Economic Growth and Poverty Alleviation in Russia: Should We Take Inequality into Consideration?

Similar documents
Growth and Poverty Reduction: An Empirical Analysis Nanak Kakwani

Interrelationship between Growth, Inequality, and Poverty: The Asian Experience

Economic Growth, Income Inequality, and Poverty Reduction in People s Republic of China BO Q. LIN

ERD. Working Paper. No. Interrelationship between Growth, Inequality, and Poverty: The Asian Experience. Hyun H. Son ECONOMICS AND RESEARCH DEPARTMENT

Poverty, Income Inequality, and Growth in Pakistan: A Pooled Regression Analysis

Asian Development Bank Institute. ADBI Working Paper Series. Income Distributions, Inequality, and Poverty in Asia,

A poverty-inequality trade off?

Income Distributions, Inequality, and Poverty in Asia,

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

The Social Policy and Development Centre (SPDC)

Spatial Inequality in Cameroon during the Period

Economic growth, inequality, and poverty in Vietnam

China s (Uneven) Progress Against Poverty. Martin Ravallion and Shaohua Chen Development Research Group, World Bank

HOW ECONOMIES GROW AND DEVELOP Macroeconomics In Context (Goodwin, et al.)

Assessment of the Impact of Pro-Poor Growth on Poverty in Developing Countries

World Bank Releases World Development Indicators Seeking Alpha

Outline: Poverty, Inequality, and Development

Poverty and Inequality

Poverty, growth and inequality

Pro-Poor Growth and the Poorest

and with support from BRIEFING NOTE 1

How Have the World s Poorest Fared since the Early 1980s?

CIE Economics A-level

New Evidence on the Urbanization of Global Poverty

Growth and inequality effects on poverty reduction in Italy

PERSISTENT POVERTY AND EXCESS INEQUALITY: LATIN AMERICA,

Economic Growth and Poverty Reduction: Lessons from the Malaysian Experience

Poverty and Inequality

ESTIMATING INCOME INEQUALITY IN PAKISTAN: HIES TO AHMED RAZA CHEEMA AND MAQBOOL H. SIAL 26

Trends in inequality worldwide (Gini coefficients)

Volume 36, Issue 1. Impact of remittances on poverty: an analysis of data from a set of developing countries

The Ghana Poverty and Inequality Report: Using the 6th Ghana Living Standards Survey 2016

vi. rising InequalIty with high growth and falling Poverty

Branko Milanovic* and John E. Roemer Interaction of Global and National Income Inequalities

Analysis of Urban Poverty in China ( )

There is a seemingly widespread view that inequality should not be a concern

Poverty and Inequality

Inequality is Bad for the Poor. Martin Ravallion * Development Research Group, World Bank 1818 H Street NW, Washington DC

A Structural Analysis of Growth and Poverty in the Short-Term

The Trends of Income Inequality and Poverty and a Profile of

Application of PPP exchange rates for the measurement and analysis of regional and global inequality and poverty

Household Income inequality in Ghana: a decomposition analysis

Growth, Inequality, and Poverty: An Introduction Nanak Kakwani, Brahm Prakash, and Hyun Son

Human Capital and Income Inequality: New Facts and Some Explanations

Welfare, inequality and poverty

CHAPTER 2 LITERATURE REVIEWS

The Role of Labor Market in Explaining Growth and Inequality: The Philippines Case. Hyun H. Son

Remittances and Poverty. in Guatemala* Richard H. Adams, Jr. Development Research Group (DECRG) MSN MC World Bank.

Does Inequality Matter for Poverty Reduction? Evidence from Pakistan s Poverty Trends

Is Global Inequality Really Falling?

