The welfare use of immigrants and natives in Germany

Similar documents
Table A.2 reports the complete set of estimates of equation (1). We distinguish between personal

English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap

Supplementary information for the article:

Differences in Unemployment Dynamics between Migrants and Natives in Germany

Between here and there. Immigrant fertility patterns in Germany.

Employment convergence of immigrants in the European Union

Naturalisation and on-the-job training participation. of first-generation immigrants in Germany

Cohort Effects in the Educational Attainment of Second Generation Immigrants in Germany: An Analysis of Census Data

Assimilation and Cohort Effects for German Immigrants

Explaining the Deteriorating Entry Earnings of Canada s Immigrant Cohorts:

NERO INTEGRATION OF REFUGEES (NORDIC COUNTRIES) Emily Farchy, ELS/IMD

Immigrant-native wage gaps in time series: Complementarities or composition effects?

Appendix to Sectoral Economies

Human capital transmission and the earnings of second-generation immigrants in Sweden

Naturalisation and on-the-job training: evidence from first-generation immigrants in Germany

The Savings Behavior of Temporary and Permanent Migrants in Germany

F E M M Faculty of Economics and Management Magdeburg

Gender pay gap in public services: an initial report

Home-ownership and Economic Performance of Immigrants in Germany

Happiness convergence in transition countries

Welfare Dependency among Danish Immigrants

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US

Canadian Labour Market and Skills Researcher Network

English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap in the UK

The Effect of Ethnic Residential Segregation on Wages of Migrant Workers in Australia

DETERMINANTS OF IMMIGRANTS EARNINGS IN THE ITALIAN LABOUR MARKET: THE ROLE OF HUMAN CAPITAL AND COUNTRY OF ORIGIN

The Savings Behavior of Temporary and Permanent Migrants in Germany

Immigrant Employment and Earnings Growth in Canada and the U.S.: Evidence from Longitudinal data

Transferability of Human Capital and Immigrant Assimilation: An Analysis for Germany

3-The effect of immigrants on the welfare state

The effect of migration in the destination country:

Data on gender pay gap by education level collected by UNECE

Economic assimilation of Mexican and Chinese immigrants in the United States: is there wage convergence?

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

The dynamics of welfare entry and exit among natives and immigrants

Discussion Paper. Draft Comments are welcome. Employment convergence of immigrants in the European Union SZILVIA HÁMORI*

The Employment of Low-Skilled Immigrant Men in the United States

Latin American Immigration in the United States: Is There Wage Assimilation Across the Wage Distribution?

Self-employed immigrants and their employees: Evidence from Swedish employer-employee data

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts

DETERMINANTS OF INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION: A SURVEY ON TRANSITION ECONOMIES AND TURKEY. Pınar Narin Emirhan 1. Preliminary Draft (ETSG 2008-Warsaw)

Immigrant Assimilation and Welfare Participation Do Immigrants Assimilate Into or Out of Welfare?

WHO MIGRATES? SELECTIVITY IN MIGRATION

The impact of parents years since migration on children s academic achievement

Do (naturalized) immigrants affect employment and wages of natives? Evidence from Germany

Brain Drain and Emigration: How Do They Affect Source Countries?

LABOUR-MARKET INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS IN OECD-COUNTRIES: WHAT EXPLANATIONS FIT THE DATA?

A Global Perspective on Socioeconomic Differences in Learning Outcomes

Special Eurobarometer 469. Report

Remittances and the Brain Drain: Evidence from Microdata for Sub-Saharan Africa

Migration Challenge or Opportunity? - Introduction. 15th Munich Economic Summit

Immigrants and the Receipt of Unemployment Insurance Benefits

The causal effect of age at migration on youth educational attainment

The Effect of Ethnic Residential Segregation on Wages of Migrant Workers in Australia

SocialSecurityEligibilityandtheLaborSuplyofOlderImigrants. George J. Borjas Harvard University

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOMEOWNERSHIP IN THE IMMIGRANT POPULATION. George J. Borjas. Working Paper

