The Open Society Assesses Its Enemies: Shocks, Disasters and Terrorist Attacks*

Similar documents
Does government decentralization reduce domestic terror? An empirical test

Supplementary Material for Preventing Civil War: How the potential for international intervention can deter conflict onset.

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA?

IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE EASTERN DISTRICT OF PENNSYLVANIA

The Origin of Terror: Affluence, Political Freedom, and Ideology

THE CENTER FOR AGRICUTURAL ECONOMIC RESEARCH

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at

Economics and Terrorism: What We Know, What We Should Know and the Data We Need

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

Economics Honors Exam 2009 Solutions: Macroeconomics, Questions 6-7

Example 8.2 The Economics of Terrorism: Externalities and Strategic Interaction

The Macroeconomic Effects of Terrorism. Michael Siers. from as far back as 66 A.D. indicate terrorism by religious zealots in Palestine (Enders &

Differences Lead to Differences: Diversity and Income Inequality Across Countries

the notion that poverty causes terrorism. Certainly, economic theory suggests that it would be

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY. Executive Summary

Remittances and the Macroeconomic Impact of the Global Economic Crisis in the Kyrgyz Republic and Tajikistan

CDDRL WORKING PAPERS. Do Democratic Transitions Produce Bad Economic Outcomes? Dani Rodrik Romain Wacziarg

The Effects of Terrorism on Labor Market Case Study of Iraq

The Political Challenges of Economic Reforms in Latin America. Overview of the Political Status of Market-Oriented Reform

Workers Remittances. and International Risk-Sharing

The Impact of Foreign Workers on the Labour Market of Cyprus

Growth Consequences of Terrorism in Western Europe

Is Corruption Anti Labor?

The impact of political instability on economic growth (Case of Albania)

Rainfall, Economic Shocks and Civil Conflicts in the Agrarian Countries of the World

Violent Conflict and Inequality

Skill Classification Does Matter: Estimating the Relationship Between Trade Flows and Wage Inequality

UNRISD UNITED NATIONS RESEARCH INSTITUTE FOR SOCIAL DEVELOPMENT

East Asian Currency Union

A COMPARISON OF ARIZONA TO NATIONS OF COMPARABLE SIZE

REMITTANCES, POVERTY AND INEQUALITY

5.1 Assessing the Impact of Conflict on Fractionalization

Abdurohman Ali Hussien,,et.al.,Int. J. Eco. Res., 2012, v3i3, 44-51

Full file at

Economic Disparity. Mea, Moo, Teale

Pedro Telhado Pereira 1 Universidade Nova de Lisboa, CEPR and IZA. Lara Patrício Tavares 2 Universidade Nova de Lisboa

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts

Mexico: How to Tap Progress. Remarks by. Manuel Sánchez. Member of the Governing Board of the Bank of Mexico. at the. Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas

Does Inequality Increase Crime? The Effect of Income Inequality on Crime Rates in California Counties

The Effect of Foreign Direct Investment, Foreign Aid and International Remittance on Economic Growth in South Asian Countries

THE GLOBAL ECONOMIC CRISIS DEVELOPING ECONOMIES AND THE ROLE OF MULTILATERAL DEVELOPMENT BANKS

Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal

Executive summary. Strong records of economic growth in the Asia-Pacific region have benefited many workers.

VENEZUELA: Oil, Inflation and Prospects for Long-Term Growth

Quantitative Analysis of Migration and Development in South Asia

CHAPTER 2 LITERATURE REVIEWS

Test Bank for Economic Development. 12th Edition by Todaro and Smith

Democracy and government spending

CH 19. Name: Class: Date: Multiple Choice Identify the choice that best completes the statement or answers the question.

2009, Latin American Public Opinion Project, Insights Series Page 1 of 5

1975 TO A Thesis. submitted to the Faculty of the. Graduate School of Arts and Sciences. of Georgetown University

Presidents and The US Economy: An Econometric Exploration. Working Paper July 2014

GOVERNANCE RETURNS TO EDUCATION: DO EXPECTED YEARS OF SCHOOLING PREDICT QUALITY OF GOVERNANCE?

Working Paper Series Department of Economics Alfred Lerner College of Business & Economics University of Delaware

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach

Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions. Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University. August 2018

The Relationship between Real Wages and Output: Evidence from Pakistan

Evidence-Based Policy Planning for the Leon County Detention Center: Population Trends and Forecasts

ICES- El CENTEI El CENTEIIF EXCELLENCE

Ghana Lower-middle income Sub-Saharan Africa (developing only) Source: World Development Indicators (WDI) database.

AmericasBarometer Insights: 2009 (No.27)* Do you trust your Armed Forces? 1

Educated Preferences: Explaining Attitudes Toward Immigration In Europe. Jens Hainmueller and Michael J. Hiscox. Last revised: December 2005

5. Destination Consumption

STATISTICS BRIEF URBAN PUBLIC TRANSPORT IN THE 21 ST CENTURY

Does opportunism pay off?

Legislatures and Growth

Online Appendices for Moving to Opportunity

Economic Costs of Conflict

Handle with care: Is foreign aid less effective in fragile states?

The interaction between democracy and terrorism

Convergence Divergence Debate within India

Final Report. For the European Commission, Directorate General Justice, Freedom and Security

Figure 2: Proportion of countries with an active civil war or civil conflict,

Spatial Inequality in Cameroon during the Period

Latin American Immigration in the United States: Is There Wage Assimilation Across the Wage Distribution?

3 Wage adjustment and employment in Europe: some results from the Wage Dynamics Network Survey

Openness and Poverty Reduction in the Long and Short Run. Mark R. Rosenzweig. Harvard University. October 2003

Practice Questions for Exam #2

Non-Voted Ballots and Discrimination in Florida

Openness and Internal Conflict. Christopher S. P. Magee Department of Economics Bucknell University Lewisburg, PA

International Migration and Development: Proposed Work Program. Development Economics. World Bank

The interaction effect of economic freedom and democracy on corruption: A panel cross-country analysis

The business case for gender equality: Key findings from evidence for action paper

Charles I Plosser: A progress report on our monetary policy framework

Terrorism From Within: An Economic Model of Terrorism

Volume 36, Issue 1. Impact of remittances on poverty: an analysis of data from a set of developing countries

Global Employment Trends for Women

Natural-Resource Rents

Is Government Size Optimal in the Gulf Countries of the Middle East? An Answer

HOW ECONOMIES GROW AND DEVELOP Macroeconomics In Context (Goodwin, et al.)

