ILLEGAL FISHING: AN ECONOMIC ANALYSIS

Similar documents
Inefficient utilization of resources

(Non-legislative acts) REGULATIONS

FISHERIES BILL. Memorandum from the Department for Environment, Food and Rural Affairs to the Delegated Powers and Regulatory Reform Committee

COMMISSION IMPLEMENTING REGULATION (EU)

T R A N S L A T I O N REPUBLIC OF PANAMA MINISTRY OF AGRICULTURE DEVELOPMENT. EXECUTIVE DECREE No. 160 (June 6, 2013)

Explanatory Memorandum to The Sea Fishing (Miscellaneous Amendments) Regulations 2018

12083/08 DSI/JGC/kjf DG B III

Official Journal of the European Union. (Non-legislative acts) REGULATIONS

Proposal for a REGULATION OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL

REGULATIONS EN Official Journal of the European Union L 286/1

Proposal for a COUNCIL DECISION

CREEPING JURISDICTION : THE ENLARGEMENT OF ECONOMIC EXLUSIVE ZONES

2014 No. 379 SEA FISHERIES. The Sea Fishing (Points for Masters of Fishing Boats) (Scotland) Regulations 2014

Proposal for a COUNCIL DECISION

WHEN IS THE PREPONDERANCE OF THE EVIDENCE STANDARD OPTIMAL?

Proposal for a COUNCIL IMPLEMENTING DECISION

A NOTE ON MONITORING COSTS AND VOTER FRAUD

Solving the "Tragedy of the Commons": An Alternative to Privatization*

The Choice of Environmental Regulatory Enforcement by Lobby Groups

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE THEORY OF PUBLIC ENFORCEMENT OF LAW. A. Mitchell Polinsky Steven Shavell

Official Journal of the European Union L 348/17

Facts and Figures: Thailand s Tangible Progress in Combatting IUU Fishing and Forced Labour

CONVENTION ON THE CONSERVATION AND MANAGEMENT OF HIGH SEAS FISHERIES RESOURCES IN THE NORTH PACIFIC OCEAN

Plea Bargaining with Budgetary Constraints and Deterrence

Quantifying Harm for Breaches of Antitrust Rules A European Union Perspective

Agenda Item J.3.a Attachment 1 November ST MEETING OF THE INTER-AMERICAN TROPICAL TUNA COMMISSION SUMMARY OF OUTCOMES.

Thailand Taking Action against Illegal, Unreported and Unregulated Fishing (IUU) (Continued)

Damages Actions for Breach of the EC Antitrust Rules

Fisheries Bill EXPLANATORY NOTES

Conf Introduction from the sea. (Rev. CoP16)

NEW HORIZONS IN THE LAW OF THE SEA

CORRUPTION AND OPTIMAL LAW ENFORCEMENT. A. Mitchell Polinsky Steven Shavell. Discussion Paper No /2000. Harvard Law School Cambridge, MA 02138

TREATY BETWEEN THE GOVERNMENT OF CANADA AND THE GOVERNMENT OF THE UNITED STATES OF AMERICA ON PACIFIC COAST ALBACORE TUNA VESSELS AND PORT PRIVILEGES

Port State Measures Agreement: Why Seafood Buyers Should Help

2018 No. 643 SEA FISHERIES. The Sea Fishing (Miscellaneous Amendments) Regulations 2018

The Fairness of Sanctions: Some Implications for Optimal Enforcement Policy

EU-MERCOSUR CHAPTER. Article 1. Objectives and Scope

Sentencing Guidelines, Judicial Discretion, And Social Values

I (Acts whose publication is obligatory)

Rights-Based Management in International Tuna Fisheries. Dale Squires IIFET 2014

IUU Fishing and the rights of work in international law. Mazara del Vallo, 1 December note from. Brandt Wagner. Senior Maritime Specialist

Dr Nengye Liu, Hobart, 6 July The European Union and Conservation of Marine Living Resources in Antarctica

CONSERVATION MEASURE (2009) Scheme to promote compliance by non-contracting Party vessels with CCAMLR conservation measures.

