ENVIRONMENTAL GOVERNANCE THE ASPECT OF COORDINATION. Arild VATN a) ABSTRACT

Similar documents
Institutional Economics The Economics of Ecological Economics!

Economic Assistance to Russia: Ineffectual, Politicized, and Corrupt?

János Kornai s Contributions to Economic Analysis

Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance by Douglass C. North Cambridge University Press, 1990

Domestic Structure, Economic Growth, and Russian Foreign Policy

The Way Forward: Pathways toward Transformative Change

Evolutionary Game Path of Law-Based Government in China Ying-Ying WANG 1,a,*, Chen-Wang XIE 2 and Bo WEI 2

REGIONAL POLICY MAKING AND SME

We the Stakeholders: The Power of Representation beyond Borders? Clara Brandi

Final exam: Political Economy of Development. Question 2:

An Introduction to Institutional Economics

Diversity of Cultural Expressions

LAW OF THE RIGHTS OF MOTHER EARTH

New institutional economic theories of non-profits and cooperatives: a critique from an evolutionary perspective

Post-2008 Crisis in Labor Standards: Prospects for Labor Regulation Around the World

(GLOBAL) GOVERNANCE. Yogi Suwarno The University of Birmingham

Enlightenment of Hayek s Institutional Change Idea on Institutional Innovation

Remarks on the Political Economy of Inequality

The Political Economy of International Cooperation. (Thema Nr 3 )

INSTITUTIONS MATTER (revision 3/28/94)

TST Issue Brief: Global Governance 1. a) The role of the UN and its entities in global governance for sustainable development

Introduction to Economics

4 INTRODUCTION Argentina, for example, democratization was connected to the growth of a human rights movement that insisted on democratic politics and

1. Introduction. Michael Finus

CHAPTER 1 PROLOGUE: VALUES AND PERSPECTIVES

Management prerogatives, plant closings, and the NLRA: A response

Chapter II European integration and the concept of solidarity

Making the WTO More Supportive of Development. How to help developing countries integrate into the global trading system.

Functions of institutions X-institutions Y-institutions. ownership. Redistribution (accumulationconcordance-distribution)

Robust Political Economy. Classical Liberalism and the Future of Public Policy

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES

Import-dependent firms and their role in EU- Asia Trade Agreements

REFORMING WATER SERVICES: THE KEY ROLE OF MESO-INSTITUTIONS

ECONOMIC SYSTEMS AND DECISION MAKING. Understanding Economics - Chapter 2

DELOCALISATION OF PRODUCTION: THREATS AND OPPORTUNITIES FOR ESTONIA Abstract

Notes from discussion in Erik Olin Wright Lecture #2: Diagnosis & Critique Middle East Technical University Tuesday, November 13, 2007

RATIONAL CHOICE AND CULTURE

POLICY AREA A

Comments on Betts and Collier s Framework: Grete Brochmann, Professor, University of Oslo.

Sociological Theory II SOS3506 Erling Berge. Introduction (Venue: Room D108 on 31 Jan 2008, 12:15) NTNU, Trondheim. Spring 2008.

Running Head: POLICY MAKING PROCESS. The Policy Making Process: A Critical Review Mary B. Pennock PAPA 6214 Final Paper

Jürgen Kohl March 2011

Lobbying and Bribery

1. Free trade refers to a situation where a government does not attempt to influence through quotas

A Correlation of. Campbell. Biology. 9 th Edition, AP* Edition. to the. AP Biology Curriculum Framework

Regulation and Regulatory Environment: Case Study of Bhutan

MONEY AS A GLOBAL PUBLIC GOOD

VALUING DISTRIBUTIVE EQUALITY CLAIRE ANITA BREMNER. A thesis submitted to the Department of Philosophy. in conformity with the requirements for

Local Characteristics of the Democratic Regime Development of Macao

island Cuba: Reformulation of the Economic Model and External Insertion I. Economic Growth and Development in Cuba: some conceptual challenges.

Problems with Group Decision Making

Disagreement, Error and Two Senses of Incompatibility The Relational Function of Discursive Updating

A Comparison of Two Different Theoretical Approaches to Commons

1 Introduction. Cambridge University Press International Institutions and National Policies Xinyuan Dai Excerpt More information

Rise and Decline of Nations. Olson s Implications

Chapter 4 Specific Factors and Income Distribution

International Financial Stability as a Public Good

Trade Costs and Export Decisions

5. Markets and the Environment

Introduction to New Institutional Economics: A Report Card

Regulatory Governance of Network Industries: Experience and Prospects

Global Health Governance: Institutional Changes in the Poverty- Oriented Fight of Diseases. A Short Introduction to a Research Project

James M. Buchanan The Limits of Market Efficiency

Systematic Policy and Forward Guidance

Essays on Incentives and Regulation

Exploring Civilian Protection: A Seminar Series

International Trade Theory College of International Studies University of Tsukuba Hisahiro Naito

The future of the WTO: cooperation or confrontation

The Development of FTA Rules of Origin Functions

Major Group Position Paper

AM ): 9:00-11:10 AM

Notes on Charles Lindblom s The Market System

OLIVER E. WILLIAMSON University of California, Berkeley

CHAPTER 1 PROLOGUE: VALUES AND PERSPECTIVES

* Economies and Values

Influence of Identity on Development of Urbanization. WEI Ming-gao, YU Gao-feng. University of Shanghai for Science and Technology, Shanghai, China

SUMMARY OF THE IMPACT ASSESSMENT

Cover Page. The handle holds various files of this Leiden University dissertation.