Trends in inequality worldwide (Gini coefficients)

2. Money Metric Poverty & Expenditure Inequality

chapter 1 people and crisis

Immigrant Employment and Earnings Growth in Canada and the U.S.: Evidence from Longitudinal data

The 2017 TRACE Matrix Bribery Risk Matrix

The Changing Nonlinear Relationship between Income and Terrorism

Migration and Remittances 1

The single European Market, the European Monetary Union and United States and Japanese FDI flows to the EU

Perspective of the Labor Market for security guards in Israel in time of terror attacks

Living in the Shadows or Government Dependents: Immigrants and Welfare in the United States

Transcription:

The Open Society Assesses Its Enemies: Shocks, Disasters and Terrorist Attacks* José Tavares Faculdade de Economia Universidade Nova de Lisboa October, 31 st 2003 * Please do not quote without permission. Prepared for the Carnegie-Rochester Conference on Public Policy on The Macroeconomcs of Terrorism, November 21-22 2003. 1

Abstract: This paper conducts a first systematic investigation of the determinants and costs of terrorism attacks at the aggregate level. We use newly assembled datasets on terrorism attacks, natural disasters and bank and currency crises to answer three questions: what are the determinats of terrorism incidence, is there an output cost after a terrorist attack and do democracies suffer a larger or smaller cost? We find that rich countries are the most prone to suffer attacks while democracies are neither more nor less vulnerable than other countries. There is a cost to terrorism, which is quantitatively small and associated with the occurrence of an event rather than with the number of casualties. Finally, we find strong evidence that the output cost of attacks is smaller in democracies. José Tavares Faculdade de Economia Universidade Nova de Lisboa Campus de Campolide 1099 032 Lisbon Portugal Europe Tel: (351) 21 380 1669 Fax: (351) 21 388 6073 E-mail: jtavares@fe.unl.pt http://www.fe.unl.pt/~jtavares 2

1. Introduction The nature and scale of the terrorist attack of September 2001 in New York has raised important new issues for economic policy analysis. 1 The first is the relationship between uncertain catastrophic events, output and economic growth. The September attacks caused massive casualties and substantial physical damage, translating into a sharp negative shock to aggregate US output. In addition, and probably more important, the attack opened an era of greater economic uncertainty. Thus, a first issue is to estimate whether terrorist attacks affect the output of the economy and if so, by how much and for how long. There are two reasons to be skeptical towards existing studies: the diffuse nature of the terrorist threat and the associated difficulty of measurement, and the failure to consider different forms of terrorism and of other catastrophic events simultaneously. In fact, case-studies of individual countries find that the long-term cost of a terrorist threat ranges from 4 to 10 percent of Gross Domestic Product. 2 Thus, a first issue to be addressed is to estimate the cost in terms of output of terrorism attacks, and compare it to the cost of other catastrophic events. Some time after the September 2001 terrorist attacks in the United States, another issue progressively came to the fore. What is the connection between civic institutions and the exposure to terrorism? More specifically, are democratic countries an easier target for terrorist groups and, if so, do they respond in a different way to the attacks? The implications are wide-ranging. If democracies are more easily the victims of attack maybe they should adjust their political and legal institutions in response to the increased risk of terrorism. This sentiment has driven recent policy changes in the United States towards some restrictions of individual rights. The economics literature has established that political rights are not significantly associated with economic growth as in Barro (1994) and Tavares and Wacziarg (2001) but suggests that developed political and legal institutions may result in less aggregate risk to the economy. In other words, we will investigate whether the open society reacts better to external risks. Rodrik (1997, 1998) and, more recently, Acemoglu et al. (2002), put forward the possibility that weak institutions cause macroeconomic volatility through a variety of channels. Easterly (2001) found that well developed institutions avoid the negative economic impact of risk factors such as ethnic diversity. We conjecture that the economic cost of a terrorist attack is, all else equal, less severe in countries with better developed institutions. Democracy and the rule of law act as risk-reducers, if not as far as incidence, at least in terms of the cost to economic growth. Thus, open societies may have different exposure to terrorist attacks either because of increased likelihood of an attack the incidence issue as well as economic cost of the attack the cost issue. Our paper attempts to provide a first answer to the different questions above. First, we estimate the determinants of the incidence of terrorist attacks, particularly as they relate to the level of political rights of the victim country. Second, we estimate the impact of a terrorist attack on GDP growth by comparing, for the first time, the relative impacts of economic shocks, natural disasters and terrorist incidents. In 1 The attacks, according to Lenain et al. (2002) mark the largest insurance-event in history, by most estimates two to three times as large as the $21 billion associated with Hurricane Andrew (Florida, 1992). 2 The first figure is for the Israeli economy as World Bank (2002) and the second to the Basque Country, Spain as in Abadie and Gardeazabal (2001). See more below. 3

contrast with previous work that focuses on international terrorism, we will assess the impact of domestic as well as international terrorist incidents using a broader dataset, with respect to time and space dimensions. Easterly et al. (1993) have suggested that terms of trade shocks are an important determinant of economic growth, while Auffret (2003) uncovers a substantial effect of natural disasters on consumption. Thirdly, in response to the issues that have arisen following the September 2001 attacks on New York, we assess whether the nature of the political and legal institutions affects the output cost to the economy once a terrorist attack has occurred. To answer these three questions we rely on existing macroeconomic and institutional data for a wide panel of countries, adding newly compiled datasets on terrorist attacks and natural disasters, as described below. Our expectation is that terrorist attacks have a measurable effect on GDP growth, larger in the short than in the long-run. The comparison with other shocks will allow us to gauge the cost of terrorism relative to the cost of other sporadic but extremely negative events such as natural disasters. 2. Shocks, Disasters and Terrorist Attacks In this section we conduct a brief review of the literature on three background issues of interest to this paper: the causes, incidence and costs of terrorist attacks; the cost of shocks caused by natural disasters and the relationship between the institutional framework of a country and the effects of risk on the economy. 2.1. The Causes, Incidence and Costs of Terrorism It is important to start by defining terrorism. One possible such definition sees terrorism as the premeditated use, or threat of use, of extreme violence to obtain a political objective through intimidation or fear directed at a large audience. 3 The term international terrorism applies to terrorist acts involving citizens or the territory of more than one country, either as victims or perpetrators. The objectives of terrorists are very diverse but can be summarized as three main tactical goals: 4 1 - Publicity, the means to make a specific ultimate objective or cause known to the public. As terrorists seek media attention, cities may become especially vulnerable. 2 - Destabilize the polity. Terrorists act outside the constitutional political framework to erode its legitimacy as a way of furthering their chances of achieving their goals. 3 - Damage the economy. Terrorists seek to impose material cost on the population as a form of pressure on the society as a whole. This paper focuses on the last two goals of terrorism, especially as far as there is an interaction between them. 3 We have adopted the definition in Krueger and Maleckova (2002). Since 1983, the U.S. State Department has used, for analytical purposes, the following definition: Terrorism involves premeditated and politically motivated violence perpetrated against noncombatant targets by subnational groups or clandestine agents, usually intended to influence an audience. 4 From Schelling (1991), quoted in Frey and Luechinger (2002). 4

