Introduction: Seven Decades of the IS-LM Model

Similar documents
Readings in the History of Modern Macroeconomics

Part 1. Economic Theory and the Economics Profession

Program and Readings 2014 Summer Institute The History of Economics

CURRICULUM VITAE ROBERT E. LUCAS, JR. Birth Date: September 15, 1937, Yakima, WA Home Address: 320 West Oakdale Avenue, # 1903, Chicago, IL 60657

A History of Economic Theory

Monetary Theory and Central Banking By Allan H. Meltzer * Carnegie Mellon University and The American Enterprise Institute

Modigliani and Keynes

IJOESS Year: 9, Vol:9, Issue: 33 SEPTEMBER 2018

Review of Michel de Vroey s A history of macroeconomics from Keynes to Lucas and beyond. New York: Cambridge University Press, 2016, 429 pp.

Figure 1.1 Output of the U.S. economy, Copyright 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 1-2

PAPER No. : Basic Microeconomics MODULE No. : 1, Introduction of Microeconomics

List of Nobel Memorial Prize laureates in Economics

Macroeconomics and the Phillips Curve Myth by James Forder

A Dictionary Article on Axel Leijonhufvud s. On Keynesian Economics and the Economics of Keynes: A Study in Monetary Theory.

General view of the economy The less the government is involved in the economy the better it will perform.

From Muddling through to the Economics of Control: Views of Applied Policy from J. N. Keynes to Abba Lerner. David Colander.

Teaching Macroeconomics

Karl Brunner, Monetarist

The Keynesian Revolution and IS-LM: From Enigma to Conundrum

ECONOMICS AND COMPARATIVE POLITICS FORM IV

Thinkwell s Homeschool Economics Course Lesson Plan: 36 weeks

From Muddling Through to the Economics of Control: View of Applied Policy from J.N. Keynes to Abba Lerner. David Colander.

1. At the completion of this course, students are expected to: 2. Define and explain the doctrine of Physiocracy and Mercantilism

4. Philip Cortney, The Economic Munich: The I.T.O. Charter, Inflation or Liberty, the 1929 Lesson (New York: Philosophical Library, 1949).

Prior to 1940, the Austrian School was known primarily for its contributions

Dr Kalecki on Mr Keynes

DECODING J. M. KEYNES' WORKS: AN ANALYSIS OF THE INTERPRETATIONS OF KEYNESIAN ECONOMICS MELINDA SIMONFFY. Senior Sophister

On the Irrelevance of Formal General Equilibrium Analysis

The Rationale for Independent Monetary Policy

Milton Friedman's Contributions to Macroeconomics and Their Influence

Oskar Lange or how IS-LM came to be interpreted as a Walrasian model

Overview of the Austrian School theories of capital and business cycles and implications for agent-based modeling

MICROECONOMICS. Topics. 2. Competition as strategic interaction: elements of non-cooperative game theory and classical models of oligopoly

ECONOMICS 202A READING LIST. Main Textbook: David Romer, Advanced Macroeconomics, Third Edition (New York: McGraw-Hill, 2005).

A Comparison of the Theories of Joseph Alois Schumpeter and John. Maynard Keynes. Aubrey Poon

JAMES TOBIN AND MODERN MONETARY THEORY

What was lost with IS-LM* Roger E. Backhouse University of Birmingham. and. David Laidler University of Western Ontario

Portland State University Department of Economics

Samuelson, Keynes and the search for a general theory of economics Backhouse, Roger

PAPERS FOR APRIL 10 POSSIBLE TOPICS

Communicating a Systematic Monetary Policy

Friedman and the Bernanke-Taylor Debate on Rules versus Constrained Discretion

An Appeal for Rationality in the Policy Activism Debate

Systematic Policy and Forward Guidance

I would like to add my voice to the chorus in thanking President Fisher and the

Influencing Expectations in the Conduct of Monetary Policy

Chapter 25. Rational Expectations: Implications for Policy

Milton Friedman and the Evolution of Macroeconomics

In Search of Lost Time: the Neoclassical Synthesis. M. De Vroey and P. Garcia Duarte. Discussion Paper

Finance and Economics Discussion Series Divisions of Research & Statistics and Monetary Affairs Federal Reserve Board, Washington, D.C.