Official Journal of the European Union

FOOD LAW ENFORCEMENT POLICY

INTER-AMERICAN TROPICAL TUNA COMMISSION 90 TH MEETING

MODEL ANIMAL WELFARE PROVISIONS FOR EU TRADE AGREEMENTS

Economic Analysis of Public Law Enforcement and Criminal Law

CITIZENSHIP AND SOCIETY: Old and New Ideas for Challenging Times

Trade and Sustainable Development in EU Trade Agreements. DG TRADE Civil Society Dialogue Meeting 11 June 2014

TRADE AND SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT

2015 No. 191 SEA FISHERIES, ENGLAND AND WALES SEA FISHERIES, NORTHERN IRELAND. The Sea Fishing (Enforcement and Miscellaneous Provisions) Order 2015

Seafood Watch, Liberty Asia & Sustainable Fisheries Partnership: Seafood Slavery Risk Tool Fishery Profile Data Analysis

THE CFP- INFRINGEMENT PROCEDURES AND IMPOSED SANCTIONS THROUGHOUT THE EU

Escalating Penalties for Repeat Offenders

CURRICULUM VITAE. Positions at International Scientific Associations President of the European Public Choice Society, since April 2017.

INTERNATIONAL TRADE ALERT

FOURTH REGULAR SESSION 3-7 December 2007 Tumon, Guam, USA JOINT MEETING OF TUNA RFMOs, KOBE, JAPAN, JANUARY 2007: OUTCOMES

CHAPTER TWELVE TRADE AND SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT

However, it is important to consider the following aspects of the document in reference:

Lobbying and Bribery

Proposal for a REGULATION OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL

I. Background: An Exclusive Economic Zone (EEZ) is an area of water a certain distance off the coast where countries have sovereign rights to

The International Anti-Corruption Movement

Unintended Consequences of Enforcement in a Fisheries Institution: Results from an Artefactual Experiment in Tanzania

TITLE 51 - MANAGEMENT OF MARINE RESOURCES 51 MIRC Ch. 4 CHAPTER 4. FISHING ACCESS AND LICENSING ARRANGEMENT OF SECTIONS

Principle of Proportionality in Sentencing and Economic Approach in Criminology

Law of the sea. UN Convention on the Law of the Sea

The Cost-Benefit Analysis of Crime*

Trade and Sustainable Development in EU Trade Agreements

Policy brief: Making Europe More Competitive for Highly- Skilled Immigration - Reflections on the EU Blue Card 1

FISHERIES ACT CHAPTER 378 LAWS OF KENYA

FIRST MEETING OF THE PARTIES TO THE FAO AGREEMENT ON PORT STATE MEASURES. Oslo, Norway, May 2017

Overview. IFS: Resolution Conf (Rev. CoP16) IFS-related Decisions adopted at CoP16:

DISSENTING OPINION OF JUDGE AD HOC SHEARER

Introduction From the Sea (IFS)

COUNCIL OF THE EUROPEAN UNION. Brussels, 18 March 2009 (OR. en) 17426/08 Interinstitutional File: 2007/0228 (CNS) MIGR 130 SOC 800

29 May 2017 Without prejudice CHAPTER [XX] TRADE AND SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT. Article X.1. Objectives and Scope

SEPARATE OPINION OF JUDGE COT

Otto von Guericke - University Magdeburg

RECENT DEVELOPMENTS ACTUALITIÉS THE EU AFRICA PARTNERSHIP IN THE FIGHT AGAINST IUU FISHING

2010 No. 238 SEA FISHERIES

Questions and Answers on the EU common immigration policy

Antitrust: Commission introduces settlement procedure for cartels frequently asked questions (see also IP/08/1056)

International Law Enforcement Cooperation in the Fisheries Sector: A Guide for Law Enforcement Practitioners

CONVENTION ON THE CONSERVATION AND MANAGEMENT OF FISHERY RESOURCES IN THE SOUTH EAST ATLANTIC OCEAN (as amended by the Commission on 4 October 2006)

Exclusive Economic Zone Act

PUBLIC ENFORCEMENT OF LAW

RAS/16/11/USA SEA Fisheries: Strengthened Coordination to Combat Labour Exploitation and Trafficking in Fisheries in Southeast Asia

COUNCIL OF THE EUROPEAN UNION 5121/10 AGRI

STATUTORY INSTRUMENTS. S.I. No. 89 of 2018 EUROPEAN UNION (COMMON FISHERIES POLICY) (POINT SYSTEM) REGULATIONS 2018

The Lisbon Agenda and the External Action of the European Union

Responding to Illegal Foreign Fishing in Indonesian and Australian waters a comparative analysis PROFESSOR MELDA KAMIL ARIADNO AND ALISTAIR WYVILL SC

**********************

Annex 1 - Fragmented Ocean Governance: Positioning UN Environment within the Ecosystem of Ocean Management Arrangements

