UC Riverside Cliodynamics

Similar documents
12. Which foreign religious tradition was absorbed into China during the classical period? A) Hinduism B) The Isis cult C) Buddhism D) Christianity

Social Studies 6 th Grade Timeline. Macon County

World History I (Master) Content Skills Learning Targets Assessment Resources & Technology CEQ: features of early. civilizations.

2008 World History I History and Social Science Standards of Learning STANDARD

Groveport Madison Local School District Seventh Grade Social Studies Content Standards Planning Sheets

AP World History Schedule

myworld History Early Ages Edition 2012

GRADE 7 SOCIAL STUDIES SOCIAL STUDIES APPLICATION. SOCIAL STUDIES STANDARDS for Grade 7

Grade Level: 9-12 Course#: 1548 Length: Full Year Credits: 2 Diploma: Core 40, Academic Honors, Technical Honors Prerequisite: None

World History and Civilizations

Construct maps that display the location of a variety of Earth's physical features (e.g., plateaus, rivers, deltas

SOCIAL STUDIES GRADE 7. I Can Checklist Office of Teaching and Learning Curriculum Division

Grades 6 8 World History Item Specifications

Correlations to the Texas Essential Knowledge and Skills (TEKS): Student Material

Honors World History

Base your answers to questions 1 and 2 on the art work below and on your knowledge of social studies.

Chapters 5 & 8 China

Test Blueprint. Course Name: World History Florida DOE Number: Grade Level: 9-12 Content Area: Social Studies. Moderate Complexity.

All societies, large and small, develop some form of government.

Classical Civilizations of the Mediterranean & Middle East. Persia, Greece & Rome

SOCIAL STUDIES 8 COURSE OUTLINE WORLD CIVILIZATIONS

Chapter 2: The Modern State Test Bank

B.A. IN HISTORY. B.A. in History 1. Topics in European History Electives from history courses 7-11

GRADE 9 WORLD HISTORY

Unit II: The Classical Period, 1000 B.C.E. 500 C.E., Uniting Large Regions & Chapter 2 Reading Guide Classical Civilization: CHINA

Directives Period Topics Topic breakdowns

History Major. The History Discipline. Why Study History at Montreat College? After Graduation. Requirements of a Major in History

Classical China. Qin and Han Dynasties

Themes of World History

Ladies and gentleman, coming to the ring tonight is something classic... (music plays)

China Builds A Bureaucracy*

1. Base your answer to question on the chart below and on your knowledge of social studies.

TASC Social Studies Blueprint Overview (DEF)

POL 343 Democratic Theory and Globalization February 11, "The history of democratic theory II" Introduction

Ordering Power: Contentious Politics and Authoritarian Leviathans in Southeast Asia

CURRICULUM CATALOG. World History from the Age of Enlightenment to the Present (450835)

New Paltz Central School District Social Studies Global History and Geography 9. Time Essential Questions Standards/Skills Assessments

Academic Vocabulary CONTENT BUILDER FOR THE PLC WORLD HISTORY

Global Regents Review Packet #1

WS/FCS Unit Planning Organizer Subject(s) Social Studies Conceptual Lenses Grade/Course 9 th Grade

Reading Essentials and Study Guide

China Builds A Bureaucracy

B. Directions: Use the words from the sentences to fill in the words in this puzzle. The letters in the box reading down name a part of nationalism.

WORLD HISTORY NAME: DATE: Period: Semester One Study Guide - McCleskey

LEARNING GOALS World History

Name: Global 10 Section. Global Regents Pack #10. Turning Points

History. History. 1 Major & 2 Minors School of Arts and Sciences Department of History/Geography/Politics

[ CATALOG] Bachelor of Arts Degree: Minors

History (

OnTRACK Lesson Checklist

1. What were the 7 major states fighting for dominance in China? 2. What advantages did the Qin state have?

The Enlightenment and the scientific revolution changed people s concepts of the universe and their place within it Enlightenment ideas affected

World History Unit 5/Part 1 Continued Suggested Dates TEKS. Vertical Alignment Expectations *TEKS one level below* *TEKS one level above* SS TEKS

ANCIENT CHINA: Chinese River Valley. Unit 11 2/8/16

APWH Notes. How is China Unique? Early Chinese History 9/11/2014. Chapter 2

4.) Define democracy A democracy is a system of government whose leaders have been elected by the people.