The theory developed in Becker (1968) proposes that individuals allocate their time between legal activities and criminal activities in a rational way, that is, a way that maximizes their utility. In this calculation, individuals account for the risk of being caught, the probability and size of the penalty, as well as the stigma or moral cost associated with criminal activities. The result is that those who receive a higher marginal benefit from criminal activities are more likely to be involved in those activities. In fact, evidence has shown that lower wage and less educated individuals are more likely to commit property crimes, in contrast with murders and other violent crimes, which are unrelated to personal economic opportunity. In their recent study, Krueger and Maleckova (2002) use micro-data to examine the root causes of terrorism. They analyze public opinion surveys in the West Bank and Gaza measuring support for terrorist attacks on Israeli targets. Surprisingly, the authors uncover that the support for violent attacks is not associated with a lower educational and economic status. Another dataset on the characteristics of the terrorist activists themselves on both sides of the conflict also shows that higher income and higher education does not lead to lower support for terrorism. 5 Most of the studies of the causes and incidence of terrorism have been conducted at the macro-level. An example is Blomberg et al. (2002), who develop a model connecting economic conditions to terrorism. Terrorist activity is seen as the expression of demands for change from groups that are dissatisfied with the political status and who have abandoned constitutional means. The model delivers multiple equilibria, with two possible outcomes: reduced economic activity and frequent terrorist activities or the opposite. 6 A shortcoming of this theory of the emergence of terrorism is its difficult applicability to international terrorism. What do we know about the incidence of terrorism? Sandler and Enders (2002) have documented several empirical facts. First, transnational terrorism tends to result in relatively few deaths, especially as compared with more frequent events such as accidents on roads and highways. The events of September 11 stand out as clear outliers in the history of terrorism, despite the fact that, as reported in Enders and Sandler (2002a), terrorist attacks have become more threatening and lethal in recent years. Second, there seems to be a cyclical pattern in the incidence of terrorism, with a large fraction of casualties associated with a small number of events. Finally, attacks aimed at the United States or U.S. interests constitute a substantial portion of total events. Blomberg et al. (2002) document a negative relationship between income per capita and the incidence of terrorist attacks, with Europe and North America the most vulnerable and Africa the least. The United States stands out as the country with the highest absolute number of attacks per year. Harrigan and Martin (2002) have studied the vulnerability of cities to terrorist attacks. They conclude that the same forces that 5 Taylor (1988) had also concluded in a survey of the literature that Neither social background, educational opportunity or attainment seem to be particularly associated with terrorism. 6 These authors show that in rich and democratic countries economic contractions are associated with increased probability of terrorist activities. These authors use a panel data-set of 127 countries from 1968 to 1991 to show that during bad economic times low growth of output and investment - economies with well-established institutions are more vulnerable to terrorism. In contrast, economies with weak institutions are more likely to fall into civil wars and coups. In a wider study of the relationship between economic cycles and conflict, Hess and Orphanides (2001) have shown that the probability of the U.S. entering an external conflict doubles when the economy is coming from an economic contraction and the president is running for reelection. 5

are thought to lead to the formation of cities namely, the gains derived from the proximity of firms to markets, suppliers, and a large labor pool will help to preserve cities in the face of an attack. In the case of continued threats the costs are certainly higher but, even in this case, the gains from producing and consuming in large agglomerations such as New York overwhelm the tax-like cost of higher vulnerability to terrorist attacks. As documented in Blomberg et al. (2002), the largest number of terrorist attacks are perpetrated by unidentified groups, highlighting the diffuse nature of terrorism. In addition, as reported in Sandler and Enders (2002), there has been a change in the characteristics of terrorist groups in the recent past, with a greater number being affiliated with religious rather than leftist organizations. Attacks by religiously motivated individuals tend to be less focused as to victims, implying further uncertainty. What then are the costs of terrorism and how have they been evaluated in the literature? So far, economic accounts suggest that, in spite of the sharp short-term impact of the attack, the permanent negative effect on production and productivity in the long run might be small. Lenain et al. (2002) identify three possible channels through which terrorism may influence macroeconomic activity: decreased insurance coverage as a result of the perception of increased risk, larger trade costs possibly leading to lower levels of international trade and larger security and defense spending. 7 Glaeser and Shapiro (2001), focusing on the impact of war and terrorism on cities, agree that the costs are limited. A different approach has been to undertake case-studies of economies that have been subject to terrorism for longer periods. Abadie and Gardeazabal (2001) evaluate the impact of terrorism on the Basque Country in Spain by using the region s characteristics to construct a synthetic region whose evolution in time acts as a counterfactual displaying the hypothetical economic behavior of the Basque country in the absence of terrorism. The comparison of the economic dynamics of this synthetic region with the actual region suggests that Basque GDP decreased by 10 percent as a result of terrorism and periods of more intense terrorist activity are associated with decreases in GDP. A study by the World Bank of the Palestinian- Israeli conflict also uncovers relatively large costs of conflict. World Bank (2002) estimates the cost for the Israeli economy at 4 percent of Gross Domestic Product while World Bank (2003) estimates that the Palestinian territories have suffered a 50 percent decline in income per capita between 1994 and 2002. Still, aggregate studies may miss some of the costs as specific sectors, such as tourist and trade activities, are especially hurt. 8 How can societies respond to terrorism so as to decrease their vulnerability or cost? Here the evidence has not brought good news. Terrorism differs from other 7 Hobijn (2002) evaluates the third channel by estimating the increase in the cost to the US government and to the private sector of extra security measures in response to the September 2001 attack. Their estimate is that these will be on the order of 0.66 percent of GDP in 2003 and will decrease productivity levels in the private sector by only 1.12 percent. However, as the authors acknowledge, this is only a cost-side study concentrating on the economic effects of the increased expenditure, not a comprehensive evaluation of the economic cost of the terrorist threat. 8 Enders, Sandler and Parise (1992) use an ARIMA model to find that there are large and substantial losses to the tourism industry caused by terrorist incidents. 6