Understanding Social Equity 1 (Caste, Class and Gender Axis) Lakshmi Lingam

Problems with Group Decision Making

INDEPENDENT SCHOOL DISTRICT 196 Rosemount-Apple Valley-Eagan Public Schools Educating our students to reach their full potential

Understanding Politics, Laws, & Economics. Chapter 2

Community Voices on Causes and Solutions of the Human Rights Crisis in the United States

INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS, FINANCE AND TRADE Vol. II - Property Rights and the Environment - Lata Gangadharan, Pushkar Maitra

China s Road of Peaceful Development and the Building of Communities of Interests

Invited Reaction Putting Theories of the Firm in Their Place: A Supplemental Digest of the New Institutional Economics

There is a seemingly widespread view that inequality should not be a concern

The Possible Incommensurability of Utilities and the Learning of Goals

A Policy Agenda for Diversity and Minority Integration

European Sustainability Berlin 07. Discussion Paper I: Linking politics and administration

Conclusion. Jobs, Skills, and Equity in a Cleaner U.S. Economy. A report by

The New Institutional Economics Basic Concepts and Selected Applications

Nairobi, Kenya, April 7th, 2009

PLT s GreenSchools! Correlation to the National Curriculum Standards for Social Studies

11/7/2011. Section 1: Answering the Three Economic Questions. Section 2: The Free Market

ECON 1100 Global Economics (Section 05) Exam #1 Fall 2010 (Version A) Multiple Choice Questions ( 2. points each):

Chinese Economic Reform from an International Perspective

Towards Sustainable Economy and Society Under Current Globalization Trends and Within Planetary Boundaries: A Tribute to Hirofumi Uzawa

Evolution of Competition Policy of Ukraine due to its Integration to the European Union

World business and the multilateral trading system

Transcription:

Vatn, A. Environmental Governance the Aspect of Coordination. ENVIRONMENTAL GOVERNANCE THE ASPECT OF COORDINATION Arild VATN a) a) Department of International Environment and Development Studies, Norwegian University of Life Sciences, Box 5003, Aas, Norway, e-mail: arild.vatn@umb.no ABSTRACT This paper is asks whether the way we organize our economy makes it possible to solve the increasing environmental challenges humanity is facing. The basic market-firm structure, around which the economy is foremost organized, is well suited to handle independent choices. The vexing environmental problems we are confronted with shows that human action is fundamentally interdependent. The paper argues that to handle the kind of coordination problems implicit in this, demands a change in the relationship between the state and the market or even a more fundamental process of reorganizing the economy. The paper discusses specifically the introduction of ex ante state regulations and changes to other types of property structures of productive activities with high levels of interdependency like expanding state respectively common property. The paper closes with a discussion of the realism of these strategies seen against present trends. Keywords: interdependency / institutions / transaction costs / rationality / private property / markets / state property / common property / civil society INTRODUCTION The main challenge facing environmental governance is to institutionally connect actions that are physically connected by necessity. Human action is interconnected through changes we make in the various biogeochemical cycles of the earth system e.g., the carbon and nitrogen cycles. More generally, the common-pool characteristics of environmental resources e.g., space, water and air make the act of one influence the opportunities for others. The increased scale of economic activity has augmented the magnitude of these interconnections vastly, and the perspective taken here is that we lag seriously behind regarding the process of institutionally reconnecting choices made by various separated decision units. In its basics, the problem is rather simple. A number of decision units exists using resources with consequences going beyond the borders of each unit. The problem is to secure that these consequences are taken into account when decisions are made. In reality the problem is, however, very challenging as the number of units is large, the effects are geographically often very widely spread, and the environmental systems with which human activities interact are very complex, involving time lags and non-linear responses. Solutions to these challenges often take the form of incremental adjustments to existing institutional structures. While there are certainly merits to such a procedure, one risks painting oneself into a corner. In the medium to long run, the effects of this ad hoc or piecemeal strategy could be very problematic indeed. My reasoning is based on the fact that present institutional structures for economic activity are to a large extent developed as if environmental interconnections were insignificant. At a time when we realize that this is not the case anymore, we should take stock and allow ourselves to think more fundamentally about the roads ahead.

The aim of this paper is therefore to give an assessment of a set of alternatives that could strengthen coordination. While institutional reform in practice will have to be contextual, I have here chosen to focus on a set of generic solutions to coordination problems. This is motivated by a need to strengthen the debate over the more fundamental choices we are facing. This demands an analysis of type solutions, being complementary to the equally important contextualized studies. In doing this, I have chosen to delimit the analysis in this paper to the state and intra state level. This is a vast simplification as environmental problems to a large extent are international. It is, however also so that very many of the principal questions concerning environmental governance can be treated when looking at the coordination problems appearing at the state/intra state level. The paper is divided in 5 sections. First I will specify what I mean by the concept of a coordination problem. To establish a reference point for the main analysis, I will next offer a description of coordination in spontaneous living systems. In Section 4 we move to the core area of the paper that of humanly constructed governance structures. Here I will first offer a description of a set of generic alternatives and next characterize the presently dominating governance system and discuss the way we currently try to handle environmental coordination. A set of serious shortcomings and principal contradictions is observed. Section 5 is hence devoted to sketch alternative ways to the contemporary solution giving also a brief assessment of these. Certainly, no new system can forget the past. No system can be ideal. We will have to choose among various shortcomings. Therefore, the paper closes with a discussion of the realism of various solutions against present trends. It also offers a set of cautions as to how the assessments made in this paper should be taken forward. THE COORDINATION PROBLEM Coordination is about facilitating interactions between agents that serves the purposes of these agents. It could be about producing or trading goods, or it could be about handling external effects of various actions. In the context of this paper, it will be useful to distinguish between coordination problems where action is independent and where it is interdependent. Coordination of independent acts will here be termed simple coordination problems. Coordination when acts are interdependent will be termed complex coordination problems. Human coordination involves institutions a set of conventions, norms or formal rules that facilitate coordinated outcomes (Scott 1995; Vatn 2005). There are three core issues involved when studying coordination. First, we have the rights governing distribution of resources or endowments the basis from where any activity can take place. The way rights are distributed and defended concerns also rights to potential cost shifting between decision units. Second, we have the costs of coordination i.e., transaction costs 1. Remark that if coordination is cost free, there is no way to distinguish between different institutional structures concerning the efficiency of coordination. Competitive markets, oligopolistic structures, firms, state organizations, etc. are equally efficient (Williamson 1985). Finally, we have the issue of motivation and how institutional structures influence these. This is an issue that is rarely covered in the literature on coordination. Agents are mostly taken to behave according to the same logic independent of under which institutional structure they operate. This assumption will be challenged in this paper. 1 Remark, information costs are considered part of transaction costs 2

