? Clustering analysis of US public ideology survey

The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate

The Journey From Census To The United States Supreme Court Linda J. Shorey

The Next Swing Region: Reapportionment and Redistricting in the Intermountain West

Virginia's war of maps: Ethnic coalition challenges all-white leadership

THE SOUTH AUSTRALIAN LEGISLATIVE COUNCIL: POSSIBLE CHANGES TO ITS ELECTORAL SYSTEM

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES

Supreme Court of the United States

Chapter 14. The Causes and Effects of Rational Abstention

Dear Members of the Senate Committee on Rules, Joint Rules, Resolutions and Ethics,

9 Advantages of conflictual redistricting

Measuring the Compliance, Proportionality, and Broadness of a Seat Allocation Method

The Very Picture of What s Wrong in D.C. : Daniel Webster and the American Community Survey

Experimental Computational Philosophy: shedding new lights on (old) philosophical debates

at New York University School of Law A 50 state guide to redistricting

14 Managing Split Precincts

By social science convention, negative numbers indicate Republican advantage and positive numbers indicate Democratic advantage.

Transcription:

Measuring a Gerrymander Daniel Z. Levin There is no such thing as a fair or non-partisan districting plan. Whether intentionally or blindly, such plans involve political choices and have critical effects on the political parties. The various "proposed public interest criteria for redistricting...are not neutral, they are not grounded in broader principles that command general assent, and in many cases they are incoherent and cannot be made to work." 1 Because reapportionment is inherently political, some way to identify or measure its political effects is needed in selecting a districting plan. Yet there are few concrete measures of what is often called a gerrymander, "electoral districts [which] result, or are thought to result, in partisan advantage." 2 The main difficulty in gauging a gerrymander is in finding a coherent basis of comparison; to evaluate a districting proposal's political effects, it is crucial to establish some sort of context in which to do so. One such context is to locate the natural limits, the upper and lower bounds, within which a gerrymander may take place. Since the gerrymanderer cannot change the way people vote or where they live, these demographic factors constrain his efforts by providing a fixed upper limit, a perfect gerrymander. A perfect gerrymander is defined as any set of districts such that no other set, or no possible redistricting, could increase the [number of seats won by] the favored party... A perfect gerrymander is not necessarily unique; there may be infinitely many slightly different sets of districts which allow the favored party to carry the same number of districts. That maximal number, by definition, is unique, and so it provides a standard of comparison for any other set of districts. In order to use this concept, we must be able to calculate that number and show that it is in fact maximal. 3 Before constructing a perfect gerrymander which takes into account the "spatial distribution of partisan or group support," 4 however, a number of practical considerations must be addressed. A database of the region to be gerrymandered must be set up to include population and political information about each of the smallest possible subunits. Although population data comes from the U.S. Census Bureau, the choice of what political data to use in constructing a perfect gerrymander is less clear. At first glance, the precinct-by-precinct returns from the last election would seem to be the best available prediction of how each precinct will vote in the next election. This method, however, is unacceptable because "legislative votes are not 'cross-addable'; that is, it is not accurate to assume that the votes for a Daniel Z. Levin is a sophomore Bachelors of the Arts candidate in American History from the University of Pennsylvania. He is a General Honors student in the Benjamin Franklin Scholars program. 63

64 Michigan Journal of Political Science party's candidate in one district would translate into votes for the same party's candidate in another district." 5 One option which tries to correct this flaw is to calculate a party loyalty measure for each precinct. This method involves making statistical projections of how candidates might fare in new areas. Suppose that in a particular district, a district candidate did worse than his party's candidates for say governor and attorney general. Based on a similar comparison of another district candidate of the same party and the same statewide party candidates, an "expected vote model" 6 can statistically relate the information to project how the first district candidate would have done in a precinct outside his district. If all of a party's district candidates in the state are projected into that one precinct, then the average support received "across all the simulated races gives the expected mean for a candidate from a given party." 7 This procedure, of course, rests on the less than perfect "assumption that the relationship between the district candidates' votes and the statewide candidates' votes would be the same" 8 across the state, in every precinct. A second option for choosing the database's political data is to use party registration figures, which "are not biased by candidate, election, and issuespecific factors." 9 It is a simple matter to see from the last election the lowest party registration percentage at which all, or nearly all, districts or precincts were carried by a party. In fact, data from several election years are easily combined to determine even more accurately what minimum registration level can be considered safe for a party. Despite its easy application, though, this method has several drawbacks. First of all, the registration "figures themselves may be inaccurate and biased, since some of the people who are on the registration rolls for a given area will have since moved or died." 10 This is particularly a problem in areas with a high level of transiency. In addition, this method does nothing to account for an increasing number of independent and unaffiliated voters. Finally, there is only an inexact and "loose correlation between voting behavior and registration." 11 Although loyalty measures and registration figures are two of the best available approximations of party strength, they provide no more than a rough estimate of how each precinct will vote in the next election. There may also be any number of legitimate reasons, such as a long-range electoral trend, for slightly raising or lowering the estimate of a party's minimum "safe" percentage. Once the political data is finally assembled, the only remaining step in compiling a database is to combine the political and population data for each precinct. Unfortunately, since there is "no exact correspondence between the precinct units of the political data and the tract or block units of the census data, the merger process [is] tedious and difficult...[and must be] checked and rechecked many times to eliminate inevitable human errors." 12 Although the job of assembling such a database seems immense, most of the work must be done anyway for the more general task of reapportionment. With access to the

