Does opportunism pay off?

Similar documents
political budget cycles

Election Results and Opportunistic Policies: A New Test of the Rational Political Business Cycle Model

Political Budget Cycles in New versus Established Democracies

Documentos de Trabalho Working Paper Series

Political Budget Cycles in New versus Established Democracies. Adi Brender and Allan Drazen* This Draft: August 2004

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES POLITICAL BUDGET CYCLES IN NEW VERSUS ESTABLISHED DEMOCRACIES. Adi Brender Allan Drazen

Electorally-induced crime rate fluctuations in Argentina

The determinants of vote intentions in Portugal

CURRICULUM VITAE. Positions at International Scientific Associations President of the European Public Choice Society, since April 2017.

The interaction effect of economic freedom and democracy on corruption: A panel cross-country analysis

Being a Good Samaritan or just a politician? Empirical evidence of disaster assistance. Jeroen Klomp

The determinants of vote intentions in Portugal *

The Political Business Cycle in Ontario: An Empirical Analysis of Financial and Demographic Data across Medium to Large-Sized Ontario Municipalities

Pork Barrel as a Signaling Tool: The Case of US Environmental Policy

Electoral Fiscal Policy in New, Old, and Fragile Democracies

Evidence from French Municipalities

Where Does the Political Budget Cycle Really Come From? Adi Brender and Allan Drazen* July 2003

Electoral Incentives and Budgetary Spending: Rethinking the Role of Political. Institutions. Eric C.C. Chang

The Distortionary Effects of Power Sharing on Political Corruption and Accountability: Evidence from Kenya

By Any Means Necessary: Multiple Avenues of Political Cycles

Pakistan, Politics and Political Business Cycles

Electoral competition and corruption: Theory and evidence from India

Does Political Business Cycle exist in India? By

INFER Public Economics Group Workshop. Vote expectations and pre-electoral tariff cuts in Flemish municipalities

Economic Growth, Campaign Pledges and Election Outcomes

Punished for austerity?

Journal of Public Economics

Women and Power: Unpopular, Unwilling, or Held Back? Comment

Determinants and Effects of Negative Advertising in Politics

Real Convergence in the European Union

Prologue Djankov et al. (2002) Reinikka & Svensson (2004) Besley & Burgess (2002) Epilogue. Media and Policy

Fiscal redistribution around elections when democracy is not the only game in town

Publicizing malfeasance:

Intergovernmental Fiscal Transfers and Tactical Political Maneuverings: Evidence from Ghana s District Assemblies Common Fund ABEL FUMEY

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US

Candidates Quality and Electoral Participation: Evidence from Italian Municipal Elections

Pedro Telhado Pereira 1 Universidade Nova de Lisboa, CEPR and IZA. Lara Patrício Tavares 2 Universidade Nova de Lisboa

Multiparty Competition, Founding Elections and Political Business Cycles in Africa. Steven Block, Smita Singh, Karen E. Ferree

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOW ELECTIONS MATTER: THEORY AND EVIDENCE FROM ENVIRONMENTAL POLICY. John A. List Daniel M. Sturm

Uncertainty and international return migration: some evidence from linked register data

Voter Rationality and Exogenous Shocks: Misattribution of Responsibility for Economic Shocks

Keskustelualoitteita #47 Joensuun yliopisto, Taloustieteet. Business Cycles, Political Incentives and the Macroeconomy: Comparison of Models

The Effect of Ballot Order: Evidence from the Spanish Senate

Evidence from Randomized Evaluations of Governance Programs. Cristobal Marshall

The determinants of vote intentions in Portugal

GEORG-AUGUST-UNIVERSITÄT GÖTTINGEN

The Political Cycle of Public-Private Contract Renegotiations: Evidence from the French car park sector

Timing tariff increases over the electoral cycles : an empirical investigation of political decision making

Practice Questions for Exam #2

DISCUSSION PAPERS Department of Economics University of Copenhagen

Endogenous antitrust: cross-country evidence on the impact of competition-enhancing policies on productivity

Women as Policy Makers: Evidence from a Randomized Policy Experiment in India

Political Budget Cycles and the Civil Service: Evidence from Highway Spending in US States

EU enlargement and the race to the bottom of welfare states

A REPLICATION OF THE POLITICAL DETERMINANTS OF FEDERAL EXPENDITURE AT THE STATE LEVEL (PUBLIC CHOICE, 2005) Stratford Douglas* and W.

Classical papers: Osborbe and Slivinski (1996) and Besley and Coate (1997)

Causality for the government budget and economic growth

Democracy and government spending

Does government decentralization reduce domestic terror? An empirical test

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach

Supplemental Online Appendix to The Incumbency Curse: Weak Parties, Term Limits, and Unfulfilled Accountability

Is Corruption Anti Labor?