A simple coordination problem involves then choices with only trivial information problems and no external effects/opportunities for cost shifting. The former can be illustrated by a situation where all agents involved have a set of endowments while being of different kinds, the elements of each kind are homogeneous 2. Using or transforming these assets results moreover in homogeneous goods. The coordination problem concerns how the various assets can be combined to produce the goods wanted and next distributed or exchanged. This is the standard problem as described in neoclassical welfare theory where market transactions are shown to produce Pareto optimality. This finding demands, however, the assumption of zero transaction costs to universally hold. As emphasized above, this makes it impossible to distinguish between different institutional structures on standard efficiency grounds. They may work differently concerning distribution and motivational structures, though. In the case of complex coordination problems, I will distinguish between two types dependent on the kind of interdependency involved. In the case of a complex coordination problem with specific interdependency there is interdependency between parties that engage directly with each other typically a two or few party relation. It may be the result of characteristics of the involved good. A case much emphasized in the literature concerns contracts over specific as opposed to homogeneous assets e.g., Williamson (1985; 2005). Asset specificity creates interdependency as the parties to a deal face problems with defining the various characteristics of what is to be produced/delivered. Given positive transaction costs/limited cognitive capacity, this is a situation which leads to incomplete contracts. In the literature, hierarchical solutions like firms are then favored over markets. In the case of a complex coordination problem with generalized interdependency there is indirect interdependency. Agents choices are interdependent because they take place in a common environment where choices have implications beyond the one/those directly acting. This is due to the interlinkages in that environment. Generally, endowments are not separable items. They are relational goods as they are integrated in webs of dynamic processes e.g., biological/ecosystem processes. Given the kind of world we live in, it is actually hard to imagine any coordination problem that does not involve some generalized interdependencies. All production activities demand inputs of natural resources which next changes their characteristics. Moreover, all production and consumption result in waste. There is no free disposal. So at both the input and output side of economic activities some consequences with implications for others not directly involved will appear. If these are minor, building institutional structures that disregard them may be acceptable. If they are more substantial, this may not be the case. SPONTANEOUS COORDINATION IN LIVING SYSTEMS The above perspective does not only concern human activities. It is rather a general feature of any living system. So how could such a system evolve and sustain itself? The biosphere is nothing less than a tremendous set of interconnections. Moreover it is generalized interconnection that is the main characteristics of this sphere. We are far from having a good understanding of this. Nevertheless, looking into this issue is helpful in establishing a basis from where to start thinking about how human coordination problems can be better handled. 2 i.e., no variation in quality across assets of the same kind 3

A living system demands a continuous recreation of its basis. This is a conclusion following from the fact that life is a specific type of order and could not be endured if the relevant qualities of matter was gradually exhausted i.e., entropic disorder or waste. The earth is (for practical purposes) a closed system implying that while energy is entering and leaving, matter is not. It is hence the low entropy of sun energy balanced by the high entropy of waste heat leaving the system that makes life with its continuous reproduction through complex interrelations possible (Georgescu-Roegen 1971). So from one perspective, enduring ecosystems must in some way have solved the tremendous coordination problem of generalized interdependency through various kinds of processes or feedbacks. Coordination in living systems happens at two levels. It is the internal coordination within each living unit or body and the coordination between these bodies. Certainly, bodies are open systems in metabolic terms, so the distinction is not sharp. Nevertheless, I find it reasonable to make a distinction between within and between living bodies interaction and coordination. Within-body-coordination implies a demand for what I will term direct functionality. Each part of the body must be able to deliver according to its functional responsibilities i.e., processes that are necessary for the working of the body as a whole like its sensing, its metabolism, its growth etc. Beyond-body-coordination implies a demand for indirect functionality. This implies that the basis for the delivery of continuous inputs to the separate bodies is maintained at least to the degree that the functioning of the wider system the body is a part of is not undermined. Rather it supports it. Certainly, the wider system will gradually change. The coordination necessary to make it stable is beyond the capacity of any self-organized system. The necessary flexibility to maintain life is the capacity for each species to adapt, respectively new species to appear. Life as such does not demand the existence of specific species. Single species may go extinct, while the larger system continues to evolve. A promising way of understanding coordination in living systems is found in hierarchy theory e.g., Pattee (1973); Simon (1973); Rosen (1991); Hàri and Müller (2000). Let me give a brief summary mainly based on Pattee (1973) to emphasize a set of core points. According to Pattee it is the control hierarchy 3 that is the distinguishing characteristic of life. In such a hierarchy the upper level exerts a specific, dynamic constraint on the details of the motion at lower level, so that the fast dynamics of the lower level cannot simply be averaged out. The collection of subunits that forms the upper level in a structural hierarchy now also acts as a constraint on the motion of selected individual subunits. This amounts to a feedback path between levels (p 77). He emphasizes that cells do not merely aggregate to form higher ordered bodies. Cells, being parts of bodies, differentiate due to rules imposed on it by the collection. Referring to the role of DNA or to the role of men holding office, Pattee asks how to explain that ordinary molecules and men can evolve such extraordinary authority as members of a collection. Or to put the problem in other words, how do structures that have only common physical properties as individuals achieve special functions in a collection? (ibid:78). His answer lies in the structurefunction duality the interface between the detail of structure and the abstraction of function. Specifically, a function or control can only arise through some selective loss of detail. This can be exemplified by the way cells adapt to signals from their environment e.g., from hormones. First, a decision must be made over what signal the higher level needs to send to the lower and next which information the lower level here the cell must focus on, as testing for 3 Pattee makes a distinction between a control hierarch and a structural hierarchy. In a structural hierarchy each level is made up by collections of units of a lower level. According to Simon (1973) such systems are near-decomposable. An example would be a set of atoms (level 1) forming a crystal (level 2), next forming a rock (level 3). 4