major shocks to societies and the economy in that it is the result of the action of rational actors. 9 Accordingly, when governments raise the costs and make it more difficult to pursue one method of terror, terrorists will quickly switch to other, less costly forms of terror. Enders and Sandler (2002b) report that the installation of metal detectors in airports from 1973 has indeed decreased skyjackings and associated threats, but at the cost of increasing other kinds of hostage incidents. The measured trade-off between skyjacking and other logistically complex events was nearly one for one. These authors also find strong evidence in favor of intertemporal substitution in terror incidents. Enders, Sandler and Cauley (1990) attempt to assess the effectiveness of policies aimed at thwarting terrorist activities but find little evidence for an effect of specific legislative activity in preventing terrorism. 2.2. Other Shocks and Disasters According to Centre for Research on the Epidemiology of Disasters (2003) the number of natural disasters has increased in the past century, their cost increasing dramatically in the last few decades. This in spite of the decreasing number of victims associated with disasters. Benson (2003) reports figures from the United Nations estimating the total cost of disasters during the 1980s at $120 billion in constant 1990 US dollars, total costs having risen from $70 and $40 billion in the 1970s and 1960s, respectively. 10 Furthermore, the comparison between developed and developing economies shows that the absolute cost increases with income but the relative cost (as a proportion of national or local wealth) decreases, in tandem with the number of lives lost. 11 Auffret (2003) shows that natural disasters are an important determinant of macroeconomic volatility in the Caribbean region. Despite high consumption growth, this region suffers from a geographically determined vulnerability to disasters, which causes high consumption volatility and decreases household welfare. 12 The author presents empirical evidence that consumption volatility is higher in the Caribbean than in the rest of the world. 13 In this region production shocks tend to translate almost automatically into consumption shocks due to the underdeveloped or ineffective riskmanagement mechanisms. 14 2.3. The Open Society The empirical literature on economic growth has shown that political rights and economic growth are not significantly associated. Barro (1994) and Tavares and Wacziarg (2001) both find a negative but insignificant correlation between democracy 9 This is a possible conclusion from a study by Atkinson, Sandler and Tschirhart (1987). These authors examine the impact of changes in bargaining costs, bluffing and other features of the negotiating environment on the length and severity of the attacks and find that increases in bargaining costs lengthen the duration of a terrorist incident. 10 As an example, Benson (2003) reports that before 1987 there was one case of insured losses from a natural disaster that exceeded $1 billion, while by 1995 there were 14 instances. 11 See Benson (2003). 12 Larger economies (higher absolute population) and richer countries (higher per capita GDP) seem to display lower consumption volatility, which is shown to be positively associated with income volatility. 13 The figures for Sub-saharan Africa are similar to those for the Caribbean region, while those for the OECD are the lowest. 14 This study examines 6 countries in the Caribbean and 10 from Latin America in the period 1970 to 1999 and reports that catastrophic events led to: decline in the growth of output and investment, lower but important declines in consumption growth (with most of the decline in private consumption, corresponding to half of the decline in investment and income), as well as a worsening of the current account balance. 7

and growth. However, several authors have suggested that developed political and legal institutions may result in lower aggregate risk in the economy or in lower vulnerability of the economy to external shocks. Rodrik (1997) has given three possible reasons for democracies to produce less randomness and to manage shocks better: the range of feasible policies is more restricted than in autocracies, which are more likely to produce extreme results; political participation allows for voice with no need for violent conflict; in democracies groups have fewer incentives to indulge in non-cooperative and disruptive behavior, as no specific group can be excluded from political competition. Rodrik (1998) presents evidence in favor of the hypothesis that countries with poorer institutions tended to suffer the sharpest falls in growth rates after 1975. Recently, Acemoglu et al. (2002) suggested the possibility that weak institutions cause macroeconomic volatility through a variety of channels, while Easterly (2001) found that well developed institutions avoid the negative economic impact of risk factors such as ethnic diversity. Democracy and the rule of law act like risk-reducers, if not insofar as incidence, at least in terms of the cost to economic growth. In a related argument, specifically connected with the issue of terrorism, Frey and Luechinger (2002) show skepticism towards the benefits of deterrence in the fight against terrorism, arguing instead for increasing the opportunity cost of terrorism. Their anti-terrorism strategy involves an argument for political and economic decentralization. As political power is more thinly distributed across political actors where the classical division of power is attained through democracy and the rule of law - and across levels of government through federalism societies become less vulnerable to terrorism. In addition, the decentralization of decision-making involved in a developed market economy also decreases their vulnerability, in contrast to a regulated and monopolized economy. 15 3. Empirics In this section we answer the three central questions of the paper. First, what is the incidence of terrorism, namely, what are the aggregate indicators at country level that are correlated with a higher frequency of suffering terrorist attacks? Second, does the incidence of terrorism lead to a decrease in the rate of GDP growth, and how important is that cost, quantitatively? Finally, do countries with higher levels of political rights incur a higher or lower cost from terrorist attacks? We use available datasets on macroeconomic and institutional indicators for a broad cross-section, in addition to new datasets on the incidence of terrorism and of natural disasters. Macroeconomic data come from the World Development Indicators dataset available as World Bank (2003), which covers all countries and territories. The macroeconomic variables of interest are mainly related to output per capita of GDP and its growth rate - trade trade intensity and share of primary goods exports - government expenditure total spending and spending on education and population total population and population structure. The institutional data, namely information on political rights, were compiled from Freedom House (2003) and cover most countries in the world from 1972 to 2001. 15 This view is consistent with the results in Krueger and Maleckova (2002), as detailed above. 8