Chapter Four: Chamber Competitiveness, Political Polarization, and Political Parties

Policy Responses to Speculative Attacks Before and After Elections: Theory and Evidence

On the Causes and Consequences of Ballot Order Effects

Residential segregation and socioeconomic outcomes When did ghettos go bad?

Does electoral pressure lead to better government performance?

Brain drain and Human Capital Formation in Developing Countries. Are there Really Winners?

All democracies are not the same: Identifying the institutions that matter for growth and convergence

Unemployment and the Immigration Surplus

The determinants of vote intentions in Portugal

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA?

Political Parties and Economic

THE WEBER-FECHNER LAW AND PUBLIC EXPENDITURES IMPACT TO THE WIN-MARGINS AT PARLIAMENTARY ELECTIONS

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation

The cost of ruling, cabinet duration, and the median-gap model

The Political Business Cycles in the EU enlarged

Differential effects of graduating during a recession across gender and race

Violent Conflict and Inequality

Human Capital and Income Inequality: New Facts and Some Explanations

King s Research Portal

PARTY AFFILIATION AND PUBLIC SPENDING: EVIDENCE FROM U.S. GOVERNORS

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES

Pork Barrel as a Signaling Tool: The Case of US Environmental Policy

TITLE: AUTHORS: MARTIN GUZI (SUBMITTER), ZHONG ZHAO, KLAUS F. ZIMMERMANN KEYWORDS: SOCIAL NETWORKS, WAGE, MIGRANTS, CHINA

Labor versus capital in trade-policy: The role of ideology and inequality

Negative advertising and electoral rules: an empirical evaluation of the Brazilian case

GENDER EQUALITY IN THE LABOUR MARKET AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT

What Happens to the Careers of European Workers when. Immigrants "Take their Jobs"?

Pavel Yakovlev Duquesne University. Abstract

International Cooperation, Parties and. Ideology - Very preliminary and incomplete

The Size of Local Legislatures and Women s Political Representation: Evidence from Brazil

WORKING PAPERS ON POLITICAL SCIENCE

Business Cycles, Migration and Health

Electoral Rules and Public Goods Outcomes in Brazilian Municipalities

Corruption, Political Instability and Firm-Level Export Decisions. Kul Kapri 1 Rowan University. August 2018

Voters as Fiscal Liberals

Global Samaritans? Donor Election Cycles and the Allocation of Humanitarian Aid*

Does the G7/G8 Promote Trade? Volker Nitsch Freie Universität Berlin

Size of Regional Trade Agreements and Regional Trade Bias

Transcription:

Does opportunism pay off? Linda G. Veiga, Francisco José Veiga Universidade do Minho and NIPE, Portugal Received 22 June 2006; received in revised form 1 December 2006; accepted 20 December 2006 Available online 27 April 2007 Abstract In Portugal, increases in investment expenditures and changes in the composition of spending favouring highly visible items are associated with higher vote percentages for incumbent mayors seeking re-election. The political payoff to opportunistic spending increased after democracy became well-established in the country. 2007 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. Keywords: Voting functions; Opportunism; Local governments; Elections; Portugal JEL classification: D72; H72 1. Introduction The objective of this article is to determine whether opportunistic mayors can increase their chances of reelection 1 by generating political budgetary cycles around elections. We test the hypothesis that pre-electoral increases in municipal expenditures and changes in their composition, favouring items most visible to or preferred by the electorate, are associated with higher vote percentages for the incumbent mayor. Research is conducted over a dataset comprising all Portuguese mainland municipalities, from 1979 to 2001. In previous work, Veiga and Veiga (2007) found strong evidence of political budgetary cycles in Portuguese municipalities. They also showed that electoral cycles were stronger for investment items highly visible to the electorate, for example, construction spending on public infrastructure. Given these results, it would also be Corresponding author. Escola de Economia e Gestão, Universidade do Minho, 4710057 Braga, Portugal. Tel.: +351 253604564; fax: +351 253676375. E-mail address: linda@eeg.uminho.pt (L.G. Veiga). 1 For a literature review on vote and popularity functions see Paldam (2004).