everything is not possible. So information costs are evident already at the level of the cell. The system can be illustrated by a three stage process of a hormone, a receptor and an effector protein. The signals from the hormones are captured by specific receptor proteins triggering responses when the signals are within certain bounds. Then receptor proteins typically bind with complementary effector proteins influencing the cell s own production (see for example Beavo and Brunton 2002). Two conclusions can be made on the basis of this. A hierarchical constraint can be seen as a form of classification of detail at a lower level. Second, the kind of coordination established by hierarchical systems balances between establishing constraints on lower levels without using up all the degrees of freedom i.e., securing room for adaptation at the lower level. In relation to that, Pattee also emphasizes that the establishment of constraints creates freedom as it secures the working of the larger whole on which each part is dependent. Control and adaptability seems both to be necessary capacities of living systems to exist. The control produces necessary order of e.g., flows of matter and energy. The system can however not be controlled in all its dimensions and without adaptability problems would also appear. Hence, there is a balance to be found here. Too little control would imply very heavy stress on the capacity to adapt. Beyond a certain level, collapse would appear. Similarly, too rigid control e.g., too little competition would dry out the source of variation or creativity necessary for adaptability to appear. GOVERNANCE Moving from biological to social systems, we introduce consciousness and self-reflexivity. Hence, while coordination in pure biological systems is understood as a result of blind trial and error given the physical and chemical capacities of matter and the productive capacity of energy, humans have the power to deliberatively construct coordination devices i.e., institutions. This offers quite substantial opportunities a new and very important degree of freedom is added. On the other hand, while a living system like the earth does not depend on the further existence of each and every specific species being present at a certain time in the future, the coordination problem as seen from the perspective of a single species like the human is different. It is about facilitating a systems dynamics that is well adapted to the needs of this species. Hence, moving from the systems level down to the demand for coordination as seen from the single species of humanity, one looses an important degree of freedom. So, in this sense the question is if the degree of freedom established by consciousness is what it takes to maintain the conditions for the long run survival of the species. In relation to this I will define governance as the establishment, maintenance and change of institutions to foster coordination and resolving conflicts. The subset of environmental governance is then governance related to coordination and resolving conflict over the use and maintenance of environmental resources cf. also Paavola (2007). Resource regimes the basic governance structures The institutional structures governing human resource use can be classified into types called resource regimes. This can most productively be done by referring to the principles or rules on 5

which they are based. Hence, a resource regime can be classified according to a) the rules governing the access to a certain resource, and b) the rules governing the distribution of the outputs made by those having such access (Vatn 2005). Rules of access to a certain resource are normally called property rights. For our purposes, the concept of property rights is too narrow, though. What is important is not only the right, but the way it is implemented. Hence, I will introduce the concept property rights organization. As we distinguish between four broad types of property rights, we may also differentiate between four types of property rights organizations: private property organization, public/state property organization, common property organization and open access. Systems for the distribution of the outputs made can be divided into four broad classes too: market distribution, public/state based distribution, community distribution, and finally no specified distribution rules. Together this creates 16 possible combinations see Table 1. Table 1: Resource regimes Access rules: Property rights org. Production distribution rules Market distribution Public/state distribution Community distribution No distribution rules Private property organization Public property organization Common property organization Open access Before we look at each system, it should be emphasized that the public or state actually plays a double role concerning resource regimes. According to the above, it may be a property holder. Maybe more important is its role as a 3 rd party in a) forming the rules for the different property systems and b) handling conflicts between property holders. I emphasize state or public as the function of a 3 rd party does not necessary have to rest with a state. It must, however, be an acknowledged power among its constituencies to work. Moreover, it must be the sole power of its kind for a certain domain to be able to function as a 3 rd party. Concerning the different organizations, a private property organization could be a family, a firm, but also at its limit an individual. A public property organization could be a state, a county or a local municipality administration. Finally, a common property organization could be a collection of families, firms or individuals who own a resource together. Open access is really lack of both rights and organization being everybody s right it is nobody s property. All three forms of property organization except open access include some kind of internal hierarchical or command structures. Even in the case of common property the type with the strongest horizontal coordination there are normally some elements of hierarchy related to the internal coordination rules. Hence, there are both operational and collective-choice rules (cf. Ostrom 2005). The aim here is still not to delve in the grey areas, but emphasize the type characteristics of the four. Concerning distribution rules, they relate to interaction between agents or organizations. In the case of markets, distribution takes the form of contract based trades between the property organizations involved buyers and sellers. In the case of public/state or community based distribution, the distribution rules are in a sense part of the organization itself. They concern rules developed by the organization for the distribution to or among its members. So while one can still maintain the distinction between access and distribution rules, both are within organization matters. In the case of public/state distribution, the typical form is redistribution 6