As far as terrorist attacks are concerned, we have assembled a new dataset based on data provided by International Policy Institute for Counter-Terrorism (2003). This institution offers data on the type and number of attacks per country and year, number of casualties and type of organization undertaking the attack. This dataset comprises 1427 registered terrorist incidents, varying widely in type and consequences. We have coded the variables on an annual basis for each country to include the number of terrorist events and their breakdown according to the target civilian, military or political, type of perpetrator known or unknown terrorist organization - and number of casualties total affected, killed and injured. 16 The dataset on the incidence of natural disasters earthquakes, floods, hurricanes - as well as other events is provided by CRED (2003) and documents about 6000 occurrences of natural disasters in the world between 1970 and 2002. We have compiled information on the date and country of occurrence, the number of casualties, including the number killed and injured. 3.1 The Incidence of Terrorism In this section we estimate the main determinants of the incidence of terrorism using a cross-country dataset for the 1987-2001 period. 17 Unlike most previous literature, we will use the number of terrorist attacks (and their subdivisions into type of attack, organization and casualties) divided by absolute population as a measure of incidence. Table 1 presents summary statistics for each measure of terrorism incidence. We have a sample of 2725 observations and 1428 attacks in the sample. As can be verified, the majority are directed at civilian targets. Attacks on military and political targets together account for fewer than half of the attacks on civilian targets. More attacks are undertaken by known organizations than by unknown ones and of the total affected, the number killed is about 4 times lower than the number injured. All terrorist indicators display an extremely high standard deviation, suggesting that a great number of country/year observations have more than one attack to take into account. Comparing the incidence of terrorism with other shocks, there is some indication that natural disasters are more frequent, while bank and currency crises are less so. Table 2 turns to the determinants of terrorist attacks in our sample. The main determinants considered are the country s initial level of income, the growth rate of per capita GDP, the indicator of political rights, the share of primary goods exports in GDP, indicators of ethnic, language and religious diversity, the share of urban population, the share of population younger than 14 and the occurrence of illiteracy in adult males. 18 All indicators concern the victim country. 19 With the complete set of control variables, we end up with a sample of 964 observations. The specification is thus 16 We have decided to use only the terrorism indicators covering the years 1987 to 2001 as the data prior to that date have been compiled in only a sparse way. 17 The dataset on terrorism attacks is the limiting factor in defining the sample, as we have found no systematic compilation of terrorist attacks before 1988. 18 We have considered alternative sets of control variables but decided on the current one on the basis of one criterion, the plausibility of the aggregate indictor being associated with terrorism incidence. 19 A possible complement to this approach would be to include information on neighboring countries as a determinant of incidence. 9

Terrorism Incidence i,t= º0 + º1. pcgdp i,t + º2. GrowthGDP i,t + + º3. Political Rights i,t + Additional Controls + ε i,t One must first note the low R square associated with the specification. In other words, all these aggregate indicators explain a small fraction of the variation in terrorism victimization at country level, varying between 2 and 10 percent of the total variation. As we examine the significance of the coefficients on the right-hand side variable, some patterns begin to emerge. First, as documented above and confirming previous results by other authors, we investigate the relationship between the level of per capita income and its growth rate on the incidence of terrorism. Higher levels of income per capita are associated with higher incidence in all cases except military and political targets and attacks by unknown organizations. In the case of Total Attacks, as an example, the coefficient suggests that an increase of one thousand constant US Dollars is associated with an increase of 0.09 in attacks and 1.62 in casualties per 10 million inhabitants. The results on growth are less clear but it seems that periods of higher growth are associated with higher vulnerability to attacks, especially against civilian targets. Countries with a higher degree of political development, as mimicked by a higher indicator of political rights, do not suffer from increased incidence. If anything, they are less likely to suffer attacks on military targets and attacks by known organizations. 20 Our data do not support the existing prior that more democratic regimes are more vulnerable to attack: in fact, controlling for the level of income per capita, democracies suffer fewer attacks and fewer casualties. The use of an indicator of the strength of the rule of law yields very similar results, most notably the irrelevance of the institutional indicator for incidence and the importance of per capita GDP and growth rates. Results on the role of urban and younger population as well as on the different diversity indicators, as discussed below, are remarkably similar. 21 Countries that are primary goods exporters also do not seem to increase their vulnerability to attack, as attested by the negative sign of the only two coefficients that are statistically significant. The ethnic, linguistic and religious diversity of the population are, by contrast, more closely associated with terrorism incidence. Linguistic diversity is positively related to incidence and only in the case of attacks on political targets is the coefficient not significant. The diversity variables measure the probability that two individuals randomly drawn from the population will use different languages as their primary language, ranging from 0 to 100 percent. An increase of 10 percent in diversity leads to an increase in total attacks of 0.17 and in casualties of 3.8 per 10 million inhabitants. Interestingly, after controlling for Linguistic Diversity, Ethnic and Religious Diversity seem to have a negative effect on incidence, especially as it relates to attacks on civilian and military targets and casualties of any type. This is also counterintuitive, as one would tend to associate 20 It is also true that in spite of not being significant, the coefficient on political rights is positive for attacks by unknown organizations and of approximately the same size, suggesting some substitution towards anonymous attacks. This may be related to the fact that political regimes with increased legitimacy are less prone to be openly attacked by terrorist groups. 21 Available from the author upon request. 10

more diverse populations with increased risk of internal grievances by Ethnic and Religious groups. Finally, we look at the demographic structure and spatial distribution of the population. As might be expected, a larger share of urban population is positively and significantly associated with higher incidence, with the exception of the number of injuries. This is the prior that one would hold from casual observation, as well as from reading the recent literature on terrorism in cities. Attacks in urban areas may increase the benefit of the attack to the terrorist group potential damage and visibility as well as decrease the cost of conducting the action easier to pass unnoticed before and after the attack. The share of population under 14 years of age, an indicator of an exploding demographic pyramid, with all that it entails in terms of social instability, is also positively and significantly associated with incidence. Table 1 Terrorist Attacks and Other Shocks Summary Statistics Mean Standard Deviation Total Attacks 0.57 5.99 On Civilian Targets 0.40 4.75 On Military Targets 0.11 1.56 On Political Targets 0.07 0.56 By Known Organizations 0.31 4.62 By Unknown Organizations 0.26 2.29 Total Affected 7.17 96.90 Killed 1.48 15.00 Injured 5.68 88.20 Natural Disasters 42.40 206.00 Bank or Currency Crises 0.03 0.16 Note: The number of observations is 2725 and the number of attacks 1428. All statistics are yearly averages of occurrences per 10 million inhabitants after the year 1987. 11