Declaration on the Interpretation and Implementation of the Convention on the Future Multilateral Cooperation in North-East Atlantic Fisheries

Sanction as a Legal Term in the Law of the European Union. The Term and Its Function within the System of Remedies Foreseen by European Union Law

Assessing law as a factor towards the Aichi Biodiversity Targets 1

REGIONAL CONVENTION ON FISHERIES COOPERATION AMONG AFRICAN STATES BORDERING THE ATLANTIC OCEAN

21ST SPECIAL MEETING OF THE INTERNATIONAL COMMISSION FOR THE CONSERVATION OF ATLANTIC TUNAS (ICCAT) (Dubrovnik, Croatia, November, 2018)

Transcription:

ILLEGAL FISHING: AN ECONOMIC ANALYSIS COELHO Manuel Pacheco, (P), FILIPE José António Candeias Bonito, (P), FERREIRA Manuel Alberto M., (P), PEDRO Isabel, (P) Abstract. Monitoring and enforcement considerations have been largely ignored in the study of fishery management. This paper explores this issue with a formal model of fisheries law enforcement to show how fishing firms behave and fisheries policies are affected by costly, imperfect enforcement of fisheries law. This model combines standard Economics of Fisheries analysis with the Theory of Crime and Punishment of Becker. The conclusions of the model are used to discuss the reform of the control and monitoring regime of the Common Fisheries Policy. Key words. Fisheries, Enforcement, Common Fisheries Policy Mathematics Subject Classification: Primary 65K10; Secondary. 1 Introduction Public enforcement of law, that is, the use of public agents to detect and sanction violators of legal rules is an obvious important subject. First literature on the subject of law enforcement dates from eighteen century: Montesquieu (1748), Beccaria (1767) and Bentham (1789). Curiously, after the sophisticated and expansive analysis of Bentham, the subject of enforcement lay essentially dormant in economic scholarship (POLINSKY and SHAVELL (2000)), until the influential article of Gary BECKER (1968), Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach. In the context of Fisheries Economics, the problem can be seen as an externality arising when exclusive property rights are absent (CHEUNG (1970)). And that absence depends on, among other things, the costs of defining and enforcing exclusivity. Efficiency considerations, by itself, don't dictate the choice of a certain property rights regime. In some systems of property rights (as the case of common property") the re-alignment of the property rights can have a very high or even prohibitive cost. The establishment and enforcement of a system of rights depends, of course, on efficiency considerations, but also on the individual preferences and the political and social realities in a

community. These include the lack of means (or other insufficiencies) of the administration to control and enforce the execution of legal rules (DEMSETZ (1967)). Most of the literature on fisheries management and regulation implicitly assumes law can be perfectly and costless enforced. Despite the astute observations in the traditional literature (see, for example, SCOTT (1979)), monitoring and enforcement considerations have been largely ignored in the study of fishery management. This paper explores this issue with a formal model of fisheries law enforcement to show how fishing firms behave and fisheries policies are affected by costly, imperfect enforcement of fisheries law. This model combines standard Economics of Fisheries analysis with the Theory of Crime and Punishment of Becker. The conclusions of the model are used to discuss the reform of the monitoring and control regime of the Common Fisheries Policy. 2 Illegal fishing By definition, anything that is an infringement of the law is illegal. Illegal fishing therefore covers a wide range of behaviour, which can take place at several levels. For example, for members of the European Union, any violation of national laws or EU regulations, or failure to comply with the recommendations of international bodies, especially those of Regional Fisheries Organisations, constitutes an infringement. Illegal fishing has always existed, but, in recent decades, there has been a sharp rise in violating activities, due to several factors such as the significant technical progress in motorization, freezing techniques, improved gear and new forms of stocks detection and information. At the same time, new forms of surveillance and detection of violators were introduced. Obviously, it s impossible to quantify or qualify infringements. They are known to take place at all levels and to take different forms at different times. Some violations are detected but many remain unnoticed. Infringements take the traditional forms of fishing over the quota or using nonpermitted mesh-size, but are also in situations of non-permitted by-catches or transshipment; even in the fake world of convenience flags. The vast majority of fishing activities worldwide take place within EEZs or inshore zones. Fraud committed on the High Seas is consequently marginal, but it seems that it went on growing during the 80s and 90s and made the cause of many fish wars. Illegal fishing occurs at all stages of fishing activity: on the vessel, at landing or during commercial operations. A large number of offenders are fishermen motivated by various interests: the lure of short term profit offered by certain species, the financial difficulties fitting vessels with regulatory gear, the need to secure a return on a major investment, the weight of tradition. But fishermen are not the only ones involved. Fraud can take place along the entire channel. Note that the possibilities after landing are tremendous. National administrations sometimes bear part of the blame. Every state is responsible for enforcing the existing rules and monitoring activities (policing its territory, conducting controls and penalising offenders). At the Community level, the responsibility for wrongdoing falls down on Member-states. At international level it is more difficult to oblige sovereign states to enforce rules, because there is no supranational authority. Conventions and Treaties incur the liability only of the states that ratify them. 168 volume 1 (2008), number 2