based on government/parliament decisions and/or negotiations. Also in the case of communities there will be systems of redistribution. What is specific to communities, however, is the rule of sharing or reciprocity and the role of direct communication. Finally, there is also the possible situation with no specific rules defining the distribution of outputs. The typical example would be unregulated external effects. Both the property organizations and the distribution rules are coordination devices. As emphasized in the literature on business organization, one important issue concerns which is the better to use. The dominant literature on this e.g., Coase (1937 and 1992); Williamson (1975, 1985, 1999 and 2005) discusses the choice between hierarchies (firms) and markets and the economizing of transaction or coordination costs. Hence, there is substitution opportunities between the two types of coordination the within and between entities coordination. One might typically link private property and market distribution, state property with state distribution and common property with community distribution. There is, however, no reason why products from e.g., a state owned entity could not be distributed in markets. Similarly products from a private property organization could be distributed using public distribution rules. Examples are abundant e.g., publicly owned electricity plants selling energy in markets; private health businesses distributing their services according to a set of publicly defined rules. In the above I have referred to the distribution of outputs, not products. The reason for that is that not all outputs have a positive value hence are not products. Some will be waste. Creating complex coordination problems of the generalized type, these outputs also demand some ownership and distribution rules. Actually as all production in the end becomes waste, these rules may be seen at least as important as the rules for handling the products. The fact that we do not seem to have realized this yet will be treated in the next section. The fundamental question related to the above is how well different regimes facilitate coordination both over products and waste. So far institutional development over the former issue has dominated that concerning simple coordination and complex coordination problems of specific interdependence. As the amount of generalized interdependencies increases, the regime question is shifted towards evaluating the trade-off between the capacity to coordinate production and how easy it becomes to coordinate waste handling/side-effects. In relation to this, it should be noted that regimes influence both which side-effects appear and how they can be treated. Resource management the character of present governance systems All the 16 resource regimes illustrated by Table 1 can be found in practice. Nevertheless, if we look at production both measured in economic terms and in tons of material throughput the dominant resource regime at present is that of private property organizations operating in markets. This is, however, only half the story since for waste output the dominant situation has been open access and no distribution rules. Historically, the treatment of waste was very much handled by community rules. The tremendous growth of these flows over the last century has vastly transcended the community as a unit for coordination. It has been gradually regulated mainly by increasing the role of state/public distribution rules. Presently we witness though an increased interest in market solutions also in this area e.g., payments for environmental services (Wunder 2005). 7

In relation to the above, we should first note that the state as 3 rd party has played a fundamental role in the deliberate construction of the firm-market regime. The history of this structure is long and consists of many turns both concerning the establishment and expansion of private property and the format of markets (e.g., Veblen 1904; Commons 1934; Polanyi 1944; Bakan 2004). Finally, states have played a decisive role also in the construction of rules for interactions of private property organizations across state borders like the Bretton Woods organization, the GATT/WTO etc. One of the basic aims behind establishing private property has been to ascertain security for investments through establishing a direct link between activity and individual returns from that activity. Not least through the creation of the stock holding company, the dynamism was substantially expanded as individual capitals could be easily pooled. Together with various trade liberalization efforts, this has created a very forceful system resulting in a level of economic growth that is historically unprecedented. 4 A core element in this has been to foster separation of decisions and hence separation of responsibilities. From the above, this system works, however, best for simple coordination problems. It may function reasonably well also in the case of complex coordination problems with specific interdependency e.g., high asset specificity. Under these conditions, formulating market contracts is demanding resulting in high transaction costs, and we observe the tendency to move from market coordination to hierarchical structures like vertically integrated firms (Williamson 1985; 2005). While this shifts the power from the market to the internal of the firm, it is nevertheless a development within the market-firm resource regime. The market-firm regime and generalized interdependencies The main problem with the market-firm regime in connection to the issues discussed here is its ability to handle generalized interdependencies. One type is the kind illustrated by the present financial crisis, where there are interdependencies in expectations formation following from tremendous information problems/restricted cognitive capacities in a system with many independent decision units. The more important effect of separation is in our case nonetheless related to the effects on natural resource qualities and management. In a system where natural resource use is divided into separate entities and all interaction happens through markets, the only way coordination of the utilization of natural resources can happen is through the price mechanism. This demands next that all resources are owned and that the price mechanism works properly. Let me start with the latter. According to Hayek (1931; 1948) the price mechanism is superior as it is able to solve the vast information problem that humans face when coordinating their activities. He emphasizes that knowledge is local and specific. The strength of the market is that it does not depend on anyone possessing all this localized knowledge. The price mechanism distributes the information necessary to coordinate the separate action of different people (Hayek 1948:85). There are two problems related to this reasoning see also O Neill (1998). The first concerns the problem of making decisions into the future as commodity prices only conveys information about the present and not about future plans. Firms have rather motives not to offer such 4 Certainly, the level of growth experienced in China the last couple of decennia with a combination of state property/command and free enterprise indicates that this hybrid may outcompete the more pure firm-market regime. Moreover, the introduction of the welfare state taken to its farthest development in Scandinavia indicates that economic growth may not be hampered by a large public sector. The opposite may rather be the case. Whether privatization always is a success in growth terms is also an issue with certain qualifications e.g., Rozelle and Swinnen (2004) comparing the transition of agriculture in China and former Soviet Union. 8