Early Japan and Feudalism

TABLE OF CONTENTS UNIT 1 LONG AGO

5/21/14. Chapter 2 Classical Civilization: China. Shang Dynasty ( BCE) First documented rule in China after Xia dynasty

GS-1: The student will demonstrate an understanding of the early civilizations of Africa, Asia, Oceania, and the Americas.

Year 1 Theme: Identity / Ancient Civilizations

YEARLY PLAN TEXTBOOK: World History, Patterns of Interaction. McDougal Littell. 2009

WORLD HISTORY Curriculum Map

Judeo-Christian and Greco-Roman Perspectives

Globalization and a new World Order: Consequences for Security. Professor Kjell A. Eliassen Centre for European and Asian Studies

Asia ARCTIC OCEAN. The Political Development of Imperial China CHINA. Teachers Curriculum Institute Fourth Proof TCI Arabian Sea.

2. Which of the following established a uniform code of law in ancient Mesopotamia? F Islamic law G Roman Justice H Justinian Code J Hammurabi s Code

CW Middle School World History

SOCIAL AND CULTURAL ANTHROPOLOGY

History/Social Science Standards (ISBE) Section Social Science A Common Core of Standards 1

World History I: Civics and Economics Essential Knowledge

Cultural Forum: Classical Societies and Western Dominance [10th grade]

X The Credential Sheet is attached to this alignment.

WORLD HISTORY FROM 1300: THE MAKING OF THE MODERN WORLD

Note on the historical background for European industrialization. Social organization. Trade in Feudal era. Social norms 9/20/2017

Ancient China. Hwang Ho River Valley. Hwang Ho River Valley 10/7/2016. Stuff about ancient China and stuff

SY 2017/ nd Final Term Revision. Student s Name: Grade: 10A. Subject: SOCIAL STUDIES. Teacher Signature

Essential Question: What were the important contributions of ancient Rome?

2. In what present day country AND river valley was Mesopotamia located? 4. What made Judaism a unique religion in the ancient world?

Final Review. Global Studies

C) an increase in population B) Code of Hammurabi B) codified the laws of their empire B) producing only enough crops to meet family

Classical Civilization: China

SENIOR 4: WESTERN CIVILIZATION HISTORICAL REVIEW OF ITS DEVELOPMENT (OPTIONAL)

Warm-up Questions. What was the official government policy under Wudi? Who was the peasant emperor of the Han Dynasty?

Geography and Early China

(3) parliamentary democracy (2) ethnic rivalries

Fields of Blood. Religion & the History of Violence. ACTS Winter St David s United Church Calgary

Social Studies World History Classical Civilizations and Empires 1000 B.C. to 1450 A.D.

Balance of Power. Balance of Power, theory and policy of international relations that asserts that the most effective

PETERS TOWNSHIP HIGH SCHOOL

UC Merced The Undergraduate Historical Journal at UC Merced

History (HIST) History (HIST) 1

(What would you buy if you won the lottery?) What will move Kings and Queens from Monarchy to Absolute Monarchy?

Sealy Independent School District

MIDLAND ISD ADVANCED PLACEMENT CURRICULUM STANDARDS WORLD HISTORY STUDIES

7.1.3.a.1: Identify that trade facilitates the exchange of culture and resources.

Tennessee Consortium For International Studies Syllabus Outline. World History 1120

Nationalism in International Context. 4. IR Theory I - Constructivism National Identity and Real State Interests 23 October 2012

Name: Date: Period: Chapter 27 Reading Guide. Russia and Japan: Industrialization Outside the West p

ECO/SNY 128 Spring Lecture 1 Modernity and Civilizations. M. Aykut Attar

Transcription:

UC Riverside Cliodynamics Title Middle Range Theory: A Review of The Origins of Political Order by Francis Fukuyama Permalink https://escholarship.org/uc/item/8hg1z8f9 Journal Cliodynamics, 2(2) ISSN 2373-7530 Author Manning, Joseph G Publication Date 2011-01-01 escholarship.org Powered by the California Digital Library University of California