New Macroeconomics Teaching for a New Era: Instability, Inequality, and Environment

The History of Macroeconomics Viewed Against the Background of the Marshall-Walras Divide

ITRN Syllabus Macroeconomic Economic Policy in a Global Economy Fall 2017 Monday `7.10 pm pm Founders Hall 470

Documents de Travail du Centre d Economie de la Sorbonne

Three Revolutions in Macroeconomics: Their Nature and Influence

SCHOOLS OF ECONOMICS. Classical, Keynesian, & Monetary

10/7/2013 SCHOOLS OF ECONOMICS. Classical, Keynesian, & Monetary. as Neo- Classical Supply Side Trickle Down Free Trade CLASSICAL THEORY

THE KEYNESIAN REVOLUTION

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES

Economics and Reality. Harald Uhlig 2012

ROY J. RUFFIN. Department of Economics University of Houston Houston, Texas (713) FAX (713)

econstor Make Your Publications Visible.

THE ROLE OF FINANCIAL POLICY

Edmond Malinvaud s Criticisms to New Classical Economics: Restoring the Rationale of the Old Keynesians Stance

ECON 5060/6060 History of Economic Doctrines

The Relationship between Real Wages and Output: Evidence from Pakistan

Government 7035: Political Economy

Commentary: How Should Monetary Policymakers Respond to the New Challenges of Global Economic Integration?

VITA. Short-Run Reserve Position Adjustment of New York City Banks (Chairman: Milton Friedman)

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

From business cycle theory to the theory of employment: Alvin Hansen and Paul Samuelson Backhouse, Roger

The Macroeconomist as Scientist and Engineer

Hawks and Doves at the Federal Reserve. Michael D Bordo, Rutgers University and the Hoover Institution, Stanford University

COURSE INFORMATION ECON 3008 History of Economic Thought 3 2 (January-May 2014) 3 ECON 1001and ECON 1002

Department of Economics Research Report Series

The economics and political economy of Milton Friedman: An old Keynesian critique

Course Title. Professor. Contact Information

University of California, Berkeley ECONOMICS 210C / ECONOMICS 236A MONETARY HISTORY SYLLABUS PART I: THE EFFECTS OF POLICY

Monetary Rules and Committees

Monetary Policy Strategies: A Central Bank Panel

GENERAL INTRODUCTION FIRST DRAFT. In 1933 Michael Kalecki, a young self-taught economist, published in

An Essay in Bobology 1. W.MAX CORDEN University of Melbourne, Melbourne, Australia

The Restoration of Welfare Economics

SYLLABUS. Economics 555 History of Economic Thought. Office: Bryan Bldg. 458 Fall Procedural Matters

Keynes Critique of Classical Economics

Don Patinkin and The Origins of Postwar Monetary Orthodoxy

A Perspective on the Economy and Monetary Policy

Quotes from The Economic Consequences of Peace - (1920)

THE NEW CLASSICAL COUNTER-REVOLUTION: FALSE PATH OR ILLUMINATING COMPLEMENT?

Athol Fitzgibbons Downloaded from Elgar Online at 03/21/ :12:56PM via free access

Final Paper Topics. I. Socialism and Economic Planning: Literary Perspectives

Keynes as an Interpreter of Classical Economics

Michelle R. Garfinkel

List of Important Events in Business Cycle Theory

New macroeconomics teaching for a new era: instability, inequality, and environment

Quarterly Journal of SPRING 2015 ARTICLES VOL. 18 N O. 1. Austrian. Economics. The. Garrison on Keynes... 3 Edward W. Fuller

ITRN Syllabus Macroeconomic Economic Policy in a Global Economy Fall 2018 Thursday 7.20 pm pm Founders Hall 311

As Joseph Stiglitz sees matters, the euro suffers from a fatal. Book Review. The Euro: How a Common Currency. Journal of FALL 2017

On Why There Is No Milton Friedman Today:

The Two Faces of Emergence in Economics Mark Kuperberg

Transcription:

Introduction: Seven Decades of the IS-LM Model Michel De Vroey and Kevin D. Hoover For some twenty-five years after the end of World War II, the IS-LM model dominated macroeconomics. With the advent of the new classical macroeconomics in the early 1970s, that dominance was at first challenged and then broken. Yet the IS-LM model lives on. While no longer central to the graduate training of most macroeconomists or to cutting-edge macroeconomic research, the IS-LM model continues to be a mainstay of undergraduate textbooks, finds wide application in areas of applied macroeconomics away from the front lines of macroeconomic theory, and lies at the conceptual core of most government and commercial macroeconometric models. What explains the rise, the fall, and the persistence of the IS-LM model? This volume presents essays from the HOPE conference held 25 27 April 2003 at Duke University that provide partial answers to this question. In addition to the ten essays from the conference, we are fortunate to be able to reprint an address delivered by Robert Lucas in conjunction with the conference. Professor Lucas made his remarks at a reception celebrating the commitment of his professional papers to Duke University s Rare Book, Manuscript, and Special Collections Library, where they will be housed with the papers of other distinguished economists received through the Economists Papers Project. As Lucas is one of the central players in the intellectual movement that ultimately dethroned the IS-LM model, his lecture stands We thank the editors of HOPE Craufurd Goodwin, Neil De Marchi, and E. Roy Weintraub for giving us the opportunity to organize the conference on the IS-LM model. We also thank Paul Dudenhefer for his unstinting support in helping to organize the conference and in the editorial production of the current volume.

2 Michel De Vroey and Kevin D. Hoover on an altogether different plane than the essays from the conference. It may be regarded reasonably as an eyewitness account by an observant and reflective participant. The 1930s were years of turmoil for economists concerned with the problems of business cycles. Although macroeconomic questions were among the oldest in economics, macroeconomics as a field was struggling to grow into self-consciousness. The term macroeconomics was first coined by Ragnar Frisch in 1933. 1 Economists such as Erik Lindahl, Friedrich Hayek, and John Hicks were struggling with dynamics time and expectations and beginning to create formalized models. Frisch and Jan Tinbergen, among others, started to build statistically estimated models. The conceptual basis not only for macroeconomic models, but even for national accounting, was still hotly debated. History, as is frequently said, is written by the victors. In light of the postwar dominance of Keynesian macroeconomics, it would be easy to overlook the fact that John Maynard Keynes s General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money (1936) by no means swept the boards in the macroeconomic debates of the mid-1930s. The General Theory, as the essay of Roger Backhouse and David Laidler reminds us, offered a systematic account of the macroeconomy that, on the one hand, built on numerous antecedents and, on the other hand, ignored hard-won theoretical achievements in the areas of economic dynamics. Keynes adopted a Marshallian approach, both in the sense that he deliberately echoed Marshall s microeconomic analysis in a new macroeconomic setting and in the sense that he adopted Marshall s notion that radical simplification is sometimes necessary to achieve a practically applicable analysis (Marshall [1885] 1925; see also Friedman [1949] 1953, 1955). Around the same time that Keynes s General Theory provided an account of aggregate general equilibrium, mathematical economics began to make considerable strides in developing the underpinnings for the individually based general equilibrium model that started with Léon Walras and culminated in Kenneth Arrow and Gerard Debreu s proof of the existence of general equilibrium in the early 1950s. The essay in this volume by Michel De Vroey explores the relationships and tensions between these 1. Jean-Paul Fitoussi and Kumaraswamy Velupillai (1993) report that Frisch used the term in lectures, whereas Lindahl may have been the first to use it in print. The term macrodynamic(s) was, however, already current in the middle to the end of the 1930s. The earliest example in the JSTOR journal archive is in an article by Edward Theiss (1935).