information. The second problem concerns whether the price with its specific type of selective loss of detail conveys the most relevant type of information processing for capturing the status of ecosystems/environmental resources. These are complex entities with a multiplicity of dimensions as they are also involved in a multitude of processes. As emphasized by e.g., Martines- Alier et al. (1998) and Vatn and Bromley (1994), there is a tremendous reduction of information involved when condensing this information into one price. Certainly, for coordination to be possible, selective loss of detail is necessary. This was a core conclusion from Section 3 on spontaneous coordination. The question is whether the price mechanism offers the relevant loss of detail for environmental governance to work well. There are strong arguments for this not being the case. The market price is a measure of relative scarcity based on aggregate demand. As environmental resources are integrated in webs of relations, it is their role in the functioning of these wholes that is the important question. These relations are first of all situated locally. Hence, their importance varies across space and time demanding local prices. Second, while each of the multiple functions that a resource expresses represents a simplification of information, collapsing next each of these functions into one measure demanding substitutability between them. While some natural resources can be substituted for each other in functional terms cf. the fact that different species can deliver the same function(s) this does not imply that it is a generalizable feature. Rather natural resource systems are characterized by complementarities, hence restricted substitution possibilities. So even if we assume that Hayek is right in his claim that the price of a commodity is the only message that is needed for agents to make their decisions whether to buy or not that commodity in their local contexts, the argument must be turned on its head when looking at the making of the commodity or the disposing of the commodity after it is reduced to waste. Concerning production, the commodity itself carries scant information about the changes in the functioning of the systems from which the resources necessary to make that commodity were taken. If these consequences or costs are shifted beyond the property organization making it, no information is captured. If they are within these bounds, they are reduced to one dimension that of exchange value. Finally, natural living systems are characterized by discontinuities i.e., they embody thresholds with rather abrupt changes when these thresholds are exceeded (Perrings 1997). This implies that up to a certain level, changing a living system may not change its fundamental functioning. This is the obvious result from the observation that living systems have evolved so that different processes (species) deliver the same function(s). This makes the system resilient and has been important for it to handle changes in its environment. Nevertheless, beyond a certain level of change, the fundamental dynamics of a system may be changed an attractor shift has occurred. A price, as a measure of marginal values, is specifically unable to capture this. The other side of the above coin is that attaching private property to all environmental resources is for practical purposes impossible. As environmental resources are foremost interlinked processes, dividing them into separate units would either destroy their functional capacities or be just formal implying that the processes would de facto transcend the different units of decision making. To the extent that these processes are changed, we will observe specific and/or generalized cost shifting. Certainly, if a meaningful set of local prices could be attached to each of these costs actually making markets for all processes with their specific and generalized effects the regime could still do well. The problem is that by splitting up the protected access to the resources into 9

individual pieces, the number of processes that are interrupted and the number of borders across which this interruption happens is vast. So as Bromley (1990) has emphasized, what makes the internal system work well the maximization of competing units in markets also maximizes the transaction costs related to the bargaining over side effects. The capacities of ex post state regulation Certainly, the above problem has resulted in increased state intervention in the form of legal regulations e.g., prohibition of certain cost shifting activities or by installing economic instruments like taxes or tradable quotas. Hence, as economic activity has increased driven by the internal dynamism of the resource regime the enlarged amount of cost shifting created has been countered by expanding the role of the state as a 3 rd party. The main effect of this is the establishment of a hierarchical control resulting in reduced transaction costs making it possible to handle many externalities or cost shifting activities which would escape the market. Following the ideas of Simon (1973), the hierarchy represents a simplification of the information flow. First, each economic agent needs to confront only one other agent the state and not the myriads of other agents influenced by e.g., emissions (generalized interdependence). Second, the hierarchy offers the option to classify to group units at the lower level and treat them as similar. Combined, these two mechanisms reduce necessary transactions and information flows vastly, making it possible to treat a series of interrelationships that would evade any horizontal treatment. Certainly, establishing e.g., taxes reflecting the cost of emissions at the margin is not a simple task, and even the state needs to balance the cost of setting up precise regulations transaction costs against the gain of being precise (Vatn 1998). While state regulations have made it possible to make a lot of progress in the field of environmental governance, there are plenty of challenges ahead. I would like to emphasize two, which were both implicit in the above. The first concerns the two-stage character of the instituted processes. The second concerns the trade-off between simplification and specificity of knowledge that any system faces. Concerning the first issue - the two-stage character of the instituted processes the challenge relates to the sequencing of decision making and information flows. While the economic units at level 1 of the system the firms are controlled by a level 2 set of institutional structures as formulated by the state this control is based on the assumption that ex post correction is sufficient. By ex post I mean that state regulation is instituted after harm is observed and the cause of the harm is proven. The historical development of the system was as emphasized above based on separating decision units and foster horizontal interaction in markets. The system really established an unbounded type of positive feedbacks where the growth of one unit supported the growth of others (cf. Says law). As already emphasized, doing so must have been based on the belief that physical interdependencies across separated units would cause only minor problems that could be efficiently corrected ex post. As the economy grows, it becomes more and more problematic to allow agents to develop through various positive feedbacks as if there were no (or just minor) unnoticed influences across the borders of these agents. When the problem grows large enough so that the second level agent the state observes that there is a problem, it must prove what causes it, and finally institute a reaction if the gain of doing so is found to be sufficiently large. There is a problem of time lag in this. Past harm will not be treated. Time spans may cover several decennia even centuries. Moreover, as resources cannot be reallocated without costs, we observe path 10