Table 2 - The Incidence of Terrorism - Ordinary Least Squares Dependent Variable: Terrorist Attacks, by Type of Target, Terrorist Organization, and Number of Victims Total T i t Dependent Variable By Type of Target By Terrorist Organization By Number of Victims Civilian Military Political Known Unknown Total Affected Killed Injured GDP per capita 0.09 ** 0.08 ** 0.01 0.00 0.07 ** 0.02 1.620 ** 0.21 ** 1.410 ** (2.67) (2.91) (1.47) (-0.08) (3.17) (1.46) (2.32) (2.01) (2.28) GDP growth 0.022 ** 0.019 * 0.001 0.002 0.004 0.018 * -0.050 0.039-0.089 (2.03) (1.89) (0.45) (1.02) (0.75) (1.89) (-0.19) (1.39) (-0.35) Political Rights -0.016-0.029-0.012 * 0.025-0.068 ** 0.052-1.130-0.148-0.979 (-0.18) (-0.40) (-1.94) (1.40) (-2.38) (0.74) (-1.22) (-0.85) (-1.21) Primary Goods Exporter -0.400-0.200-0.100 * -0.100-0.400 * 0.010-11.000-0.600-10.400 * (-0.67) (-0.35) (-1.99) (-1.11) (-1.87) (-0.08) (-1.59) (-0.43) (-1.70) Ethnic Diversity -0.570-0.537-0.189 ** 0.125-0.467 * -0.133-15.500 * -2.330 * -13.100 (-1.33) (-1.59) (-2.68) (0.92) (-1.86) (-0.54) (-1.70) (-1.69) (-1.61) Linguistic Diversity 1.750 ** 1.530 ** 0.190 ** 0.048 1.040 ** 0.728 ** 38.000 ** 5.690 ** 32.300 *** (2.85) (2.94) (2.13) (0.51) (2.95) (2.14) (2.99) (3.12) (2.84) Religious Diversity -0.681-0.576 * -0.046-0.046-0.581 *** -0.087-4.630-1.960 * -2.670 (-1.60) (-1.72) (-1.09) (-0.32) (-4.13) (-0.25) (-0.65) (-2.09) (-0.40) Illiteracy Adult Males -1.20 * -0.900 * -0.100 ** -0.100-0.800 ** -0.400-48.900-5.00 ** -43.900 (-1.80) (-1.67) (-2.15) (-0.86) (-2.93) (-0.78) (-1.61) (-2.29) (-1.53) Urban Population 2.80 ** 2.00 ** 0.300 ** 0.500 * 1.00 ** 1.700 ** 21.500 * 4.900 ** 16.500 (2.60) (2.33) (2.78) (1.79) (2.82) (2.12) (1.67) (2.25) (1.44) Population Younger than 14 3.80 3.40 * 0.700 ** -0.300 3.00 ** 0.800 120.000 ** 12.100 * 107.000 ** (1.55) (1.64) (2.55) (-0.59) (2.62) (0.48) (2.29) (1.86) (2.24) Number of Obs. 964 964 964 964 964 964 964 964 964 R Square 0.04 0.04 0.05 0.02 0.10 0.02 0.03 0.04 0.03 12

3. 2 The Cost of Terrorism This section estimates the impact of terrorist attacks and related casualties on economic performance as measured by growth in real GDP per capita. The estimation uses ordinary least squares and instrumental variables estimation with per capita GDP growth as the variable to be explained. On the right-hand side we use lagged GDP per capita growth and the initial level of income as controls in all specifications, as well as indicators of three types of aggregate shocks, terrorist attacks, natural disasters and bank or currency crises. Later we will add additional control variables. The specification is thus: GrowthGDPpc i,t= º0 + º1. Growth GDPpc i,t-1 + º2. GDPpc i,t + + º3. Terrorism Incidence i,t + º4. Natural Disaster Incidence i,t + + + º5. Bank or Currency Crisis i,t + Additional Controls + ε i,t where the specification in Tables 3 and 4 ignores the additional controls and the specification in Table 5 adds them. Table 3 uses the simplest specification, with the output-related control variables and the indicators of aggregate shocks. We find that lagged growth in per capita GDP is positively and very significantly related to GDP growth. In contrast, the level of per capita GDP does not seem to affect GDP growth at this high frequency. As to the indicators of aggregate shocks, the incidence of terrorism comes out as having a negative and significant effect from all specifications except when political attacks and the number killed are used. It seems that attacks on civilians and the military are the most detrimental to growth, especially when undertaken by known organizations. As to other shocks, the occurrence of natural disasters never comes out as significant in any specification, while a bank or currency crisis has a negative and very significant impact on instantaneous growth. The level of the R Square suggests that the specification explains a large part of the variation in growth fluctuations in the sample. Table 4 conducts the same empirical exercise but uses instrumental variables to correct for the possible endogeneity of terrorism attacks. As Table 2 indicates, growth is not a major determinant of the occurrence of terror attacks, so that we would not expect endogeneity to be a major problem. We instrument for terrorist attacks with its lagged value. 22 The results are largely confirmed. With the exception of the coefficient on the different casualty variables, which become insignificant, we confirm that terrorism has an immediate negative impact on growth and that this impact is strongest for attacks on civilian and military targets conducted by known organizations. The number of casualties either the total, people killed or injured - seems less important than the occurrence of attacks in themselves. Figure 1 graphically illustrates the impact on economic growth of each terrorism indicator as well as the other shock indicators. The size of each bar indicates the impact on the growth of real per capita GDP of a one-standard deviation change in 22 So that, for instance, the number of terrorist attacks on civilian targets is instrumented for with the exact same variable lagged one period. 13

each measure of aggregate shocks, obtained as the product of the coefficient in Table 3 by the standard deviation of the variable in the sample. We confirm our previous suggestion that the attacks on civilian and military targets impose the greatest potential damage, a decrease of 0.2 percent in GDP growth. Attacks by known organizations decrease growth by slightly more than 0.25 percent. These estimates, though arguably small, are of the same order of magnitude as a bank or currency crisis and much larger than the impact of a natural disaster. Table 5 now estimates the impact of terrorism after additional determinants of growth are taken into account. The additional controls are the country s population - to control for scale effects, the degree of trade openness, the rate of inflation, the share of primary goods exports in merchandise exports, the size of government measured as the share of government spending in GDP and the share of government spending in education. These variables account for most of the aggregate economic indicators shown to be significantly associated with economic growth in cross country growth empirics. We find that after controlling for the extra growth determinants, the incidence of terrorism becomes insignificant. This is in contrast with the estimate of the impact of natural disasters on growth, which is now significant at the 10 percent level. The occurrence of a banking or currency crisis is still positively and robustly associated with a decrease in income growth and its quantitative effect is the same as in Tables 3 and 4. As to the other variables, scale and openness are positively and significantly related to income growth, while inflation affects growth significantly but negatively. However, scale and inflation have a quantitatively small impact, with an increase of 10 million people and of 100 inflation points leading, respectively to 0.03 and 0.1 changes in growth rates. The coefficient of the openness indicator, on the other hand, suggests that a 10 percent increase in the share of exports in GDP leads to a 0.3 increase in growth rates. The share of primary goods exports, the size of government and the share of spending on public education are associated with negative coefficients, but these are insignificant throughout. In sum, after we take into account additional determinants of growth, it seems that natural disasters and bank or currency crises impact growth, but not terrorism. 14