Seven Decades of the IS-LM Model 3 competing visions of general equilibrium and between the Marshallian and Walrasian methodologies. In particular, it claims that the IS-LM model belonged to the Marshallian rather than the Walrasian tradition. The General Theory was immediately seen to be a vitally important book. Keynes used the language of mathematics to articulate elements of the economy: the consumption function, the liquidity preference function, the aggregate supply function, and so forth. But the glue that welded these pieces into a macroeconomic system was Keynes s elegant, but not always transparent, prose. Keynes (1936, v) had addressed the General Theory to his fellow economists. And at a meeting of the Econometric Society in Oxford in 1937, his fellow economists gathered to try to work out the meaning of his masterwork. Roy Harrod, James Meade, and John Hicks translated the General Theory into mathematical systems. 2 Their accounts have largely been forgotten, except for that of Hicks ([1937] 1967). Cutting through the elegant prose and the many detours, Hicks s IS-LL model proposed to reduce the central theoretical message of Keynes s General Theory to a short set of simultaneous equations and a single graph. At the time, Hicks could not have fancied the success that his model was to encounter. In effect, it became the organizing theoretical apparatus of the emerging discipline of macroeconomics. Knowingly perpetrating a solecism, Keynes conjured up a straw man, the classics, on page 3 of the General Theory in order to have a worthy foe to vanquish over the remaining 409. Hicks s essay, Mr. Keynes and the Classics, begins by noting the smell of newly cut hay hanging about Keynes s classics. Nevertheless, Hicks tries to locate the essence of Keynes s approach in an understanding of just what Keynes claims distinguishes himself from the classics. Hicks presents a self-consciously stylized account of the General Theory in three equations. But it was the diagram, not the equations, that engendered the enduring fame of the essay. Figure 1 is Hicks s original diagram. On the vertical axis are interest rates, and on the horizontal axis, aggregate nominal income. The downward-sloping IS curve represents the locus of points for which investment (a function of interest rates) and savings (a function of income) are equal. The upward-sloping LL curve represents the locus of points for which the stock of money (presumed fixed) equals the amount demanded 2. David Champernowne was also present at the meeting. He had previously presented a mathematical and diagrammatic version of the General Theory (Champernowne 1936), as had W. Brian Reddaway (1936).

4 Michel De Vroey and Kevin D. Hoover Figure 1 The original IS-LM diagram (Hicks 1937, fig. 3; [1937] 1967, fig. 9) to satisfy liquidity preference. Hicks saw the essential difference between Keynes and the classics in Keynes s claim that liquidity preference offered a novel account of the determination of interest rates. As a result, Hicks paid special attention to the LL curve. According to him, Keynes s system became completely out of touch with the classical world whenever the LL curve exhibited a horizontal section and the intersection between IS and LL occurred on this section (Hicks [1937] 1967, 154). In such an occurrence, the economics of depression, monetary expansion was unable to increase employment. In contrast, fiscal policy would be effective. With not even an acknowledgment of Keynes s (1936, 207) avowed ignorance of real-world cases of absolute liquidity preference

Seven Decades of the IS-LM Model 5 (or, as it came to be known, the liquidity trap), Hicks argues that the flat LL curve is the characteristically Keynesian case. The essay by Mauro Boianovsky traces the history and analysis of the liquidity trap from Keynes and Hicks through Krugman s analysis of the Japanese economy in the 1990s. Hicks himself was sensitive to the limitations of his model and his diagram. He anticipated criticisms encapsulated in Joan Robinson s (1975) dismissive phrase bastard Keynesianism and in Alan Coddington s (1976, 1263) less pejorative, but accurate, hydraulic Keynesianism. How then did Hicks s little apparatus become canonical? This occurred in two stages. First, recasting Hicks s model (De Vroey 2000), Franco Modigliani (1944) sharpened the contrast between the classical and the Keynesian submodels. The former now referred to a case of flexible wages and market clearing, the latter to downward rigid wages and involuntary unemployment. Modigliani s contribution is analyzed in Goulven Rubin s essay. Rubin also claims that Don Patinkin s (1956) simplified general equilibrium constituted an alternative way of achieving the aim that Hicks and Modigliani had set for themselves. Second, every prophet needs an apostle. Keynes and Hicks found their apostle in Alvin Hansen. Hansen (1949, 1953) reinterpreted Keynes and rewrote elementary macroeconomics using Hicks s model. For reasons that remain somewhat obscure, Hansen relabeled the LL curve LM. It is a testimony to Hansen s importance in the story that the model has been referred to as IS-LM ever since. After World War II, the IS-LM model was developed in several directions. It became gradually enriched by the consideration of open economies and by attempts to give microfoundations to the consumption function, portfolio decisions, and the investment schedule. It served as the basis for econometric models. By degrees, standard textbooks starting with books aimed at graduate students and by the 1960s trickling down to elementary texts adopted the IS-LM model as their framework. As the model became more dominant theoretically, it lost its Keynesian character with respect to practical policy issues. That is, non- Keynesians could simply state that only its classical variant was valid, its Keynesian variant being flawed because of its rigid wages assumption. Thus, friends and foes of Keynes alike could use it to promote or confute Keynesian policy prescriptions. The essay of Warren Young and William Darity is concerned with such an embellishment of the standard IS-LM model. It recounts the