European Parliament Elections: Turnout trends,

Index. adjusted wage gap, 9, 176, 198, , , , , 241n19 Albania, 44, 54, 287, 288, 289 Atkinson index, 266, 277, 281, 281n1

Unemployment Dynamics among Migrants and Natives

European Union Expansion and the Euro: Croatia, Iceland and Turkey

Introduction: The State of Europe s Population, 2003

DANMARKS NATIONALBANK

Settling In 2018 Main Indicators of Immigrant Integration

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants

University of Bristol - Explore Bristol Research

The Savings Behavior of Temporary and Permanent Migrants in Germany

Second EU Immigrants and Minorities, Integration and Discrimination Survey: Main results

BRAND. Cross-national evidence on the relationship between education and attitudes towards immigrants: Past initiatives and.

7 ETHNIC PARITY IN INCOME SUPPORT

Immigrant Earnings Growth: Selection Bias or Real Progress?

Laura Jaitman and Stephen Machin Crime and immigration: new evidence from England and Wales

How are refugees faring on the labour market in Europe?

Employment Rate Gaps between Immigrants and Non-immigrants in. Canada in the Last Three Decades

WORKING PAPER. State dependence in Swedish social assistance in the 1990s: What happened to those who were single before the recession?

Labor Market Performance of Immigrants in Early Twentieth-Century America

Differences in remittances from US and Spanish migrants in Colombia. Abstract

Employment Outcomes of Immigrants Across EU Countries

CO3.6: Percentage of immigrant children and their educational outcomes

SPANISH NATIONAL YOUTH GUARANTEE IMPLEMENTATION PLAN ANNEX. CONTEXT

3.3 DETERMINANTS OF THE CULTURAL INTEGRATION OF IMMIGRANTS

The application of quotas in EU Member States as a measure for managing labour migration from third countries

Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries)

Majorities attitudes towards minorities in (former) Candidate Countries of the European Union:

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

Immigrant Assimilation and Welfare Participation: Do Immigrants Assimilate Into or Out-of Welfare

European International Virtual Congress of Researchers. EIVCR May 2015

Ethnic Persistence, Assimilation and Risk Proclivity

Immigrant Legalization

School Performance of the Children of Immigrants in Canada,

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach

Social Conditions in Sweden

Household Inequality and Remittances in Rural Thailand: A Lifecycle Perspective

Migration and Integration

The Pull Factors of Female Immigration

INTERNAL SECURITY. Publication: November 2011

65. Broad access to productive jobs is essential for achieving the objective of inclusive PROMOTING EMPLOYMENT AND MANAGING MIGRATION

Supplementary Materials for

3 Wage adjustment and employment in Europe: some results from the Wage Dynamics Network Survey

Employment and Unemployment in the EU. Structural Dynamics and Trends 1 Authors: Ph.D. Marioara Iordan 2

Ethnic Intergenerational Transmission of Human Capital in Sweden

Transcription:

The welfare use of immigrants and natives in Germany Christoph Wunder a,*, Monika Sander b, Regina T. Riphahn a April 25, 2010 Abstract This paper analyzes the welfare use of immigrants and natives in Germany. We describe the system of minimum income protection and explain the changes to the previous system introduced by the labor market reforms between 2003 and 2005 (the Hartz reform package). Using data from the German Socio-Economic Panel Study, the analysis graphically illustrates life cycle trajectories of transfer receipt for immigrants and natives, and studies the empirical linkage between contextual factors and transfer receipts. We find no evidence of statistically significant differences in the probability of transfer receipt between immigrants and natives, once the socioeconomic characteristics of the household are taken into account. In general, the labor market status and human capital variables are correlated with the incidence of transfer receipt. Moreover, households with children, and particularly single parent households, are more likely to receive transfers. Keywords: Immigration, Unemployment Benefit II, Transfers JEL Classification: I38, J61 a University of Erlangen-Nuremberg b University of Bamberg * Corresponding author: Christoph Wunder, University of Erlangen-Nuremberg, Department of Economics, Lange Gasse 20, 90403 Nuremberg, Germany. Tel.: +49 911 5302 260; Fax: +49 911 5302 178. E-mail: christoph.wunder@wiso.uni-erlangen.de Acknowledgments: We would like to thank Anna Kim for valuable comments. The paper benefited from discussions in seminars at the University of Erlangen-Nuremberg and the University of Bamberg, both in December 2009. We also thank the participants of a workshop at the IZA in Bonn in March 2010.