Cliodynamics: the Journal of Theoretical and Mathematical History Middle Range Theory A Review of The Origins of Political Order: From Prehuman Times to the French Revolution by Francis Fukuyama (Straus & Giroux, 2011) Joseph G. Manning Yale University This book does not lack ambition. Fukuyama s aim is to achieve, in the tradition of 19 th century historical sociologists, a middle range theory of the historical development of political order. Like Goldilocks and the three bears, the book seeks a theory that is not too abstract, as Economists prefer, and not too particular, as Historians and Anthropologists are want to describe the world. The book is written as a kind of updated account of Samuel Huntington s Political Order in Changing Societies (1968). F. s book is motivated by his belief that still more work needs to be done to understand development and decay. Unlike Weber and most other theorists of modernization, however, F. stresses throughout the book that China was first to emerge as a modern state. But it was only Europe, where individualism, rule of law and government accountability came together in delicate balance, which was able to achieve a durable political equilibrium and economic growth. The book should be read against the contemporary backdrop of what F. sees as a democratic recession of the early 21 st century that has seen 20 percent of countries that democratized during Samuel Huntington's Third Wave (1970 2010) have reverted back to some form of authoritarian government. There have been many books Michael Mann (The Sources of Social Power, 2 volumes, 1986, 1993) and Ian Morris (Why the West Rules For Now, 2011), to name just two written to explain the exceptionalism of the political development of the West and how the future might play out based on these historical developments. The rise of China and the global financial crisis continues to fuel interest in macro historical explanations of political development and decay, and state formation in a broad, comparative historical framework. Not a new phenomenon, it is a tradition that goes back to scholars like Max Weber who wanted to explain German modernity. Corresponding author s e-mail: joseph.manning@yale.edu Citation: Manning, Joseph G. 2011. Middle Range Theory: A Review of The Origins of Political Order: From Prehuman Times to the French Revolution by Francis Fukuyama. Cliodynamics 2: 333 340.

The core of Fukuyama s treatment revolves around the Weberian frame of governance (patrimonial versus bureaucratic) and Samuel Huntington s critique of why states fail. Like Michael Mann s Sources of Social Power, F s analysis will be divided into two volumes. Volume 2, we are told, will explain the conditions of political development today (p. 18) and how they differ from those set out in the present volume. His main concern here is with the history of states, modernity, and political institutions (p. 450). For institution he follows Huntington s definition: stable, valued, recurring patterns of behavior. And for what a state is, he follows Weber s classic definition: an organization deploying a legitimate monopoly of violence over a defined territory. For modern state, again the definition comes from Weber: states subject to a rational division of labor, based on technical specialization and expertise, and impersonal both with regard to recruitment and their authority over citizens. The underlying thesis is that political institutions are very often too slow, too rigid to adjust to social change (driven by a variety of factors), which leads to social decline and decay. In order to explicate this thesis, F. organizes his material into Five Sections: I. Before the State, II. State Building, III. The Rule of Law, IV. Accountable Government and V. Toward a Theory of Political Development. F. s aim is in its essence to explain how states Get to Denmark, i.e. achieve a modern, liberal, democratic, growth-producing state. F. deploys three categories of institutions in his analysis: (1) the State, (2) The Rule of Law, and (3) Accountable Government. F. is concerned primarily with five main regions: China, Europe, India, Islamic states in the Middle East and the Ottoman Empire. He choses these case studies, I think, primarily because they are important both historically and in the modern world as well. Most of the leading social scientific works in English (F.'s bibliography is exclusively English language titles) on social science history of state formation appear in these pages. Such efforts have been attempted before. Barrington Moore's Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy (1966) and Reinhard Bendix Kings or People: Power And The Mandate To Rule (1980) are two examples, although neither appear in F. s bibliography. F. differs from earlier work in holding up England/Denmark as the ideal against which other states can be measured, and in his motivation to take account of the recent developments in democratization throughout the world since the 1970s and the decline of democracy in some parts of the world more recently. F. is interested, one senses here, not just in comparative historical analysis but in policy implications as well. The first four chapters of the book are devoted to setting up F. s project and with understanding early human nature, tribal societies, and the nature of kinship and how this undergirds politics. Humans are violent creatures, prone to war. Warfare is important as a driver in the scaling up process from band to tribe and eventually to states. Chapter 5 begins the story of state 334