interesting to know if voters reward (or punish) politicians' opportunistic spending policies. Additionally, because democracy was reestablished in Portugal in 1974, during our sample period the country has evolved from a new to an established democracy. This makes Portugal an appropriate laboratory for analyzing if the determinants of electoral results change as a democracy matures. There are several other reasons that make Portugal an interesting case for study. First, we have very detailed data on local governments' financial accounts. Second, the mayor is a principal decision-maker in the allocation of resources and the distribution of investment in the municipality. Third, the institutional structure of local governments and the policy instruments available are the same for all Portuguese localities. Finally, election dates are fixed and defined exogenously from the perspective of the local authorities, and all municipalities have elections on the same day. 2 2. Data, model specification and results The dataset is composed of data on a set of political, financial and economic variables for 275 Portuguese mainland municipalities, for years from 1979 to 2001. 3 Since this article tries to determine whether or not political opportunism by mayors pays off, only the cases in which they run for re-election are considered. The two models used in the empirical work are specified as follows: Votes it ¼ avotes i;prev:el: þ /YM it þ cgp it þ b 1 IE it þ b 2 IE i;t 1 þ b 3 IE i;t 2 þ m i þ e it Votes it ¼ avotes i;prev:el: þ /YM it þ cgp it þ b 1 IEtm it þ b 2 IEdev it þ m 1 þ e it ð1þ ð2þ i ¼ 1; ;275 t ¼ 1979;1982;1985;1989;1993;1997;2001 where Votes it is the percentage of votes obtained by the incumbent's party in the municipality i, in election of year t, Votes i,prev.el. is the percentage of votes obtained in the previous election, YM it stands for Years Mayor (the number of years the mayor of municipality i has been in office), GP it is a measure of Government Performance/Popularity, 4 IE are levels of real per capita Investment Expenditures (in the election year, t; the year before elections, t 1; and 2 years before elections, t 2), 5 IEtm is its term 2 During the sample period, there were local elections in 1979, 1982, 1985, 1989, 1993, 1997 and 2001, always in December. 3 Election dates and municipal electoral results were obtained from STAPE, Portugal. The government popularity index is based on monthly surveys published in the newspaper Expresso, from 1986 to 2001. Data on municipal accounts and population, from 1979 to 2001, were obtained from DGAL, Portugal. Data on the total number of employees in firms within each municipality and on their average wages, since 1985, were obtained from the Portuguese Ministry of Labour and Social Solidarity. Finally, the consumer price index was obtained from the OECD's Main Economic Indicators. 4 Government Performance is accounted for by the following two interaction variables: Government's Party Inflation Rate; and, Government's Party Government Popularity. The dummy variable Government's Party takes the value of one when the mayor's party is the same as that of the Prime Minister, and equals zero otherwise. By interacting this variable with the Inflation Rate or Government Popularity, we account for the possibility that the votes for an incumbent mayor whose political party is in charge of the national government are affected by the performance/popularity of the latter. 5 Since the first terms were only 3-years long, when working with the full sample it is not possible to include the level of expenditures 3 years before elections. In the estimations, lags that turned out as not statistically significant were sequentially excluded.

L.G. Veiga, F.J. Veiga / Economics Letters 96 (2007) 177 182 179 Table 1 Investment expenditures Votes 1979 2001 1979 1989 1990 2001 1986 2001 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Votes (previous election) 0.447 (10.9) 0.459 (11.2) 0.445 (6.71) 0.486 (5.27) 0.233 (3.41) 0.220 (3.18) 0.149 (2.69) Years Mayor 0.836 ( 10.7) 0.850 ( 10.9) 1.664 ( 9.22) 1.672 ( 6.54) Government's Party* 0.172 0.173 0.279 0.206 Inflation Rate ( 3.75) ( 3.81) ( 5.23) ( 2.70) Government's Party*Government Popularity Investment expenditures Election year 0.008 (2.01) Term mean 0.017 (3.88) %Deviation of election year 018 0.014 (1.73) 0.772 ( 6.77) 0.068 (3.31) 0.013 (3.21) 0.782 ( 6.85) 0.070 (3.37) 0.837 ( 8.80) 0.034 (1.95) 0.012 (3.27) 0.005 (.34) 0.020 (3.21) 0.017 0.0029 from the term mean (1.71) (.63) (2.12) Employment 0.0124 (1.12) Real wages 0.0026 (3.29) # Observations 1128 1136 597 486 650 650 839 # Municipalities 275 275 261 259 274 274 275 # Elections 6 6 4 3 3 3 4 Adjusted R 2 0.037 0.037 0.036 0.033 0.040 0.041 0.036 Notes: Panel regressions, for election years, controlling for municipality fixed effects. Votes, the dependent variable, was defined as the percentage of votes obtained by the incumbent. Models estimated with a constant. T-statistics based on heteroskedastic consistent standard errors are in parenthesis. Significance level at which the null hypothesis is rejected:, 1%;, 5%, and, 10%. mean, IEdev is the percentage deviation of the election year level from the term mean,ν i is the individual effect of municipality i, ε it is the error term, and, α, ϕ, γ, β 1, β 2 and β 3 are parameters to be estimated. The estimation results of the panel data models described above, controlling for municipality fixed effects, are shown in Table 1. Results for the full sample are consistent with the hypothesis that preelectoral manipulation of investment expenditures leads to a higher percentage of votes cast for the incumbent mayor. Expenditures in the election year are statistically significant, with a positive sign (column 1), 6 and the same applies to the term mean and to the percentage deviation of the level of the election year relative to the term mean (column 2). 7 There is also evidence of systematic popularity erosion over time (sometimes referred to as a cost of ruling ), and support for the hypothesis that mayors belonging to the prime minister's party lose votes when inflation is high. 6 Levels for Investment Expenditures in previous years are not statistically significant when included. 7 In the longer working paper version of this article (Veiga and Veiga, 2006), we also report estimation results for models including budget balances, taxes, total expenditures, and current and capital expenditures. Evidence that opportunism pays off was found for total and for capital expenditures. Since it was for investment expenditures that Veiga and Veiga (2007) found greater evidence of political business cycles, only the results obtained for those are reported in the present paper.