dependency. This implies that the costs of correcting a problem ex post depends on previous decisions made under the assumption that there would be no problem. Hence, these costs could be large. In addition, those involved in producing under this assumption will be interested in protecting the status quo rules to avoid any regulation. Path dependency is not only technical or economic. It becomes also political. Taken together the two stage model the ex post regulation model will produce a path that is very different from other institutional structures. Concerning the second problem the trade-off between needed simplification in information flows and the specificity of knowledges necessary for local management the state-firm hierarchy faces several challenges, too. These concern both the specificities of natural resource dynamics, and that of human motivation. Certainly, Hayek is right in emphasizing that local knowledge is specific and that the state cannot collect and handle all this information. Rather, for the functioning of the state regulation, loss of detail is necessary. On the other hand, knowledge of detail is important when carrying out actions at the lower level. Hence, state action depends on its necessarily coarse messages being transformed into lower level action that is more informed and specific. This demands that it is in the interest of the lower level units to not just follow the coarse message to the minimum i.e., utilizing fully the fact that the state has restricted capacity in evaluating and controlling lower level action. It also demands that lower level units internalize the goals formulated at the higher level and take local action that is well adapted to their circumstances. This must not only concern their individual interests. In their adaptation they must also consider the consequences for others. There are certainly huge variations in what is demanded as the information problems vary substantially across topic areas. Hence, in the case of homogeneous emissions from economic activity by which I mean that an input into the economy results in the same environmental consequence independent of how it is used and where emissions take place 5 information problems at the interface between the controlling and the operative level are relatively small. Like in the case of CO 2 emissions from fossil fuels, a tax or tradable quota on inputs is in principle all that is needed if we look at it in pure informational terms. The amount of CO 2 emissions is proportional to the input and where the emissions happen has no impact on the climate change effect. Since fossil fuel is a marketed good, it is technically quite easy to regulate this way. In the case of ecosystem management including adaptation to climate change, effects are localized and/or dependent on the specific technology used. In such situations regulation is technically much more demanding. To get good results, the lower level agents have to take the aim of the policy, not only the specific signal or incentive directed at their behavior into account to secure a necessary transformation of the regulatory message to the local context. 6 ALTERNATIVE DIRECTIONS TO TAKE The above characterization of the problems we face is meant as a basis for starting to think about alternative ways to organize ourselves to better handle generalized interdependencies. This is both a huge intellectual and political problem. While my area is the former, I certainly acknowledge that we are far away from having solutions even at the conceptual level. I will nevertheless 5 See Vatn (1998) for further clarification and proofs. 6 The above conclusion is supported by Tietenberg (2002) and Rose (2002), while their perspective is a bit different from that of this paper. 11

try to take some small steps further just to indicate the kind of issues we are up against. As already emphasized, I will restrict myself to the problem at the level of a single state. I will briefly indicate three different paths to follow. First, I will look at a change in the present regime based on private property organization and markets moving from ex post to ex ante state regulations of externalities. Next, I will look at a movement towards increasing the role of state as property owner, and finally I will look at an increased role of common property and civil society engagement. In comparing these three alternatives, both information/transaction cost issues and the kind of motivational structures that are fostered through the various institutional arrangements will be underlined. Ex ante regulations One way of handling generalized interdependencies could be a more systematic use of ex ante as opposed to ex post state measures. This would, in our situation, imply that firms had to get an ex ante acceptance from the society that a certain activity could be started including also specified conditions for it to continue as a going concern. In practice such a right would have to be granted by the state and represent a strengthening of hierarchical power. Compared to ex post regulation, this would imply turning the burden of proof around and demand ex ante proof of safety or acceptable levels of harm. It would represent a substantial change compared to the present situation concerning how private property is generally viewed and institutionalized. It could even be argued to be against the very idea of private property with its role in granting freedom of choice. Nevertheless, Honoré (1961) in discussing what characterizes full ownership emphasizes prohibition of harmful use as one of 11 points. Hence, according to this understanding ownership does not include a right to harm others. Following from the above situations with generalized interdependencies, avoiding harmful use would, however, be impossible. Therefore one could argue that it is not against, rather in line with the idea of private property to institute comprehensive ex ante regulations securing avoidance of harm in the case of generalized interdependencies. Since society depends on production, the rules established would nevertheless have to balance the need for avoiding harm with the need for a well functioning production sector. This is the challenge for ex ante regulation not least because it will be very demanding as most production activities will include some generalized interdependencies and the assessment must be based on uncertain information about future consequences of various levels of regulation. Taken to its limit, ex ante regulation could be understood as demanding a documentation showing that harm beyond certain predefined limits will not happen. Offering such proof would not be possible in most cases, implying that either many potential producers would be unable to prove their products to be socially acceptable, or the ex ante regulation would have to include quite some flexibility around the limits set. One way of establishing flexibility is to institutionalize a learning procedure beyond the initial evaluation, hence combine weaker ex ante regulation with a continuous evaluation of consequences facilitating learning. This solution could be seen as analogous to the idea of adaptive management as advocated among scholars in the field of ecosystem management (e.g., Folke et al. 2005). The challenge for instituting this in a private property-market setting relates not least to the fact that private property holders would need some security for their investments to be willing to invest. Instituted adaptive learning in such a setting faces the risk that the 12