This is also the cause of proliferation of flags of convenience, a frequent occurrence on the High Seas, which many see as the most pernicious element of illegal, unregulated and unreported fisheries (IUU). The globalisation of the economy, by liberalising markets and capital movements, has multiplied the number of ship owners registering their vessels in a country other than their own. Increasingly binding regulations and the burden of social charges on employers contributes to the development of this phenomenon. Fishermen are interested in this new game rules: it enables them to side-step the constraints imposed in their countries, gaining free access to resources, avoiding controls and improving competitiveness. For the state, there are, also, advantages: tax revenues and creation of jobs. The states involved are usually developing countries lacking the will and the means to set effective controls (even less if the action take place in areas and resources that are not theirs). 3 Crime and Punishment Theoretical Analysis Despite the enormous volume of literature on Fisheries Economics, only a few numbers of papers are devoted to the issue of enforcement. It has always been the neglected element in fishery management (SUTINEN and HENNESSEY (1986)). Our approach explores this issue with a formal model to show how fishing firms behave and to study how fisheries policies are affected by costly, imperfect enforcement of fisheries regulation. This model (See SUTINEN, J. and ANDERSEN, P. (1985)) combines standard Economics of Fisheries analysis with the Theory of Crime and Punishment of Becker. The fundamental problem in fisheries management is to obviate the tendency towards overexploitation of the resources under open access. Regulation methods used to curb this tendency of overfishing and overcapacity includes gear restrictions, area and seasonal closures, TACs, ITQs, limiting entry and other forms of reducing fishing effort. Assume that, whatever means are applied to reduce catch rates, any catch level above the level of the permitted quota for a certain fishing, q*, is illegal. If we suppose a system of individual nontransferable quotas, the amount of the individual firm catch above its quota (q i q i *) is illegal. If detected and convicted, a penalty fee is imposed on the firm in an amount given by f, f = f (q i q i *), where f >0, if q i > q i * ; and f =0, otherwise; and f / q 0 ; 2 f / q 2 0 ; q i > q i *. We assume that the function f(.) is continuous and differentiable for all q i * > q i.. This penalty fee has a finite upper bound and each firm is assumed to face the same penalty fee schedule. An individual firm s profit before penalty is given by Π i (q i,x) = p q i c i (q i,x), where p denotes the price of fish, x is the size of fish stock and c(.) is the cost function. We assume that firms are price takers. In an imperfect law enforcement regime not every violator is detected and convicted. Let the probability of detection and conviction be given by θ, and, to simplify, let us assume that all firms face the same probability. If detected and convicted of a violation, a firm s profit will be Π i (q i,x) - f (q i q i *) ; if not, Π i (q i,x). So, expected profits are 1) θ [Π i (q i,x) - f (q i q i *)] + (1-θ ) Π i (q i,x) Assuming firms are risk neutral and maximising expected profits, each q i is determined by the first order condition (subscripts other than i denote partial derivatives) volume 1 (2008), number 2 169