THE EFFECTS OF INTEGRATION AND THE GLOBAL ECONOMIC CRISIS ON THE COUNTRIES IN SOUTH- EASTERN EUROPE

Cornell University ILR School. Chen Zongsheng Nankai University. Wu Ting Party School of Communist Party of China

(Work in progress September 2008 no citations, please) Caste dominance and inclusive growth: Evidence from a panel data set for India

Poverty in the Third World

A comparative analysis of poverty and social inclusion indicators at European level

Operationalising Pro- Poor Growth. A Country Case Study on Brazil

Understanding the dynamics of labor income inequality in Latin America (WB PRWP 7795)

HOUSEHOLD LEVEL WELFARE IMPACTS

THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN DEMOGRAPHIC CHANGE AND INCOME INEQUALITY IN AGING SOCIETY OF THAILAND

China Nunziante Mastrolia

INCLUSIVE GROWTH AND POLICIES: THE ASIAN EXPERIENCE. Thangavel Palanivel Chief Economist for Asia-Pacific UNDP, New York

Ghana Lower-middle income Sub-Saharan Africa (developing only) Source: World Development Indicators (WDI) database.

Poverty and Inequality Changes in Turkey ( )

POVERTY AND INEQUALITY IN SOUTH AFRICA AND THE WORLD

A Comparative Perspective on Poverty Reduction in Brazil, China, and India

FOREIGN TRADE DEPENDENCE AND INTERDEPENDENCE: AN INFLUENCE ON THE RESILIENCE OF THE NATIONAL ECONOMY

Asian Development Review

Being a Good Samaritan or just a politician? Empirical evidence of disaster assistance. Jeroen Klomp

Informal Summary Economic and Social Council High-Level Segment

Estimating Economic Growth and Inequality Elasticities of Poverty in Rural Nigeria

Edexcel (A) Economics A-level

More Relatively-Poor People in a Less Absolutely-Poor World

REVIEW POVERTY, INCOME INEQUALITY, AND HEALTH CARE CONSUMPTION IN THAILAND

Labour market of the new Central and Eastern European member states of the EU in the first decade of membership 125

Augustin Kwasi Fosu 1. December 2010

Lecture 2: Poverty, Inequality and Growth: Debates, Concepts and Evidence

Poverty, Inequality and Growth: Debates, Theories and Evidence

Edexcel (B) Economics A-level

Chapter 2: The U.S. Economy: A Global View

The widening income dispersion in Hong Kong :

KADARMANTO & DENZO KAMIYA

What do we know about pro-poor growth and regional poverty in Nigeria? Abstract

Poverty of Ethnic Minorities in the Poorest Areas of Vietnam

Comparative Study of Poverty Reduction Strategies Between Nigeria and China. Thesis proposal by Rosemary I. Eneji

Inclusive Growth and Poverty Eradication Policies in China

AQA Economics A-level

Poverty and Social Change in Colombia Diagnostic and Main Challenges

Reducing income inequality by economics growth in Georgia

Inclusion and Gender Equality in China

Population as Public Interest

Southern Africa Labour and Development Research Unit

Part 1: Focus on Income. Inequality. EMBARGOED until 5/28/14. indicator definitions and Rankings

Economic Groups by the Inequality in the World GDP Distribution

Levels and Trends in Multidimensional Poverty in some Southern and Eastern African countries, using counting based approaches

CHAPTER 12: The Problem of Global Inequality

Has Growth Been Socially Inclusive during ?

IV. Labour Market Institutions and Wage Inequality

INCOME INEQUALITY WITHIN AND BETWEEN COUNTRIES

Globalization and Poverty Forthcoming, University of

Inequality and Poverty in Rural China

Transcription:

WELLSO 2015 - II International Scientific Symposium on Lifelong Wellbeing in the World Economic Growth and Poverty Alleviation in Russia: Should We Take Inequality into Consideration? Dmitry Rudenko a * * Corresponding author: Dmitry Rudenko, drudenko@inbox.ru a Tyumen State University, 10, Semakova street, Tyumen, 625003, Russia, Email: drudenko@inbox.ru http://dx.doi.org/10.15405/epsbs.2016.02.15 Abstract The paper describes main ideas surrounding the topic of inclusive and pro-poor growth. This study investigates the impact of economic growth on inequality and poverty in Russia over the period 2002-2012. High rates of economic growth had brought about rapid reduction of the poor people while income inequality had risen. The work examines whether Russian economic growth is pro-poor over that period. Poverty in Russia is a problem of excessively high inequality now and its scope can t be radically reduced in the short term without a rapid reduction of inequality. The current situation is paradoxical the economic growth only reinforces inequality, is not conducive to the alleviation of poverty, and may be characterized by low quality. We conclude that it is essential to formulate pro-poor policies along with growth-enhancing policies in order to alleviate both absolute and relative poverty in Russia. Growth is good for the poor, and growth that is accompanied by progressive distributional change is even better. 2016 Published by Future Academy www.futureacademy.org.uk Keywords: Inequality, poverty, pro-poor growth, economic growth, Russia. 1. Introduction According to the Concept of Russia s long-term development till 2020, the goal of achieving sustainable economic growth remains a key focus of policymakers. However, high rates of economic growth over the last decade were accompanied by strengthening of inequality. In these circumstances, the problem of poverty has acquired a new character chronic and local. After the 2008 financial crisis economic growth does not have a positive impact on official poverty headcount in Russia, canning poverty within 11%. Moreover, the relative poverty headcount is much higher and remains stable at the level of 30%. It is obvious that a high level of economic development facilitates the struggle against poverty, providing resources for this purpose. However, it is also possible that economic growth increases This is an Open Access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution-Noncommercial 4.0 Unported License, permitting all non-commercial use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.

eissn: 2357-1330 Selection & Peer-review under responsibility of the Conference Organization Committee poverty. This can happen when inequality increases so much that the beneficial effects of growth is completely eliminated. Bhagwati calls this as an immeserizing growth, the growth that provokes poverty (Kakwani, & Pernia, 2000). Opponents of growth consider that there is virtually no reason to believe that economic growth helps to solve social problems. In many countries, mainly developed, the problem of poverty is a problem of distribution, rather than production. Moreover, high rates of growth can be related to environmental pollution and high stress, which would be prejudicial to physical and mental health. So, it is necessary to determine the extent to which economic growth improves the status of the poor. Do the poor benefit to the same extent as the rest of the population? Following Dollar & Kraay (2002): Economic growth is good for the poor, since average incomes of the poorest quintile rise proportionally with average incomes of the rest. Changes in the income distribution (on average) are slight and moving too slowly to lead to substantial changes in the level of poverty. The evidence emphasizes the importance of economic growth for poverty reduction. However, the beneficial effect of economic growth on the poor considerably varies not only between countries but also within. In some cases, the increase in per capita income by 1% can lead to a decrease in poverty headcount by 3-4%, while in other cases, by only a tenth of a percent or even an increase. Such a phenomenon can be observed in the Russian economy in 2005, 2008 and 2011, when economic growth exacerbated the problem of poverty (see Fig. 1). 20 15 10 5 0-5 -10-1,5 8,7 5,1 0,397-2,9 0,422 15 0,421 0,421 0,42 12,4 13,5 0,421 10,4 0,415 12,1 0,417 11,1 8,2 7,3 7,2 0,409 0,409 8,5 6,4 5,2 5,1 4,3 4,4 4,7 0,403 0,1 0,1 2,4 3,1 4,5 0,5 3,4 0,397 0,2-4,3-2,7-2,5-1,9-0,4-0,5 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 The change of poverty headcount, percentage points The growth rate of real GDP, % -7,8-1,7 0,43 0,42 0,41 0,4 0,39 0,38 Fig. 1. The major indicators of socio-economic development in Russia, 2002-2012 Saving income inequality at a present high level under accelerated economic growth shows the uneven distribution of gains from economic growth, which could potentially lead to a weakening of the influence of economic growth on poverty reduction. This study investigates the impact of economic growth on inequality and poverty in Russia over the period 2002-2012. We examine whether Russian economic growth is pro-poor over that period. 2. Pro-Poor Growth: A Short Review The concept of pro-poor growth has become very popular during the last decade. It reflects the idea that economic growth should affect all the segments of society and this is why the term inclusive growth is also often used. Pro-poor growth is defined as a growth, which leads to a significant 110