Measuring a Gerrymander 65 reapportioner's computer database, only a few additional adjustments and calculations may be necessary for the task of constructing a perfect gerrymander. We may now proceed with that task. 13 Some frequently used variables in the perfect gerrymander model are as follows: X the space, usually a state, to be redistricted. N the number of districts into which X is to be divided. U any given region in X where there are: P(U) people; F(U) supporters of the favored party; and B(U) supporters of both parties combined. The object is to create for the favored party the largest possible safe region A, with just barely enough support, and to pack the opposition party's supporters into the smallest possible region X-A. Before the actual district lines can be drawn, the safe region A must be constructed. Suppose that there is only one precinct in the space X where the favored party's portion of voter support, F/B, is at its maximum and also that F/B progressively declines when moving away from that precinct. The safe region A should obviously include the maximal precinct and all the other precincts around it which have a level of F/B at or above what is considered safe. Although the remaining precincts will all be carried by the opposition party, some of these precincts can be included in A as long as the overall level F(A)/B(A) does not fall below the favored party's safety mark. Deciding which set of the remaining precincts will maximize P(A) is best done by using a decision tree which considers every possible combination of contiguous precincts. Each decision "path" on the tree ends when the addition of another precinct to A would lower F(A)/B(A) below the safety level. The results of each decision path can be compared and the one with the highest value for P(A) designated as the optimal solution. Unfortunately, since precincts generally contain hundreds of people 14 and states, millions, such a decision tree, with perhaps 1000! solutions, is totally impractical and could not even be computed in the time between censuses. Instead, one must use an algorithm which approximates the maximization of P(A). Once the region A produced by the algorithm approaches the safety limit, however, it may be desirable to switch to the remaining portion of the overall decision tree and find the optimal solution at least from that point. The algorithm for determining the safe region A is as follows. Suppose again that there is only one relative maximum of F/B and include in A that maximal precinct and all the other precincts around it which have a level of F/B at or above what is considered safe. Since districts must be contiguous, consider only the remaining precincts adjacent to a precinct already in A and add the precinct with the highest F/B to A. After checking that this step has not

66 Michigan Journal of Political Science lowered the overall F(A)/B(A) for the new region A beneath the safety mark, repeat the procedure until the addition of the precinct with the next highest F/B would bring the whole region A below the safe level. It may be, however, that the remaining precinct with the highest F/B has a large B which dilutes the region A, making it unsafe. In that case, a smaller precinct, with a slightly lower F/B, could still be added to A, whereas the safer but larger precinct could not. Therefore, consider the remaining precincts adjacent to A in descending order of F/B and add in that order those which do not reduce F(A)/B(A) to below the safe level. If more than one precinct has the same F/B, and all of these precincts cannot be added without making A unsafe, then the precincts should be added one at a time in decreasing order of population P, checking at each step that the overall F(A)/B(A) has not fallen below the safety mark. In the more general case where the space X has several relative maxima of F/B, the algorithm is repeated for each of the separate subregions in X where F/B is at or above the favored party's safety level. If the safe subregions come into contact while expanding, they should be joined. Once the safe region A is maximal, it must be made divisible by districts of equal population. Of the total N number of districts in the space X, each separate safe subregion Ai is entitled to N. P(Ai)/P(X) districts. When this figure is not a whole number, it may be possible to link nearby subregions of A by corridors through the unsafe region X-A to allow additional districts to be formed; for example, linking a subregion of A with enough people for 1.6 districts and another for 1.5 districts. The same procedure, using several corridors, can also be applied to three or more safe subregions whose combined populations would yield additional districts. Slightly arbitrary parameters must be set for the minimum width of and maximum region through which a corridor C may be constructed to connect two safe subregions Ai and Aj. Within these parameters, the best corridor is the one which minimizes the cost of creating the combined subregion Ai+j. Since the corridor itself slightly increases the F number of favored party supporters in the enlarged subregion by F(C) F(Ai) + F(Aj), then, ideally, the corridor should increase the B number of supporters of both parties by the same fraction, maintaining the enlarged subregion at the minimum safe level. Since a corridor contains extremely unsafe territory, though, many more than the ideal number of supporters of both parties are added by having a corridor. The best corridor, however, minimizes the difference between the number of supporters of both parties a corridor adds and the number it should add to preserve the favored party's level of support,