180 L.G. Veiga, F.J. Veiga / Economics Letters 96 (2007) 177 182 There may be an endogeneity problem in this regression. It is possible that the popularity of the mayor affects the size of the opportunistic cycle: when certain of winning by a large margin, she does not need to engage in the manipulation of expenditures; 8 but, when confronted with a close race, she has the greatest incentive to behave opportunistically. However, even when a mayor does not expect a close race, she may still want to increase expenditures shortly before elections, in order to elect as many deputies as possible in the Town Hall and in the Municipal Assembly. Thus, the endogeneity bias may be small. 9 In order to determine if expenditure manipulation affected votes in the same manner throughout time, we split the sample into two parts. Results shown in columns 3 and 4 imply that opportunistic spending was not highly vote-productive in the period 1979 1989, as investment expenditures are only marginally statistically significant in column 3 and no effects of opportunism on votes are found in column 4. But, results for the period 1990 2001 are stronger than for the full sample. Thus, electoral manipulation of the timing of spending had higher pay off as the Portuguese democracy became more established after its restoration in 1974. In these estimations, there is also evidence that government's popularity ratings affect the votes obtained by mayors of the government party. 10 The increasing importance of fiscal performance on voters' decisions over time is in line with Brender's (2003) findings for Israel. It may result from a shift in voters' concerns away from ideological issues to economic ones, as democracy matured, leading to a greater sensitivity of voters to the budget cycle. But, contrary to Brender, who found evidence that the Israeli electorate started penalizing incumbents for loose fiscal policy as democracy matured, our results suggest that the political pay off to opportunistic spending increased after democracy became well-established in Portugal. A possible explanation for this result is that, as the Portuguese democracy matured, politicians learned how to take advantage of electoral institutions and, unlike in Israel, no significant measures were implemented to increase the transparency of local governments' accounts. In this respect, it is worth mentioning that Alt and Lassen (2006), working on a sample of advanced industrialized economies, identified a persistent pattern of electoral cycles on low(er) transparency countries, while no such pattern could be observed in high(er) transparency countries. The next step of the empirical analysis was to include variables accounting for the economic performance of municipalities. In column 7, municipal Employment and average real Wages were included along with Investment Expenditures. Results for the latter are very similar to those of column 5. While Employment does not seem to affect votes, higher Wages in the election year lead to greater percentages of votes for the incumbent. 11 In the estimations of Table 2, investment expenditures are broken up into their seven components. In column 1, only Other Buildings and Miscellaneous Constructions are statistically significant. These results were expected, as these are the most important and most visible components of Investment 8 Although the incentive for opportunistic behavior may also be small for those who are certain of losing, they generally decide not to run for re-election and, consequently, most of them are not included in our sample. 9 Since only the mayors who run for re-election are considered, most of the cases in our sample in which there is not a close race correspond to situations in which the mayor is sure of winning. Consequently, our estimates are likely to underestimate the causal relationship between opportunistic cycles and popularity. 10 The variable (Government's Party Government Popularity) was not included in the previous estimations because popularity data are only available after 1986. 11 Since data for unemployment and wages are only available after 1985 and that for government popularity after 1986, only the elections that occurred between 1986 and 2001 are covered in this estimation.