http://dx.doi.org/10.15405/epsbs.2016.02.15 eissn: 2357-1330 / Corresponding Author: Dmitry Rudenko, Email: drudenko@inbox.ru Selection and peer-review under responsibility of the Organizing Committee of the conference reduction in poverty. However, this does not give a formal definition of clear quantitative criteria for a significant reduction of poverty. It is recognized that the pro-poor growth should enable the poor to participate actively in economic activities and to receive some benefits from this participation. The author stands by the concept of relative pro-poor growth, which implies an increase in the proportion of the poor in the total distribution of the national income. Although there have been only a few studies on pro-poor growth in Russia, some studies have highlighted that Russian economic growth has not been pro-poor over the last decade. Following Takeda (2010), who had examined the effect of economic growth on poverty reduction in Russia based on the elasticity of poverty to real per capita GRP, using Russian regional data for 1995-2006, growth benefited the richer regions (or people) more. As a result, from the regional point of view, she concluded that the growth after the 1998 financial crisis had not been pro-poor in Russia. Shvareva & Kononova (2007) have found that the inflation burden was higher for the poor, so the inflation in Russia stood one of the factors that increased social inequality. They also have argued that economic growth could be characterized as pro-rich growth because major gains from economic growth were distributed in favor of the wealthy. 3. Data and Methodology In this study, we use official data by the Federal State Statistics Service of Russia for 2002-2012 on the average per capita money income and subsistence minimum, as well as data on the distribution of population by disposable income. We proceed from the premise that poverty is fully determined by three parameters the level of per capita income (the mean income of the distribution), the poverty line and the Lorenz curve representing the structure of relative income inequalities. The poverty index, as measured by the class of FGT indices, can be written as P P( L, µ z) = (1) where P the poverty index, L a vector of parameters fully describing the Lorenz curve, µ the mean (average) income, z the poverty line. The framework of analysis has its origins in the decomposition of changes in poverty into growth and redistribution components proposed by Ravallion & Datt (1991). The level of poverty may change due to a change in the mean income µ relative to the poverty line, or due to a change in relative inequalities dp P d η ( µ z) dg Gr R + ε = + ( µ z) G P P = (2) where η the pure growth elasticity of poverty, ε the inequality elasticity of poverty, Gr the growth component of a change in the poverty measure; R the redistribution component of a change in the poverty measure. The growth component of a change in the poverty measure is defined as the change in poverty due to a change in the mean while the distribution of income does not change. The redistribution component is the change in poverty when the Lorenz curve changes in the absence of growth. 111