6 Michel De Vroey and Kevin D. Hoover story of how the model was broadened to consider the balance of payments and exchange rates key questions in international finance. The essay by Robert Dimand addresses James Tobin s efforts to introduce more complex, more realistic financial markets into the IS-LM framework. Throughout the high tide of the IS-LM model in the 1950s and 1960s, Milton Friedman and his fellow travelers (mostly associated in one way or another with the University of Chicago) advocated the superiority of the quantity theory of money over the Keynesian income-expenditure theory. Karl Brunner (1968) coined the term monetarism to describe the school of thought that included Friedman, Anna Schwartz, himself, and his frequent coauthor Allan Meltzer, as well as many of their students and colleagues. Drawing on very different paradigms, monetarists and Keynesians often seemed to talk at cross-purposes. When finally he was persuaded to try to articulate the framework of his monetary thinking, Friedman (1974), in an effort to bridge the gap between him and his Keynesian antagonists, turned to the IS-LM model. Friedman was not successful. In their essay, Michael Bordo and Anna Schwartz argue that, because of fundamental methodological differences between the monetarists and Keynesians, the IS-LM model was an inappropriate vehicle for successfully characterizing monetarism and that Friedman s attempt was doomed. They note that other monetarists, such as Brunner and Meltzer, who had argued that a much richer asset structure than was available in the IS-LM model was needed to capture monetarist views of the transmission mechanism for monetary policy, were not tempted to follow Friedman in trying to use the model as a neutral tool of communication with the Keynesians. Keynesians such as Tobin held similar views to Brunner and Meltzer about the need for rich asset structures (see Robert Dimand s essay), but nevertheless saw their position as elaborating rather than contradicting IS-LM (cf. Dornbusch 1976). Scott Sumner s essay argues that the IS-LM model offered an appropriate basis for monetary policy only in the gold standard era that was just ending at the time that Keynes wrote the General Theory. Sumner argues that, despite decades of intellectual dominance, the IS-LM model is necessarily an inadequate tool of analysis and communication for the quantity theorist. The success of the IS-LM model must also be explained by its happy adaptability to econometric modeling. Keynesian economics provided the intellectual foundation of a new theory of economic policy. Although

Seven Decades of the IS-LM Model 7 Keynes himself was deeply skeptical about the new econometrics of the 1930s expressed particularly in his 1939 review of Tinbergen s early modeling exercises macroeconometric modeling grew up in tandem with Keynesian macroeconomics. Published as The Keynesian Revolution (1947), Lawrence Klein s doctoral dissertation was an interpretation of the General Theory in which Klein paid attention to important modeling aspects of Keynesian economics, including microfoundations for, in particular, the consumption function, the money-demand function, and the investment function. Klein went on to become the doyen of macroeconometric modeling in the United States and the United Kingdom. Econometric models became ever more elaborate, but their essential structure was closely related to the conceptual form of the IS-LM model. Only one key feature of postwar macroeconometric models was not captured in the first generation of the textbook IS-LM model: inflation. The model was conceived in an era in which prices were not expected to trend up or down for long periods. Although the macroeconometric models added lagged variables to capture dynamics in a rough-and-ready way, the IS-LM model itself was essentially static. Soon after the publication of A. W. Phillips s (1958) paper on wage inflation and unemployment in the United Kingdom, the Phillips curve, now generally estimated for price inflation and unemployment, became the standard way of closing the macroeconometric model. The Phillips curve may have proved to be the undoing of standard Keynesian theory. The Phillips curve was criticized particularly by Friedman (1968) and Edmund Phelps (1967) for failing to integrate expectations and for ignoring the long-run neutrality of money. When macroeconometric models appeared to perform badly in the early 1970s, much of the blame attached to the Phillips curve. Robert Lucas (1972a, 1972b) initially turned his fire on his own antecedents, criticizing his old teacher, Milton Friedman, for modeling expectations in a manner that suggested that people made systematic, expensive, and easily correctable errors. Lucas and other new classicals such as Thomas Sargent and Robert Barro argued that expectations should be modeled according to the rational expectations hypothesis in a manner that did not build in systematic error. The early new classical models (e.g., Sargent and Wallace 1976) simply added rational expectations to the IS-LM framework. Lucas soon came to see that the failure to model expectations appropriately was part