formation. The various explanations for the rise of states are summarized, pristine states are distinguished from secondary or competitive state formations. Here again China is highlighted as a state that began extremely early, somewhat after Egypt and Mesopotamia (p. 92). Part II begins with Chapter 6 on Chinese tribalism. The first four chapters in the section are devoted to the rise of the Chinese state. The different social structures in F. s comparison set begin to emerge in detail. Patrimonial power and the importance of family in China that was supported by Confucianism was weakened by Legalism, which led to the emergence of the modern state in China and not elsewhere. Intensive warfare between the Eastern Zhou and early Han periods was the engine of what F. claims to be a singular event of state modernization in antiquity. The number of wars, their scale, and their intensity is indeed a remarkable feature of Chinese state formation and bureaucratization. From Chapter 9, we begin to understand what goes wrong in states. Following Huntington, F. argues that social change upsets the political equilibrium. The developing corporate interest of palace Eunuchs, environmental issues, revolts, and an enormous drop in population led to the reemergence of patrimonial structures and the consequent decline in central state power. India makes for a good comparison case for F. In strong contrast to China, the default position of the Indian subcontinent was small squabbling kingdoms and only occasional unity. There are many reasons for the contrast. For F. perhaps the most important is the comparative role of religion. China was a Caesaropapist state, one that subordinated the priestly class to the political regime, whereas in India, priests were a separate class (varna) and an independent power. It was from this source that Law sprang, not from the political but from religious power. The Mauryan kings in the 3 rd century BCE managed to unite most of the subcontinent but it quickly fell apart. States were weak in India and the concentration of power and the ability to mobilize an army was difficult. But F. s aim is not simply to analyze states but to come up with his middle range theory by the contrasts set up between India and China, for example. This is highlighted in his conclusion about the contrasts and similarities between Chinese and Indian history. A better form of freedom, F. argues, is created when a strong state is balanced by a strong society, something, as we will see as we read on, that is rare in world history. Chapters 13, 14, and 15 continue the study of state formation by examining Muslim states. In these chapters F. is concerned with the unusual solution of military slavery to solve the problem created by tribal organization. The Mamluk system was particularly effective and military slavery was the key not only to the political organization but also to the survival of Islam under pressure from Crusaders and the series of Mongol invasions. Even though the Mamluk regime in Egypt and Syria fell to the Ottomans in 1517, the Mamluk 335

system itself lasted in most parts of the Muslim world until the 19 th century. But the Ottoman system and the military slavery system itself declined under the pressure of a variety of factors including demographic and environmental change and growing pressures of fighting wars on two major fronts. The Ottoman empire, the most successful regime in the Muslim world, compares well to the Chinese in F. s analysis. Ultimately military slavery was a dead end. F. ends his second section in Chapter 16 by discussing how it was that Europe managed to exit the kinship structure. The difference between Europe and China, India or the Middle East lies in the early emergence of the individual in Europe created by the force of Christianity. F. follows Jack Goody s study The Development of the Family and Marriage in Europe (1983), in emphasizing the role of the Catholic Church in Europe. From an early point the Church, centralized and bureaucratic, emerged as a powerful force able to establish marriage and inheritance rules. Importantly, such rules, inter alia forbidding close kin marriage and divorce, severely affected kinship structures of tribal organization. Parts III and IV of the book build on what came before and shows the contrast between Europe and the rest based on two keys of political development: the rule of law and the idea of an accountable government. Europe was unique in state formation, F. argues, in that states ability to enforce laws played a stronger role in development than did military power. That, in turn, is premised on the existence of the rule of law that was contingent on the important role of the Catholic Church. The main contrast is once again China, where the emperor was the sole source of positive law and no rule of law existed. Part IV on accountable government is related to the preceding section. The establishment of the rule of law constrained rulers behavior. Importantly, the relative lateness of Europe s state building was a key factor in achieving the equilibrium between state strength and the strength of society. The core of Part IV is dedicated to four main stories of governance: Weak Absolutism (the Dutch and Spanish), Successful Absolutism (Russia), Failed Oligarchy (Hungary and Poland) and Accountable Government, the Getting to Denmark story (England and Denmark). The reason why F. spends so much time developing the various cases is that he, quite rightly, did not want to make it seem that getting to Denmark was inevitable, merely narrating a Whig historical account of English history as the teleological conclusion of European developments. History is at once more complex and more contingent than that simple linear story. F. concludes the volume at the end of the 18 th century with the American and French revolutions. By these events all three principles of the modern political order: a strong state, a state subordinated to the rule of law and a government accountable to all citizens had been established. The path to this modern order was indeed very difficult and it is not yet universal. Indeed in many parts of the world this modern political order does not yet exist. 336