eissn: 2357-1330 Selection & Peer-review under responsibility of the Conference Organization Committee The pure growth elasticity of poverty η which is the percentage change in poverty in response to a growth rate 1 percent provided inequality of income measured by Lorenz curve does not change can be defined as η Gr ( µ z) ( µ z) P = (3) As an increase in average income reduces poverty, net growth elasticity is always negative. The inequality elasticity of poverty ε which is the percentage change in poverty in response to a percent change in the Gini index provided average income does not change can be defined as ε R G G P = (4) The inequality elasticity of poverty decreases monotonically with the initial level of inequality. On the one hand, efforts of a society with a high level of initial inequality to reduce poverty may be futile. On the other hand, a further increase in inequality in such a society weakly affects the poor. In general, the lower initial level of inequality will be more productive fight against poverty. On dividing the equation (2) by the growth rate of real mean income d ( z) ( µ z) poverty elasticity where µ gives the total δ = η ε λ (5) + δ the total poverty elasticity, λ the growth elasticity of inequality, which measures the percentage change in the Gini index when there is a growth rate of 1 percent. When λ is positive (negative), the growth process is accompanied by an increase (decrease) in inequality. The total poverty elasticity measures the impact of growth on poverty when inequality can also change with growth. It measures the percentage change in poverty when there is a growth rate of 1 percent. Following Kakwani & Pernia (2000), the degree of pro-poor (pro-rich) growth can be measured by an index of pro-poor growth where φ the index of pro-poor growth. φ = δ η (7) If φ > 1, the growth process is considered to be pro-poor. If φ = 1 and φ = 0, the growth process is accompanied by a zero change in inequality and poverty, respectively. When 1 < φ < 0, economic growth reduces poverty, but the inequality effect of economic growth is negative so that the poor benefit proportionately less from economic growth than the non-poor. This can be characterised as trickle-down growth. If φ < 0, economic growth actually. In case of an economic recession, the propoor index is inverted to be remains unchanged. η δ. A growth episode is called pro-poor only if inequality declines or Following Aivazian (1997), the distribution of Russian households by per capita income may in fact be adequately described with a mixture of log-normal laws. A similar point is made by Lopez and Serven (2006), who using a large cross country dataset spanning close to 800 country-year 112

http://dx.doi.org/10.15405/epsbs.2016.02.15 eissn: 2357-1330 / Corresponding Author: Dmitry Rudenko, Email: drudenko@inbox.ru Selection and peer-review under responsibility of the Organizing Committee of the conference observations from industrial and developing countries on income/expenditure inequality formally test the null hypothesis of lognormality for the size distribution of income/expenditure. Their results suggest a rejection of the null hypothesis for per capita expenditure, but they are unable to reject the null for per capita income (Lopez, & Serven, 2006). The advantage of this approach is that, with the data on the distribution of income by quintile shares, the poverty line and the average income, we can easily estimate any desired poverty measures (absolute or relative): poverty headcount, poverty gap and squared poverty gap. The last two are not officially presented by the Russian Federal State Statistics Service. First, we have estimated values of the Gini index and headcount indexes of poverty according to the log-normal model presented by Kolenikov & Shorrocks (2003). H = F 2 LN ( υ, σ ) ln z υ ln( z µ ) σ ( z) = Φ = Φ + σ σ 2 ( 2) 1 (7) G = 2Φ σ (8) where Н the poverty headcount ratio (the proportion of population with money income below subsistence minimum level), z the poverty line (subsistence minimum level), µ per capita money income, υ the average of logµ and σ the standard deviation of logµ, G Gini index. Table 1 gives our estimated poverty measures. Table 1. Official and estimated poverty measures in Russia Year Poverty headcount index, % Gini index Rosstat Model Rosstat Model 2002 24.6 24.47 0.397 0.398 2003 20.3 20.63 0.403 0.404 2004 17.6 17.83 0.409 0.410 2005 17.7 17.95 0.409 0.410 2006 15.2 15.52 0.416 0.418 2007 13.3 13.47 0.422 0.423 2008 13.4 13.67 0.421 0.423 2009 13 13.06 0.421 0.421 2010 12.5 12.62 0.421 0.421 2011 12.7 12.97 0.417 0.418 2012 11 11.21 0.420 0.420 The measures show a pronounced trend decrease in poverty over the period. Poverty indexes fell, though not all continuously. However, increases are small and probably not significant statistically at a reasonable level. The poverty headcount index is estimated to have started at 24.47% in 2002, falling by 13.3 points to 11.21% in 2012. By year-to-year periods, this was made up of a fall in the index of 3.84 points over 2002 to 2003, 2.8 points between 2003 and 2004, and it rose by 0.19 points between 2008 and 2009, 0.34 points between 2010 and 2011. 4. Data and Methodology We apply the two-way Shapley decomposition to changes in poverty since 2002. We assess the factor contribution to poverty changes presented in table 2. Table 2. SOS decomposition of year-on-year change in poverty headcount index 113