8 Michel De Vroey and Kevin D. Hoover of a larger problem. In his important paper Econometric Policy Evaluation: A Critique (1976), he argued that the failure of the macroeconometric models in the early 1970s was attributable to a general failure to model the behavior of the individual, rational, optimizing agents that constitute the economy. In particular, Lucas criticized the practice of assuming that the parameters of aggregate econometric models would maintain stability in the face of changes in the conduct of economic policy. Lucas argued that the parameters themselves were functions of deeper parameters, governing the tastes and constraints of agents, and that these agents would adapt to new economic policies by adapting their behavior in a way that would shift the parameters of aggregate models. The Lucas critique was widely taken to demand a microeconomic basis for macroeconomics. It is, of course, a difficult problem to model the millions of individual agents in the economy. And, rapidly, the new classicals settled on the representative agent model (and some other highly stylized models) as the basis for macroeconomic theory. This is not the place to go into the successes and failures of this modeling strategy (but see Janssen 1993, Hartley 1997, and Hoover 2001). The important thing in this context is that the widespread acceptance by new classicals and new Keynesians alike of the ideal of microfoundations for macroeconomics was a body blow to the aggregative IS-LM model. By 1980, the IS-LM model no longer stood at the forefront of research in macroeconomic theory. Over the next two decades it gradually faded from more and more applied areas of macroeconomics. A graduate student in 2003, having studied no economics as an undergraduate, might obtain a PhD without any acquaintance much less mastery of the IS-LM model. Yet, somehow the model did not die. As Edward Nelson points out in his essay, the pedagogical simplicity of the IS-LM model made it an unparalleled tool of exposition not only to students but also to policymakers. In their pure form, modern dynamic optimization models are difficult to grasp. But with judicious arrangement, policy models used at central banks can be cast as optimizing IS models. Typically, the LM curve is exchanged for an interest-rate policy rule. Nelson argues that monetary aggregates may, nevertheless, serve as proxies for the wide range of asset prices (beyond the policy rate and a longer bond price often found in these models) affected by policy and affecting the economy. A dynamic optimizing IS model with an important role for monetary aggregate would appear to be another incarnation of Hicks s little apparatus.

Seven Decades of the IS-LM Model 9 In his keynote address, Lucas suggests another reason for the persistence of the IS-LM model its flexibility and adaptability. He argues that the microfoundational models that he, as the leader of the new classicals, has championed for a quarter century try to capture quite detailed optimization problems. But they are nevertheless more stylized than realistic. They work in environments that suit them. The postwar macroeconomic environment has, he believes, favored them. Central bankers and government policymakers in developed countries have more or less followed sensible policies and have successfully stabilized the economy. In these stable environments, microfoundational models are at home and work well. But in novel and highly disrupted environments for example, in the Great Depression or in the various crises of the developing countries they hardly work at all. In contrast, the IS-LM model, although it is unsatisfactory from a purely theoretical point of view, nonetheless provides a framework on which practical empirical analysis can be hung. Lucas still hopes that better models will one day supplant it completely. But that day is not yet at hand. And, so, the IS-LM model persists. David Colander closes the current volume with an examination of that persistence. No longer at the forefront of research, it remains unsurpassed as a tool of undergraduate pedagogy and communication about macroeconomic policy. A bibliometric study shows only a highly attenuated decline in references to the IS-LM model over the decades. But a greater proportion than ever are in historical or pedagogical contexts and fewer and fewer in pure theory. Textbooks still feature the IS-LM model, but where in Gardner Ackley s 1961 textbook the model itself was a focal point, in N. Gregory Mankiw s popular recent textbook (2003), it is mainly deployed as an instrument for the discussion of economic policy. References Ackley, Gardner. 1961. Macroeconomic Theory. New York: Macmillan. Brunner, Karl. 1968. The Role of Money and Monetary Policy. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review 50.7:8 24. Champernowne, David G. 1936. Unemployment, Basic and Monetary: The Classical Analysis and the Keynesian. Review of Economic Studies 3.3:201 16. Coddington, Alan. 1976. The Search for First Principles. Journal of Economic Literature 14.4:1258 73. De Vroey, Michel. 2000. IS-LM à la Hicks versus IS-LM à la Modigliani. HOPE 32.2:293 316.