investment will could collapse and that unnecessarily low production/high unemployment rates would prevail. Despite this, one should observe that there are already examples of this kind of regulations in place. They concern, however, mainly products where direct consequences for human health is involved e.g., rules demanding pre-testing of drugs against potential negative health effects. The European regimes for regulating the production and use of genetically modified organisms (Kvakkestad and Vatn 2008) is another example where both health and ecosystem issues are involved. The latter case illustrates the problem with proving harm respectively safety. As e.g., the EU rules are formulated, only short run consequences are assessed, while the issues raised from e.g., some ecologists concern consequences over a much longer time horizon (Kvakkestad et al. 2007). Expanding state property In a case of generalized interdependencies, one way would be to opt for a solution where all interdependencies are made internal to a single decision unit. Like in the case of the firm (Coase 1937) or the vertically integrated business (Williamson 1985) one would then bring the involved interdependencies the type of dynamics that markets are weak at handling under the same information and authority structure. As the side-effects of production is generalized i.e., influencing everybody in some sense the only logical business with the capacity to directly include all relationships would be a single firm or the state. Circumventing here the question about what would be the difference between the two, I will sketch some questions concerning what a solution with moving to state property would imply. Bringing decision under one roof would, in principle, make it possible to assemble all necessary information to evaluate where to strike the balance between protection and expansion, between commodity production and the level of acceptable environmental harm. It should in principle remove the type of strategic information games characterizing state regulation of private businesses. One could also avoid the specific uncertainty around investments discussed above and facilitate learning without potentially endanger the will of investment in future production. While the breakdown of the Soviet Union was not only the result of problems related to centralized planning, the experience it offers certainly makes us reluctant to go down this alley. The problem can be split in two that of information overload and that of agents motivation. The information problem in state planning While the logic of generalized interdependencies points towards establishing a regime where these could be treated simultaneously under one decision structure i.e., remove transaction costs this does not eliminate the information problems in themselves. What is done is to establish a structure where the information is treated under one common authority. This makes it possible to treat uncertainties in a different way compared to both ex ante and ex post regulations of firms. The system should in principle also open up for greater flexibility concerning changing strategies when new information is available. It will not depend on renegotiating terms with involved firms. Moreover, this system should not be hampered by strategic conflicts over harm/safety proofs as is the case with external regulations. These are all important potentials that should be seriously considered. The problems relate not least to information overload and the need to still split or specialize information flows and 13

decision arenas within the state. Concerning overload, some of these problems could obviously be avoided by letting state properties operate in markets, off loading the system with having to separately produce information about commodity demand. Compared to the above discussion, one could still escape some of the problems with strategic use of information asymmetries and investment reluctance as in the case of ex ante regulations of private firms. Concerning specializing information flows and decision arenas, the challenge would be that while formally part of the same hierarchy, this division would tend to create epistemic subcultures. This could easily result in internal rivalry between branches of the state as is well observed even today. Specifically, in the case of market oriented state firms, conflicts between state firms operating in markets and the regulatory branch of the state would most probably occur. So while the authority structure would be different to that of state-private, the problems would far from vanish. As emphasized earlier, there is also an issue of local information related not only to commodity demand, but also ecosystem functioning. Hence, we face the issue of optimal loss of detail, or of balancing which decisions should be taken high up in the state hierarchy and what could be decentralized. The function of the higher levels would be to coordinate, while that of the lower would be to offer sensitivity to changes, to capture necessary information detail and to learn about ecosystem dynamics. Following the perspectives raised in Section 3 of this paper, maintaining necessary degree of freedom at the lower levels is very important, but will also create a tension in the system as it is a potential source for internal conflict with higher level decisions. The motivational aspects of state planning This takes us to the aspect of motivation. On the basis of the standard public choice literature e.g., Niskanen 1971; Dearlove 1989 one would argue that state power would rather have to imply abuse of power and no capacity to solve common problems. Public authorities would support what is best for themselves, not for society. Moreover, each official would follow what is individually best for him/her. In a certain sense this argument is quite logical. It follows the idea that humans are motivated only by individual interests e.g., they maximize individual utility. Given this, it would be necessary to construct a private reward structure for public officials that is systematically reflecting their provisioning of common goods. This is not only very demanding in informational terms. It also is impossible as it demands agents involved that do not depend on such motivation i.e., those constructing the motivation structures for the subordinates. The logic of all-encompassing individual interests ends in an infinite regress concerning any capacity to solve common problems. While logical from the perspective of strict individualism, this reasoning would imply that no society could really exist. This is counter to observation. So while the problem of bureaucratic control is a serious one, it is most probably so that the model of the agent used in public choice theory is far too restricted. Based on a century of observations from both anthropological and sociological studies, and from recent experiments in economics and social psychology, there are strong arguments in favor of the hypothesis that motivations are plural e.g., Barth (1967); Etzioni (1988); Bowles (1998); Fehr and Gächter (2000); Gintis (2000); Gneezy and Rustichini (2000; Gintis et al. (2005). While some situations are quite well described by the standard model of individual utility maximization, these are first of all typically characterized being quite simple e.g., Davis and Holt (1993). When complexity is increased, problems appear e.g., Tversky and Kahneman (1986) and the issue of framing effects and preference reversals. What is the more interesting observation here is that people in many contexts act in ways taking the interests 14