eissn: 2357-1330 Selection & Peer-review under responsibility of the Conference Organization Committee Period Absolute factor contribution, percentage points Relative factor contribution, % Growth component Redistribution component Growth component Redistribution component 2002-2012 -15.490 2.23-63.305 9.113 2002-2003 -4.614 0.772-18.857 3.156 2003-2004 -3.510 0.708-17.017 3.433 2004-2005 0.127 0 0.710 0 2005-2006 -3.344 0.910-18.629 5.07 2006-2007 -2.610 0.563-16.821 3.627 2007-2008 0.200 0 1.481 0 2008-2009 -0.358-0.249-2.615-1.822 2009-2010 -0.440 0-3.366 0 2010-2011 0.571-0.225 4.520-1.786 2011-2012 -1.913 0.153-14.751 1.178 Table 2 gives the decomposition estimates for each year. Over the full period we find that both the growth and redistribution components were strong, with exactly opposite effects. Changes in distribution tended to increase poverty, but there was sufficient growth in the average per capita income to counteract their effect. The bulk of the adverse distributional effect was before the financial crisis of 2008. After determining the factor contribution to poverty changes, we have calculated propoor growth indexes (Table 3). Table 3. The pro-poor growth indexes estimation Period The total relative change in The total poverty The pure growth The inequality The index of poverty measures, % elasticity elasticity of poverty elasticity of poverty pro-poor growth 2002-2012 -54.19-0.889-1.038 1.629 0.856 2002-2003 -15.70-1.294-1.554 1.985 0.833 2003-2004 -13.58-1.331-1.667 2.346 0.798 2004-2005 0.71 2005-2006 -13.56-1.250-1.717 2.635 0.728 2006-2007 -13.19-1.403-1.789 2.972 0.784 2007-2008 1.48 2008-2009 -4.44-3.383-1.994 3.325 1.697 2009-2010 -3.37-2.032-2.032 0 1.000 2010-2011 2.73 2011-2012 -13.57-1.758-1.910 3.342 0.920 The results in table 3 show that economic growth over 2002-2012 had a different character to overcome poverty. The largest (in absolute) value of the pure growth elasticity of poverty can be observed in 2009-2010, while the lowest in 2002-2003. Over 2004-2005, 2007-2008 and 2010-2011 the poverty line had grown faster than per capita income, leading to a drop in the purchasing power of income and to an increase in poverty measures. According to the index for the full period the poor did not participate fully in the growth that occurred. Growth in Russia has not been strictly pro-poor, although it has resulted in considerable poverty reduction. Poverty reduction would have been even faster if the government had avoided policies with adverse consequences on income distribution. For instance if the Lorenz curve had been at the 2002 level the poverty headcount would have been 9% of the total population. In the aftermath of the financial crisis 2008, the high positive growth rates achieved by the Russian economy had slowed down. The annual growth rate of real disposable money income fell from 12.4% in 2002-2007 to 3% in 2008-2012. The decline in annual growth of real GDP was even more dramatic from 7% in 2002-2007 to 1,8% in 2008-2012. The results in Table 1 show that the crisis had also reduced the inequality the Gini index fell from 0.422 in 2007 to 0.417 in 2011. The economic growth over that period may be characterized as strictly pro-poor which resulted in a fluctuation of pro-poor growth index from 1 to 1.697 over 2007-2011. Thus, the economic crisis adversely affected the 114