10 Michel De Vroey and Kevin D. Hoover Dornbusch, Rudiger. 1976. Comments on Brunner and Meltzer. In Monetarism, edited by Jerome Stein. Amsterdam: North-Holland. Fitoussi, Jean-Paul, and Kumaraswamy Velupillai. 1993. Macroeconomic Perspectives. In Monetary Theory and Thought, edited by Haim Barkai, Stanley Fischer, and Nissan Liviatan. London: Macmillan. Friedman, Milton. [1949] 1953. The Marshallian Demand Curve. In Essays in Positive Economics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.. 1955. Leon Walras and His Economic System: A Review Article. American Economic Review 45.5:900 909.. 1968. The Role of Monetary Policy. American Economic Review 58.1:1 17.. 1974. A Theoretical Framework for Monetary Analysis. In Milton Friedman s Monetary Framework: A Debate with His Critics, edited by Robert J. Gordon. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Hansen, Alvin. 1949. Monetary Theory and Fiscal Policy. New York: McGraw-Hill.. 1953. A Guide to Keynes. New York: McGraw-Hill. Hartley, James E. 1997. The Representative Agent in Macroeconomics. London: Routledge. Hicks, John R. 1937. Mr. Keynes and the Classics. Econometrica 5.2:147 59.. [1937] 1967. Mr. Keynes and the Classics. In Critical Essays in Monetary Theory. Oxford: Clarendon. Hoover, Kevin D. 2001. The Methodology of Empirical Macroeconomics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Janssen, Maarten. 1993. Microfoundations: A Critical Inquiry. London: Routledge. Keynes, John Maynard. 1936. The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money. London: Macmillan.. 1939. Professor Tinbergen s Method. Economic Journal 49.195:558 68. Klein, Lawrence R. 1947. The Keynesian Revolution. New York: Macmillan. Lucas Jr., Robert E. 1972a. Econometric Testing of the Natural Rate Hypothesis. In The Econometrics of Price Determination, edited by Otto Eckstein. Washington, D.C.: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.. 1972b. Expectations and the Neutrality of Money. Journal of Economic Theory 4.2:103 24.. 1976. Econometric Policy Evaluation: A Critique. In The Phillips Curve and Labor Markets, edited by Karl Brunner and Allan H. Meltzer. Carnegie- Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, vol. 11 (spring). Amsterdam: North-Holland. Mankiw, N. Gregory. 2003. Macroeoconomics. 5th ed. New York: Worth Publishers. Marshall, Alfred. [1885] 1925. The Present Position of Economics. In Memorials of Alfred Marshall, edited by A. C. Pigou. London: Macmillan. Modigliani, Franco. 1944. Liquidity Preference and the Theory of Interest and Money. Econometrica 12.1:45 88. Patinkin, Don. 1956. Money, Interest, and Prices. New York: Harper and Row. Phelps, Edmund S. 1967. Phillips Curves, Expectations of Inflation, and Optimal Unemployment over Time. Economica, n.s., 34.3:254 81.

Seven Decades of the IS-LM Model 11 Phillips, A. W. 1958. The Relation between Unemployment and the Rate of Change of Money Wages in the United Kingdom, 1961 1957. Economica, n.s., 25.100:283 99. Reddaway, W. Brian. 1936. The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money by J. M. Keynes. Economic Record 12 (June): 28 36. Robinson, Joan. 1975. What Has Become of the Keynesian Revolution? In Essays on John Maynard Keynes, edited by Milo Keynes. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Sargent, Thomas J., and Neil Wallace. 1976. Rational Expectations and the Theory of Economic Policy. Journal of Monetary Economics 2.2:169 83. Theiss, Edward. 1935. Dynamics of Saving and Investment. Econometrica 3.2:213 24.