The final part of the volume, Part V. Toward a Theory of Political Development attempts to put all of this historical study into his middle range theory explaining the processes of political development and decay. F. s study is an account of political development from prehumen times up to the eve of the French and American revolutions (p. 437). F. s theory treats the biological foundations of humans, their organization into kinship groups, their propensity for following rules, their propensity toward violence, and their desire for recognition, the latter being an important part of political struggle. F. s explains his General mechanism of political development by briefly reviewing the important role of institutions in political history (pp. 446 52). Here is where, we are told, political systems differ in development and decay from biological systems. Institutions can change quickly or be extraordinarily conservative. The treatment of states and institutions in the volume is superficial and disappointing. As I ve said, F. adopts Huntington s definition of institution and Weber s definition of the state (p. 450). The use of Weber is doubly bad. It conflates institution and organization, and it uses a definition of state that is highly problematic. F. s treatment surely would have benefitted from Sheilagh Ogilvie s recent discussion of institutions in Economic History Review (2007, 60:649 84). There is much fine analysis in F. s book and it is well worth reading. In the end, however, I found the book wanting in several areas. For one, it is too myopic in its approach to the history of states, missing both a large amount of history and some important work in the historical social sciences. Political institutions that sustain intensive economic growth are in the background of what F. is looking for, but growth is not well treated in the volume. He eschews discussing the ancient world entirely, even democratic Athens. Classical Republicanism (his preferred term) he tells us, did not scale well. That is quite true. Such states, moreover, were rather more limited in number than the more common authoritarian monarchies, which established more stable political equilibria over large territories. Nevertheless any treatment of the development of political order in a global context must, at a minimum, discuss Republican states. Unfortunately we must wait for the promised second volume to get F. s analysis of the relationships between classical republics and modern democracies (p. 20). The premodern Middle East, including Egypt is also entirely absent in the volume although for these states not even a cursory reason is proffered. At the risk of sounding particularist, to dismiss without comment a civilization like Egypt, whose language was written and spoken for two-thirds of recorded human history, and one that cast a large shadow over subsequent eastern 337

Mediterranean history is a serious intellectual flaw. F. is not the first to leave out the ancient Near East and Egypt in macro-historical studies of state development. Hegel s work (and Hegel is very much on F.'s mind here as in his previous book The End of History and the Last Man) on ancient art is one powerful reason. Standing proxy for Egyptian civilization and its political development at large, Egyptian art could be admired, but it still was merely Vorkunst, not fully free and not fully art for that matter. For that we have to wait for Greek art. Hegel was not alone is his preference for classical civilization, but there were more practical reasons why Egyptian and Ancient Near Eastern civilization (except for Biblical History) was treated so differently. Egyptian civilization itself was not directly accessible before Champollion s initial decipherment in 1822. Establishing fully understood texts took much of the remainder of the 19 th century. We really only have, then, a century of analytical scholarship on Egypt, and for some topics such as the economy, real work has just begun. Preferences for classical civilization and a lack of accessibility have played powerful roles in downplaying the contributions of the Near East in western civilization. In terms of state formation, F. offers another, unstated, reason, namely that the region was a dead end. Mesopotamia and Egypt were absorbed into the Islamic world, and thereafter followed a different historical trajectory. States such as the Egyptian New Kingdom or the Persian empire were seen as developmental dead ends, governing large and stable territory for long periods, but subject to cyclical expansion and contraction, and not leading directly into later political and economic developments, and certainly not into today. While these basic ideas have become commonplace, they are wrong, and they lead to bad scholarship. The absence of thousands of years of state history, as in F.'s book, impoverishes any account of political, legal and economic history. F. insists, for example, that China was the first to develop state institutions (p. 19), and the only great world civilization that did not have, by his definition, the rule of law. This, simply put, gets history wrong. Several states in Mesopotamia, and Egypt formed states earlier than China, not simply somewhat earlier, and that is an important fact in the history of states. F. specifically has in mind Han period China, although he mentions extensive written and archaeological records of early Chinese history with its uniform, multilevel administrative bureaucracy, something that never happened in Greece or Rome (pp. 92 93). Egypt certainly is another important historic case of early development of state institutions. F.'s treatment of the history of the rule of law also misses something by excluding the Egyptian case. The definition that F. gives on p. 246, the rule of law can be said to exist only where the preexisting body of law is sovereign over legislation is too simplistic. The key concept in Egyptian civilization, which was established at the dawn of the Egyptian state (c.3000 BCE), was Ma at, 338