http://dx.doi.org/10.15405/epsbs.2016.02.15 eissn: 2357-1330 / Corresponding Author: Dmitry Rudenko, Email: drudenko@inbox.ru Selection and peer-review under responsibility of the Organizing Committee of the conference nonpoor proportionally more than the poor. However the trend of increasing inequality in the Russian economy has been resumed in 2012. Sustained high economic growth in almost all regions has significantly reduced absolute income poverty, but in many of the high-growth regions, the growth has been associated with a rising inequality (Rudenko, Pogodaeva, & Didenko, 2015). The development strategy, based on the growing inequality in the distribution of income between the rich and the poor, actually does not lead to an increase in economic potential. By the number of billionaires Russia is one of the leaders in the global economy. Thus, according to the annual Forbes ranking 2013, Russia was ranked third after the United States and China, but according to the GDP per capita (PPP) Russia was ranked only 77 (Rudenko, 2014). 5. Conclusion We must say that the problem of absolute monetary poverty in Russia is almost solved. But if we look at the relative poverty the problem remains constant or even worsens the proportion of people with money incomes below the half of average income is estimated to have started at 28.3% in 2002, rising to 31% in 2012. The state social policy of redistribution has no significant effect on the risk of poverty and the benefit system that is aimed at poverty reduction does not actually perform this function. Poverty in Russia is a problem of excessively high inequality now and its scope can t be reduced in the short term without a radical reduction of inequality. The current situation is paradoxical the economic growth only reinforces inequality, it is not conducive to the alleviation of poverty, and may be characterized by low quality. Trying to meet the challenges of economic growth and the eradication of poverty at the same time will not be successful until we prioritize goals. We conclude that it is essential to formulate pro-poor policies along with growth-enhancing policies in order to alleviate both absolute and relative poverty in Russia and its regions. Acknowledgements The study was supported by the Ministry of education and science of Russia, project 14.Z56.14.3051-MK. References Rosstat (2014). Social and Economic Indicators for Russia 2013. Available at: http://www.gks.ru/dbscripts/cbsd/dbinet.cgi#1 (accessed April 10, 2015). Kakwani, N., & Pernia, E.M. (2000). What is pro-poor growth? Asian Development Review, 18 (1), 1-16. Dollar, D., & Kraay, A. (2002). Growth is good for the poor. Journal of Economic Growth, 7 (3), 195-225. Ravallion, М. & Chen, S. (2003). Measuring pro-poor growth. Economics Letters, 78 (1), 93-99. Kraay, A. (2006). When is growth pro-poor? Evidence from a panel of countries. Journal of Development Economics, 80 (1), 198-227. Takeda, Y. (2010). Is Russia s economic growth pro-poor? In A., Uegaki, & S., Tabata, (Eds.), The Elusive Balance: Regional Powers and the Search for Sustainable Development (pp. 129-142). Sapporo: Slavic Research Center, Hokkaido University. Shvareva, N. & Kononova, V. (2007). Impact of economic growth on poverty reduction: the Russian experience of 2001-2005. In Scientific papers of the Institute for Complex Strategic Studies, 2006. (pp. 8-33). Moscow: Institute for Complex Strategic Studies. Ravallion, M., & Datt, G. (1991). Growth and redistributive components of changes in poverty measures. A decomposition with applications to Brazil and India in 1980s. Living Standards Measurement Study Working Paper 83. Washington D.C.: The World Bank. Aivazyan, S.A. (1997). The model for the formation of population distribution in terms of per capita income in Russia. Economics and Mathematical Methods, (4), 74-86. 115

eissn: 2357-1330 Selection & Peer-review under responsibility of the Conference Organization Committee Lopez, J.H. & Serven, L. (2006). A normal relationship? Poverty, growth and inequality. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 3814, January 2006. Kolenikov, S.О., & Shorrocks, A.F. (2003). А decomposition analysis of regional poverty in Russia. WIDER Discussion Paper No. 2003/74. Rudenko, D.Y., Pogodaeva, T.V., & Didenko, N.I. (2015). Poverty Alleviation Strategies in the Russian Arctic Zone Regions. Mediterranean Journal of Social Sciences, 6(1), 32-39. Rudenko, D.Y. (2014). Alternative Approaches to Measure Poverty in Russian Regions. Mediterranean Journal of Social Sciences, 4(13), 262-267. 116