L.G. Veiga, F.J. Veiga / Economics Letters 96 (2007) 177 182 181 Table 2 Components of investment expenditures Votes 1 2 Votes (previous election) 0.0335 (6.42) 0.0298 (5.67) Years Mayor 0.0887 ( 9.72) 0.0889 ( 9.71) Government's Party*Inflation Rate 0.0146 ( 2.05) 0.0185 ( 2.64) Main components Acquisition of land: election year 0.0025 (0.074) Housing: election year 0.0017 (1.07) Other buildings: year before election 0.0039 (2.95) Miscellaneous constructions: election year 0.0011 (2.46) Transportation material: election year 0.0098 (1.39) Machinery and equipment: election year 0.0036 (.75) Other investments: election year 0.0021 (0.053) Components of other buildings Sports, recreational and schooling facilities: election year 0.0003 (0.22) Social equipment: election year 0.0105 (1.97) Other: year before election 0.0056 (3.12) Components of miscellaneous constructions Overpasses, streets and complementary works: year before election 0.0030 (2.12) Sewage: election year 0.0023 ( 1.05) Water treatment and distribution: election year 0.0030 ( 1.84) Rural roads: election year 0.0019 (2.44) Infrastructures for solid waste treatment: election year 0.0047 (1.11) Other miscellaneous constructions: election year 0.0002 (0.33) # Observations 934 930 # Municipalities 275 275 # Elections 5 5 Adjusted R 2 0.032 0.033 Notes: Panel regressions, for election years, controlling for municipality fixed effects. Votes, the dependent variable, was defined as the percentage of votes obtained by the incumbent. Models estimated with a constant. T-statistics based on heteroskedastic consistent standard errors are in parenthesis. Significance level at which the null hypothesis is rejected:, 1%;, 5%, and, 10%. Expenditures. Since we have very detailed data on the municipal accounts, we are able to disaggregate Investment Expenditures even further, in order to analyze the three components of Other Buildings and the 6 components of Miscellaneous Constructions. Results shown in column 2 indicate that votes can be gained by increasing expenditures in the election year (or in the year before, in some cases) in Social Equipment, Other, Overpasses, Streets and Complementary Works, and in Rural Roads. 3. Conclusions Results indicate that higher investment expenditures in election years are associated with higher vote percentages for incumbent mayors in Portuguese municipalities. This finding is in line with the evidence presented by Akhmedov and Zhuravkaya (2004) for Russian regions. We also find that opportunistic spending was more vote-productive after Portugal became an established democracy than it had been when democracy was newly established. This may be a result of a lack of transparency regarding local fiscal policies combined with the acquisition of knowledge by politicians, and with a greater sensitivity of Portuguese voters to the budget cycle, as democracy matured.

182 L.G. Veiga, F.J. Veiga / Economics Letters 96 (2007) 177 182 Electoral manipulation can also be accomplished by altering the composition of expenditures, as suggested by Drazen and Eslava (2005). Our results show that opportunistic mayors should spend relatively more on: Social Equipment; Other; Overpasses, Streets and Complementary works; and, Rural roads. With the exception of Social Equipment, it was exactly for these components of investment expenditures that Veiga and Veiga (2007) found greater evidence of political budgetary cycles. Acknowledgements The authors wish to thank Henry Chappell and one anonymous referee for their very helpful comments and the financial support provided under research grant POCI/EGE/58641/2004, approved by the Portuguese Foundation for Science and Technology and the European Regional Development Fund, through the Operational Programme Science and Innovation 2010. References Akhmedov, Akhmed, Zhuravkaya, Ekaterina, 2004. Opportunistic political cycles: test in a young democracy setting. Quarterly Journal of Economics 119, 1301 1338. Alt, James, Lassen, David, 2006. Transparency, political polarization, and political budget cycles in OECD countries. American Journal of Political Science 50 (3), 530 550. Brender, Adi, 2003. The effect of fiscal performance on local government election results in Israel: 1989 1998. Journal of Public Economics 87, 2187 2205. Drazen, Allan, Eslava, Marcela, 2005. Electoral Manipulation via Expenditure Composition: Theory and Evidence. NBER Working Paper W11085. Paldam, Martin, 2004. Are vote and popularity functions economically correct. In: Rowley, C.K., Schneider, F. (Eds.), The Encyclopedia of Public Choice. Kluwer Academic Publishers, Dordrecht, The Netherlands, pp. 49 59. Veiga, Linda, Veiga, Francisco, 2007. Political business cycles at the municipal level. Public Choice 131 (1 2), 45 64. Veiga, Linda, Veiga, Francisco, 2006. Does opportunism pay off? NIPE Working Paper, WP-5/2006. Available at: http://ssrn.com/ abstract=911200.