moral rightness, cosmic order, correctness, balance, a concept that connected all of society from the gods to the king and to all people in Egypt. The law was embodied in the king, and the concept constrained what good kings could and could not do, just as it governed private behavior that led up to the last judgment of the dead. It did not always solve the bad emperor problem that F. discusses for China, but it is an important concept in the history of law and in political history that should have been addressed. Another example of why Egypt mattered historically comes in the one-sided analysis of the rise of Han China. The Early Han dynasty was established in 221 BCE. The focus on Chinese state formation should have been contrasted with similar and contemporary processes in the Mediterranean. The early Ptolemaic kings, as the early Han kings, went some way to professionalize the bureaucracy and to subordinate patrimonial social structure and religious power to state aims. In terms of state building the Ptolemies were, in my view, the most successful of the Hellenistic states. The same year as the founding of the Han dynasty was, as François Chamoux once put it, a turning point in Mediterranean history. Between 223 and 221 BCE new kings ascended the throne in all three of the major Hellenistic kingdoms (Philip V in Macedonia, Ptolemy IV in Ptolemaic Egypt and Antiochus III in the Seleukid kingdom). In some ways these kings mark the end of the height of Hellenistic state power and the rise of another to the west, Rome. If we are to follow Weber in what counts as modern, surely these Hellenistic states and the cities they built and supplied (Alexandria for one), and the armies they mobilized that emerged at the end of the fourth century in the eastern Mediterranean basin equally count as modern. In both Han China and the Hellenistic states (and we cannot exclude the rise of Rome in this Hellenistic context), intensive war fueled the bureaucratization process that disembedded, to varying degrees, ancient patrimonial patterns. We would have, then, at least two, not one, inflection point in world history beginning in the late fourth century BC the rise of the Chinese state culminating in the Han Dynasty, and the post-alexander eastern Mediterranean. They were not mutually isolated processes. The Ptolemaic state, for example, created by Ptolemy I beginning in the 320s BCE, compares very well to the Han state in terms of structure. Warfare in the Mediterranean was crucial to the bureaucratization process. Another difference may have been the much vaunted recruitment and examination system in China that did not seem to have emerged in Egypt. There are many things that we do not know precisely about how the Ptolemies recruited and trained officials or scribes who served in the bureaucracy. But there were methods of instilling loyalty in the bureaucracy and there are instruction texts that describe how good behavior in one office would lead to promotion higher up the bureaucratic chain. In both cases, neither China not Egypt completely 339

solved the problem of the historic weight of the patrimonial power of local families. An extended comparison of Hellenistic and early Chinese developments would be fascinating to see in the context of this book. One Hellenistic state is treated by F., the Mauryan state in India, as a precursor to later Indian developments. This state arose at the end of the fourth century BC, along with the Seleukids, the Ptolemies, and other states in the Mediterranean. The early Mauryan kings successfully united virtually the entire subcontinent. While the state is often treated in isolation, its rise, in my view, should be seen in the context of the wave of new state formation ( competitive state formation to use F.'s term) created by the Alexander's campaigns, the collapse of the Persian empire, and the intensive inter-state competition that resulted. Not to say that the Mauryan kingdom was a Hellenistic kingdom in the traditional sense of the term to be sure, Greeks were not ruling in India. But it is to say that states from Greece to central Asia were more connected than ever before. In this light, it is at least worth asking whether Han state formation was linked to these massive post hegemonic disruptions and new state formations in the Mediterranean world. The connections, after all, between the Mediterranean and East Asia after Alexander were real. The great Mauryan king Ashoka, in the middle of the third century BC, was aware of his contemporaries Ptolemy II, Antigonus Gonatas, and Magas. Trade along the silk road and the southern sea routes through India intensified in the wake of Alexander s campaigns in central Asia. Jack Goody s recent The Theft of History (2006) shows us some of what we lose by focusing on just a few states in isolation when attempting to explain European exceptionalism. Any successful middle range theory of political order should be more expansive than what F. provides. If history gives us lessons for political development, one of these is surely that there were multiple modernities before the American and French Revolutions, not merely one, the Han state in China, that ultimately failed. There is no simple road map to Denmark, and F. is right in suggesting how complex the political processes were in getting there. As Chapter 30 of the present volume intimates, F. s second volume will really be concerned about the modern world, about the fates of the West and of China. The development and economic growth of modern states certainly face different conditions that prevailed since the Industrial Revolution (p. 483). But the very complex history of premodern state formation still has much to teach us about the fate of human societies. 340