Measuring a Gerrymander 67 B(C) F(C) F(Ai) + F(Aj) {B(A i) + B(Aj)}. The best corridor will minimize the amount of precincts from Ai or Aj that must be abandoned to bring F(Ai+j)/B(Ai+j) back up to the safety mark. If, even using the best corridor, so many precincts must be abandoned that P(Ai+j) is too small to merit the extra districts sought in the first place, then the two subregions cannot be successfully linked by a corridor. When a subregion Ai, which is already maximal, cannot be linked to any others by a corridor, Ai must be reduced in size to an exact number of districts. By shedding those precincts with the lowest F/B, Ai can also become somewhat safer in the process. Once all the safe subregions Ai have been either linked or reduced to an exact number of districts, it only remains to count how many districts are in the favored party's safe region under the perfect gerrymander. While not essential to the model, it may prove useful to draw a set of district lines to demonstrate that it is possible to divide the maximal region A such that every one of its districts is at or a little above the safe level. One way to do so is to draw as many lines radiating from the maximally safe precinct as there will be districts in that subregion of A, creating roughly equal pie-shaped districts. Districts with a population at the wrong level add or subtract precincts from neighboring districts within their subregion Ai. To achieve a desired level of party support, districts "trade" precincts of different partisan strengths with neighboring districts to achieve the correct level. The maximal number of seats won by the favored party in a perfect gerrymander, Nmax, provides an upper limit for what a gerrymanderer can do; finding the lower bound is also useful for putting districting proposals in some sort of context. By constructing a perfect gerrymander for the opposition party, using the same database and procedures described above, one can determine the absolute minimum number of districts that the favored party will carry, Nmin. With the range of possible partisan outcomes of reapportionment thus established, a Gerrymander Index measuring the severity of a gerrymander can be calculated. For any districting plan in which a particular party may anticipate winning N seats, the Gerrymander Index ( ) = N - Nmin Nmax - Nmin. The measure of the districting plan ranges from zero to one, where the higher the fraction, the closer the plan comes to a perfect gerrymander. In addition to the Gerrymander Index, the actual values for Nmin and Nmax may be of interest to those evaluating a redistricting proposal.

68 Michigan Journal of Political Science There is, of course, no ideal value for the index for which a plan should aim. The Gerrymander Index merely provides a framework for discussion of a reapportionment plan and its political effects. What those effects should be is a political question, not a mathematical one. A mathematical measure of a redistricting plan, though, can elevate the political debate to a more informed and meaningful level. Notes 1. Daniel Lowenstein and Jonathan Steinberg, "The Quest for Legislative Districting in the Public Interest: Elusive or Illusory?," UCLA Law Review 33 (1985): 75. 2. Philip Musgrove, The General Theory of Gerrymandering, Sage Professional Papers in American Politics, Vol. 3, Series Number 04-034 (Beverly Hills and London: Sage Publications, 1977), p. 5. 3. Ibid., pp. 6-7. 4. John K. Wildgen and Richard L. Engstrom, "Spatial Distribution of Partisan Support and the Seats/Votes Relationship," Legislative Studies Quarterly 3 (1980): 433. 5. Charles Backstrom, Leonard Robins, and Scott Eller, "Issues in Gerrymandering: An Exploratory Measure of Partisan Gerrymandering Applied to Minnesota," Minnesota Law Review 62 (1978): 1128. 6. Bruce E. Cain, The Reapportionment Puzzle (Berkley and Los Angeles: University of California Press, 1984), p. 139. 7. Ibid., p. 145. 8. Ibid., p. 139. 9. Ibid., p. 141. 10. Ibid., p. 142. 11. Backstrom, Robins, and Eller, "Issues in Gerrymandering," p. 1132.

Measuring a Gerrymander 69 12. Cain, The Reapportionment Puzzle, p. 83. 13. The perfect gerrymander model is taken in large part from pages 8-12, 18-20, 26, and 46-7 of Philip Musgrove's The General Theory of Gerrymandering, but with several substantive changes. In addition to employing a different set of variables, this paper provides a more precise treatment of the case where data are available only in discrete units, i.e., by precinct. The Gerrymander Index at the end of this paper is distinct from the one proposed by Musgrove. 14. Cain, The Reapportionment Puzzle, p. 85.

Michigan Journal of Political Science A University of Michigan Student Journal of Political Studies ARTICLES Sovetskii Dzhaz Soviet Jazz on Trial: The Cultural Revolution of 1928-1932 Mark Garo Matossian From Fraternity to Terror: A Study of Sartre's Theory of Social Ensembles John Carlos Cantú Number 9 Winter 1988 1 20 Grace Award: Theoretical Implications of Global Nuclear Proliferation: Assessing the Validity of the Deterrence Theory Eric J. Urbani 41 NOTES Measuring a Gerrymander Daniel Z. Levin United States Constitution Simulation Dr. Edgar Taylor 63 69 BOOK REVIEWS 73