Total T i Lagged pcgdp growth 0.430** (9.34) pcgdp 0.007 (0.79) Table 3 - The Cost of Terrorism - Ordinary Least Squares Dependent Variable: Growth in Real GDP per capita Right-Hand Side Terrorism Indicator By Type of Target By Terrorist Organization By Number of Victims Civilian Military Political Known Unknown Total Affected Killed Injured 0.430** 0.431** 0.431** 0.430** 0.431** 0.431** 0.431** 0.431** (9.34) (9.34) (9.35) (9.34) (9.36) (9.35) (9.35) (9.35) 0.007 0.006 0.006 0.007 0.006 0.007 0.006 0.007 (0.80) (0.71) (0.74) (0.79) (0.76) (0.79) (0.76) (0.79) Terrorism Indicator -0.042** (-3.04) Natural Disasters -0.004 (-1.31) Bank or Currency Crisis -0.939** (-4.71) Number of Observations 2418 R Square 0.21-0.052** -0.167** 0.113-0.069** 0.005-0.001** -0.010-0.001* (-3.83) (-2.11) (1.05) (-6.56) (0.11) (-1.98) (-1.26) (-1.78) -0.004-0.004-0.004-0.004-0.004-0.004-0.004-0.004 (-1.30) (-1.29) (-1.24) (-1.30) (-1.26) (-1.27) (-1.28) (-1.27) -0.939** -0.937** -0.936** -0.943** -0.936** -0.940** -0.942** -0.939** (-4.71) (-4.70) (-4.69) (-4.73) (-4.70) (-4.72) (-4.73) (-4.71) 2418 2418 2418 2418 2418 2418 2418 2418 0.21 0.21 0.21 0.21 0.21 0.21 0.21 0.21 15

Total T i Lagged pcgdp growth 0.430** (9.35) Table 4 The Cost of Terrorism Instrumental Variables Estimates Dependent Variable: Growth in Real GDP per capita Right-Hand Side Terrorism Indicator By Type of Target By Terrorist Organization By Number of Victims Civilian Military Political Known Unknown Total Affected Killed Injured 0.430** 0.431** 0.427** 0.430** 0.431** 0.431** 0.431** 0.430** (9.35) (9.33) (8.92) (9.35) (9.34) (9.34) (9.35) (9.33) pcgdp 0.006 (0.78) 0.007 0.006 0.002 0.006 0.006 0.006 0.006 0.006 (0.79) (0.67) (0.24) (0.78) (0.76) (0.73) (0.76) (0.69) Terrorism Indicator -0.032* (-1.69) -0.038** -0.325** 2.250-0.048** -0.013 0.842-0.017 0.002 (-2.08) (-4.15) (0.68) (-2.77) (-0.24) (0.23) (-1.09) (0.46) Natural Disasters -0.004 (-1.29) -0.004-0.004-0.003-0.004-0.004-0.004-0.004-0.004 (-1.29) (-1.32) (-0.84) (-1.29) (-1.26) (-1.24) (-1.30) (-1.23) Bank or Currency Crisis -0.938** (-4.71) -0.938** -0.937** -0.942** -0.941** -0.935** -0.932** -0.946** -0.928** (-4.71) (-4.70) (-4.50) (-4.72) (-4.68) (-4.66) (-4.75) (-4.61) Number of Observations 2418 2418 2418 2418 2418 2418 2418 2418 2418 16

Figure 1 Terrorism, Shocks, Natural Disasters and Economic Growth 0.1000 0.0500 Percent Growth in Real GDPpc 0.0000-0.0500-0.1000-0.1500-0.2000-0.2500 Attacks Civilian Military Political Known Unknown Total Affected Killed Injured Natural Disasters Bank or Currency -0.3000 17

Total T i Table 5 The Cost of Terrorism - Ordinary Least Squares Dependent Variable: Growth in Real GDP per capita Right-Hand Side Terrorism Indicator By Type of Target By Terrorist Organization By Number of Victims Civilian Military Political Known Unknown Total Affected Killed Injured Lagged pcgdp growth 0.248** 0.248** 0.248** 0.248** 0.248** 0.248** 0.248** 0.248** 0.248** (4.88) (4.88) (4.88) (4.88) (4.88) (4.88) (4.88) (4.88) (4.88) PcGDP -0.009 (-0.68) Terrorism Indicator 0.007 (0.32) Natural Disasters -0.045* (-1.88) Bank or Currency Crisis -0.976** (-3.56) -0.009-0.009-0.009-0.009-0.009-0.009-0.009-0.009 (-0.69) (-0.64) (-0.68) (-0.63) (-0.69) (-0.67) (-0.67) (-0.68) 0.007 0.155 0.027 0.065-0.003 0.389 0.007 0.334 (0.27) (0.95) (0.24) (1.30) (-0.12) (0.33) (0.62) (0.28) -0.045* -0.046* -0.045* -0.045* -0.045* -0.045* -0.045* -0.045* (-1.88) (-1.90) (-1.88) (-1.88) (-1.88) (-1.88) (-1.87) (-1.88) -0.977** -0.962** -0.978** -0.954** -0.978** -0.979** -0.977** -0.979** (-3.57) (-3.50) (-3.57) (-3.47) (-3.57) (-3.57) (-3.57) (-3.57) 18

Table 5 (continued) The Cost of Terrorism - Ordinary Least Squares Dependent Variable: Growth in Real GDP per capita Scale 0.030** (4.64) Openness 0.032** (4.84) Inflation -0.001** -2.20) Primary Goods Exporter -0.013-1.60) Government Size -0.027 (-1.62) Education Expenditure -0.104 (-1.02) Number of Observations 695 R Square 0.22 0.030** 0.030** 0.030** 0.030** 0.030** 0.030** 0.030** 0.030** (4.64) (4.64) (4.65) (4.65) (4.64) (4.65) (4.65) (4.65) 0.032** 0.032** 0.032** 0.032** 0.032** 0.032** 0.032** 0.032** (4.84) (4.86) (4.83) (4.86) (4.84) (4.86) (4.85) (4.86) -0.001** -0.001** -0.001** -0.001** -0.001** -0.001** -0.001** -0.001** -2.20) -2.19) -2.20) -2.19) -2.20) -2.20) -2.19) -2.20) -0.013-0.013-0.013-0.013-0.013-0.013-0.013-0.013 (-1.60) (-1.58) (-1.60) (-1.61) (-1.58) (-1.59) (-1.61) (-1.59) -0.026-0.027* -0.026-0.028* -0.026-0.026-0.026-0.026 (-1.61) (-1.64) (-1.61) (-1.68) (-1.61) (-1.61) (-1.62) (-1.61) -0.104-0.106-0.104-0.108-0.104-0.106-0.106-0.105 (-1.01) (-1.03) (-1.01) (-1.05) (-1.01) (-1.02) (-1.03) (-1.02) 695 695 695 695 695 695 695 695 0.22 0.22 0.22 0.22 0.22 0.22 0.22 0.22 19