2) Π q i (q i,x) θf q (q i q i *). The solution to 2) for one form of the marginal penalty schedule, f q, has a clear economic meaning: For a given stock size (x), the firm sets its catch rate at a level in excess of its quota, where marginal profits equal the expected marginal penalty. If there were no penalty for fishing beyond legal quota, or if there were no probability of being detected and convicted (f = 0 or θ = 0) the firm would set its catch at the open access catch rate, q i 0. If the expected marginal penalty schedule lies above the marginal profit schedule for all qi above the legal quota, the firm s optimum catch equals its quota. Firms with no quota have an expected net gain for entering, illegally, in the fishery, if their expected marginal penalty schedule begins below their marginal profit schedule. This approach reveals the importance of empirical studies trying to estimate the factors that ensure compliance with the regulation. These studies give important basis for public authority decision about the actions to be implemented. STIGLER (1970) argues that public authorities have four basic means to improve compliance: - minimise the chances that violations will go undetected, - maximise the probability that sanctions will follow the detection of violations, - speed up the process from time to detection to assignment of sanction, - make the sanctions large. There is dispute among experts about the best alternatives. Some scholars have argued that the probability of being detected is more important than the size or magnitude of the sanction, while others argue that making the charging time follow as closely as possible to the detection of illegal behaviour is the most important factor in enhancing compliance. Others, also, put in evidence the level of expenditure oriented to monitoring activities. Global enforcement costs equation can be represented by E (q,x,q*),where E/ q<0, E/ x>0, E/ q*>0. That is: - A reduction in the catch level requires an increase in enforcement costs. - Increase in the fish stock or quota requires greater enforcement costs to achieve a given catch level. - The size of the quota also affects enforcement. The least cost quota depends on the form of the marginal penalty schedule and is another question to investigate further. 4 The Reform of the Common Fisheries Policy - Concluding Remarks Since 2003, Common Fisheries Policy (CFP) is developing a process of Reform. The Control and Monitoring Regime of common fisheries is one of the most important subjects where this reform takes place. Applying theoretical analysis to the guidelines of CFP reform, suggests the following concluding remarks: - Implementing Community policies in Member States is never easy, especially when myopic individual interests do not match with long term collective interests. This is the case in fisheries. Fishermen do not have greater propensity to altruism than the rest of the society; so, they are little inclined to refrain catches for the sake of a clear conscience, if they think their competitors are less scrupulous (EUROPEAN COMISSION/ DGF (2000)). That is, without a clear and effective policy of control and enforcement, the Commission is certain that the Tragedy of the Commons will result and that overfishing and overcapacity will occur. The reform of CFP insists in the philosophy of intervention of its early days, when the Commission put the problem of control in terms of ethical reasons: It s the only way to assure that 170 volume 1 (2008), number 2

the sacrifices of some member states in the recovery of the stocks are not in vain because of the irresponsible action of others (COMISSÃO EUROPEIA (1976)). According to BECKER (1968), individuals rationally decide whether or not engage in criminal activities by comparing the expected returns to crime with the legitimate business. His main thesis is that crime is less attractive if the government increases the probability and severity of punishment. Since imposing a fine is costless, this fine should equal an individual s entire wealth and be complemented by a probability of punishment to optimally deter crime (GAROUPA (2000)). The analysis of the Commission proposals seems to give a special attention to the increase of the probability of detection as a means to deter criminal behaviour and increase compliance with regulation. Introduction of severe penalties is not in the first line of measures to control illegal fishing. Of course they are considered and an important effort to clear define the legal procedures to penalise the violators, is made. But they are not in the centre of the policy. The reasons stand, perhaps, in this: The Commission believes that the financial support will guarantee the indispensable means of surveillance and control to the Member States. This will increase the deterrence capacity of control in Member States, in uniform manner, and increase transparency and trust between partners. But the Commission also knows that legal administration, in the Member States, have significant differences and that judicial machinery has a great inertia. The capacity and efficiency of Member States justice is not only a question of financial means devoted to his mission. It has also cultural and historical roots. It s virtually impossible to put all the Member States in uniform position in terms of speed and severity of penalties application. References [1.] BECKER, G. (1968); Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach, Journal of Political Economy, Vol.86, pp169-217. [2.] BROWN, G. (2000); Renewable Natural Resource Management and Use without Markets, Journal of Economic Literature, Vol.38, pp 875-914. [3.] CHEUNG, S. (1970); The Structure of a Contract and the Theory of a Non-Exclusive Resource, Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 13, pp 49-70. [4.] CLARK, C. (1980); Towards a Predictive Model for The Economic Regulation of Commercial Fisheries, Canadian Journal of Fisheries and Aquatic Sciences, Vol.37, pp1111-1129. [5.] CLARK; C. and MUNRO, G.(1975); The Economics of Fishing and Modern Capital Theory: A Simplified Approach, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, Vol. 2, pp 92-106. [6.] COELHO, M. (2002); Blue Europe Revisited: The Reform of the Common Fisheries Policy, Vth International Workshop on European Economy, CEDIN / ISEG. [7.] COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES (2004); Communication from the Commission to the Council and the European Parliament, Improving the monitoring of industrial fishing within the EU, COM (2004) 167 final, Brussels. [8.] COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES (2003); Communication from the Commission, Compliance with the Rules of the Common Fisheries Policy, Compliance Work Plan and Scoreboard, COM (2003) 344 final, Brussels. volume 1 (2008), number 2 171

[9.] COMISSÃO DAS COMUNIDADES EUROPEIAS (2003); Proposta de Decisão do Conselho relativa a uma contribuição financeira da Comunidade para os programas de controlo da pesca dos Estados-Membros, COM(2003), 706 final., Bruxelas. [10.] DEMSETZ, H. (1967); Toward a Theory of Property Rights, American Economic Review, Vol. 57, pp 347-359. [11.] EUROPEAN COMMMISSION (2001), Green Paper on the Future of the Common Fisheries Policy, Brussels. [12.] EUROPEAN COMMISSION/ DIRECTORATE-GENERAL FOR FISHERIES (2003); A level playing field for better enforcement of CFP rules, Fishing in Europe, N.19,pp 4-7. [13.] EUROPEAN COMMISSION/ DIRECTORATE-GENERAL FOR FISHERIES (2001); Illegal Fisheries: the international community springs into action, Fishing in Europe, N.6, pp 6-9. [14.] EUROPEAN COMMISSION/ DIRECTORATE-GENERAL FOR FISHERIES (2000); Monitoring of fishing activities, Fishing in Europe, N. 4, pp 6-9. [15.] FAO (1995); Código de Conduta para uma Pesca Responsável, Ed. da Escola de Pesca e da Marinha do Comércio. [16.] GAROUPA, N. (2000), Optimal Law Enforcement and Criminal Organization, Seminário do Departamento de Economia Nº 8/2000, ISEG/UTL. [17.] POLINSKY, A. and SHAVELL, S. (2000); The Economic Theory of Public Enforcement of Law, Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 38, pp 45-76. [18.] SCOTT, A. (1979); Development of Economic Theory on Fisheries Regulation, Journal of the Fisheries Research Board of Canada, Vol. 36, pp 725-741. [19.] STIGLER, G. (1970); The Optimum Enforcement of Laws, Journal of Political Economy, pp 526-536. [20.] SUTINEN, J. and ANDERSEN, P. (1985); The Economics of Fisheries Law Enforcement, Land Economics; Vol. 61, pp387-397. [21.] SUTINEN, J. and GAUVIN, J. (1989); An Econometric Study of Regulatory Enforcement and Compliance in the Commercial Inshore Lobster Fishery of Massachusetts, in Neher (ed), Rights Based Fishing, Kluwer Academic Publishers, pp. 415-428. [22.] SUTINEN, J. and HENNESSEY, T. (1986), Enforcement: The Neglected Element in Fishery Management, in Miles, Pealy and Stokes (eds), Natural Resource Policy and Management: Essays in Honor of James Crutchfield, pp185-213. [23.] TIETENBERG, T. (2003); Environmental and Natural Resource Economics; sixth edition, Addison Wesley. Current address Manuel Francisco Pacheco Coelho, Professor Auxiliar ISEG Instituto Superior de Economia e Gestão SOCIUS Centro de Investigação em Sociologia Económica e das Organizações Rua do Quelhas, 6, 1200-781 Lisboa (Lisbon, Portugal), Tel.+351 213 925 800 e-mail: coelho@iseg.utl.pt José António Candeias Bonito Filipe, Professor Auxiliar ISCTE - Instituto Superior de Ciências do Trabalho e da Empresa UNIDE Unidade de Investigação e Desenvolvimento Empresarial 172 volume 1 (2008), number 2

Av. Forças Armadas 1649-026 Lisboa (Lisbon, Portugal), Tel.+351 217 903 000 e-mail: jose.filipe@iscte.pt Manuel Alberto Martins Ferreira, Professor Catedrático ISCTE - Instituto Superior de Ciências do Trabalho e da Empresa UNIDE Unidade de Investigação e Desenvolvimento Empresarial Av. Forças Armadas 1649-026 Lisboa (Lisbon, Portugal), Tel.+351 217 903 000 e-mail: manuel.ferreira@iscte.pt Maria Isabel Craveiro Pedro, Professor Auxiliar IST - Instituto Superior Técnico (Technical University of Lisbon) CEGIST Centro de Estudos Gestão Av. Rovisco Pais 1100-099 Lisboa (Lisbon, Portugal), Tel.+351 21 423 35 07 e-mail: ipedro@ist.utl.pt volume 1 (2008), number 2 173

174 volume 1 (2008), number 2