We now turn to the relationship between the level of political rights of the victim country and the cost associated with terrorist attacks. As we have seen above, and contrary to expectations, countries that are more democratic are not more prone to terror attacks, after other aggregate indicators are controlled for. A different issue is whether the cost of a terrorist attack, once it occurs, is different in countries with a higher level of political rights. Table 6 reproduces the specification in Table 5 except that it adds each measure of terrorism incidence interacted with the level of political rights. That is, terrorism incidence enters both as an indicator in itself and interacted with political rights. Since a higher value of the political rights indicator in our sample indicates a higher level of civil liberties and more developed democratic institutions, we may interpret the sign on the interaction accordingly, a positive sign of the coefficient suggesting that the cost of a given terrorist attack for democracies is lower than for non-democracies. This is precisely what we obtain in Table 6. While an attack decreases the growth rate, its interaction with the political rights indicator is always positive and significant. In other words, democracies suffer less from a given attack. Figure 2 plots the total effect of a given terrorist event for different levels of political rights. It is obtained as the sum of the coefficient on the terrorism indicator with the coefficient on the interaction divided by the average level of political rights and then multiplied by its different levels, as in the x axis of Figure 1. All lines have a positive slope, as we would expect from the coefficient signs. We find that for Total Attacks, Civilian Attacks and Number Killed the line is very close to the zero effect on growth. For Attacks by Known Organizations the line is around 0.1 and for Total Affected (Killed plus Injured) the line is steep and takes values close to 0.1 for countries where political rights are at the highest level. However, when we test for the null hypothesis that the sum of the two coefficients being equal to 0, at different levels of political rights, we cannot reject the null. This is consistent with results from Table 6. Table 7 presents an alternative specification where, instead of using the terrorist indicator and adding the interacted variable, we use two alternative variables. The first is the value of the terrorism incidence indicator when political rights are below 0.5 and the second takes the same value if the political rights are above 0.5. 23 Thus, for given country and year, only one of these two variables takes the value of the indicator of terrorism incidence, the other taking the value 0. The results confirm those in Table 6: the higher the level of political rights, the lower the cost of terrorism. The sign of the coefficients of the low political rights victims are negative and significant, whereas the sign of the coefficients of the high political rights victims are positive and significant. The only exception are attacks on military targets, where the signs are the same but are not significantly different from 0. Actually, the positive sign on the incidence of terrorist attacks in high political rights countries suggests that these countries actually benefit from a small boom when an attack occurs. The coefficient of Total Terrorist Attacks suggests that one attack per 10 million people increases the rate of GDP growth by 0.077 percent. 23 The mean of political rights in our sample is 0.53, in a 0 to 1 range. 20

Total Terrorist Attacks Lagged pcgdp growth 0.247** (4.78) pcgdp -0.011 (-0.76) Terrorism Indicator -0.023** (-2.50) Terrorism Indicator * 0.091** Political Rights (2.12) Natural Disasters -0.044* (-1.81) Table 6 Political Rights and the Cost of Terrorism - Ordinary Least Squares Dependent Variable: Growth in Real GDP per capita Right-Hand Side Terrorism Indicator By Type of Target By Terrorist Organization By Number of Victims Civilian Military Political Known Unknown Total Affected Killed Injured 0.248** 0.248** 0.245** 0.248** 0.247** 0.247** 0.247** 0.247** (4.79) (4.79) (4.73) (4.78) (4.77) (4.780) (4.77 (4.790) -0.011-0.012-0.011-0.011-0.011-0.011-0.011-0.011 (-0.78) (-0.85) (-0.80) (-0.78) (-0.76) (-0.790) (-0.780) (-0.80) -0.025** -1.530** -0.145** -0.106-0.032** -0.007** -0.018** -0.008** (-2.23) (-1.05) (-2.64) (-1.47) (-2.69) (-3.820) (-2.77 (-3.450) 0.096* 1.890 0.532** 0.211** 0.183** 0.018** 0.054** 0.02** (1.92) (1.11) (3.01) (2.09) (1.870) (3.400) (3.070) (3.120) -0.044* -0.044* -0.043* -0.044* -0.044* -0.045* -0.044* -0.045* (-1.81) (-1.84) (-1.79) (-1.81) (-1.810) (-1.840) (-1.810) (-1.850) Bank or Currency Crisis -1.034** (-3.73) -1.045** -1.059** -1.049** -1.037** -1.046** -1.048** -1.044** -1.054** (-3.76) (-3.82) (-3.79) (-3.74) (-3.770) (-3.790) (-3.770) (-3.820) 21

Table 6 (continued) Political Rights and the Cost of Terrorism - Ordinary Least Squares Dependent Variable: Growth in Real GDP per capita Scale 0.031** (4.74) Openness 0.032** 4.81) Inflation -0.001** (-2.16) Primary Goods Exporter -0.011 (-1.41) Government Size -0.028* (-1.68) Education Expenditure -0.083 (-0.80) Number of Observations 676 R Square 0.23 0.031** 0.031** 0.031** 0.031** 0.031** 0.031** 0.031** 0.031** (4.74) (4.72) (4.76) (4.73) (4.750) (4.730) (4.760) (4.710) 0.032** 0.032** 0.032** 0.032** 0.032** 0.032** 0.032** 0.032** 4.81) 4.79) 4.80) 4.810) 4.810) 4.850) 4.830) 4.840) -0.001** -0.001** -0.001** -0.001** -0.001** -0.001** -0.001** -0.001** (-2.16) (-2.17) (-2.18) (-2.16) (-2.15) (-2.15) (-2.16) (-2.15) -0.011-0.012-0.011-0.011-0.011-0.011-0.011-0.011 (-1.43) (-1.47) (-1.41) (-1.40) (-1.42) (-1.41) (-1.40) (-1.44) -0.027* -0.026-0.027* -0.028* -0.027* -0.028* -0.027* -0.028* (-1.65) (-1.56) (-1.66) (-1.67) (-1.65) (-1.69) (-1.65) (-1.68) -0.081-0.075-0.077-0.081-0.083-0.088-0.083-0.088 (-0.79) (-0.73) (-0.74) (-0.78) (-0.80) (-0.85) (-0.80) (-0.84) 676 676 676 676 676 676 676 676 0.23 0.23 0.23 0.23 0.23 0.23 0.23 0.23 22