1. Introduction 2 1 Introduction During the second half of the twentieth century, Germany experienced large inflows of immigrants such that by 2007, there were more than 7.2 million residents without German citizenship accounting for about 8.9% of the total population (cf. Bundesamt für Migration und Flüchtlinge 2007). Taking account also of naturalized immigrants and repatriated ethnic Germans from Eastern Europe and their descendants, individuals with migration background make up almost 20% of the resident German population. Evidently, immigrants and their descendants play an important role in the determination of major social and economic policy in Germany. Previous empirical research on this field focused mostly on the labor market situation of immigrants (e.g., Seifert 1995, Kalter and Granato 2002, Kogan 2004). The issue of immigrants welfare dependence has been rather neglected in the literature in Germany (with the notable exceptions of Castronova et al. (2001), Riphahn (2004)). This is rather surprising, as it is well known that the share of immigrants in welfare programs exceeds their population share. Thus, given the yearly amount spent on welfare programs in Germany and the rising share of immigrants in the population, it is of utmost policy importance to understand the determinants of welfare dependence and to study the immigrant-native gap in welfare dependence. The present study provides an analysis of the use of welfare by immigrants and natives, respectively. The empirical focus is on the questions of whether differences in participation in welfare programs between immigrants and natives exist and to what extent such differences can be attributed to the immigrant status per se or to other contextual factors related to the immigrants status. We use data from the German Socio-Economic Panel Study (SOEP) to answer these questions in two steps. First, the empirical investigation applies semiparametric regression models using penalized splines to estimate life cycle trajectories of transfer receipts. By comparing trajectories of immigrants and natives, life cycle variations that may reflect assimilation of immigrants are presented. Second, we evaluate the contextual factors that are associated with the incidence of transfer receipt by applying linear probability models. We discuss the factors correlated with transfer receipt to learn more about households in need.

2. Legal framework and previous empirical findings 3 Our study is one of the first that investigates the situation of immigrants after the 2003-2005 labor market reforms (the Hartz reform package). A particular element of this reform package, the Hartz IV laws, was implemented in 2005 and implied a profound change in the system of minimum income protection. Basically, two pre-reform benefits, i.e., unemployment assistance and social assistance, were combined to a single post-reform benefit that is at the center of our analysis: unemployment benefit II. For comparison purposes, we also look at the receipt of unemployment assistance and social assistance to study the immigrants situation prior to the introduction of the new minimum income transfer system. The paper is organized as follows: the next section provides background information about the system of minimum income protection for unemployed individuals in Germany and summarizes previous empirical findings about the situation of immigrants. The data set and the estimation strategy are introduced in Sections 3 and 4, respectively. The results are presented and discussed in Section 5, and finally, conclusions are drawn in Section 6. 2 Legal framework and previous empirical findings Between 2003 and 2005, the German government implemented a broad package of labor market reforms, the so-called Hartz I-IV reforms, named after the chairman heading the Commission for Modern Labor Market Services, Peter Hartz. This comprehensive reform package aimed at improving labor market services and activating the unemployed. As a core element of the reform package, the Hartz IV reform, effective in 2005, implied profound changes in unemployment insurance and the system of minimum income protection. Next, we summarize the transfer payments granted to unemployed persons before and after this reform (cf. Figure 1). In Germany, unemployment insurance covers workers who become unemployed. Representing an insurance benefit, unemployment benefits (Arbeitslosengeld) depend on the contributory record and benefits are related to previous earnings (up to 67% of previous labor incomes). It is possible to claim unemployment benefits if one contributed to the insurance at least one year out of the last seven years. In addition, the maximum duration of benefit receipt is age

2. Legal framework and previous empirical findings 4 Figure 1 Unemployment compensation in Germany Before the reform (until 31.12.2004) Unemployment benefit (Arbeitslosengeld) After the reform (since 01.01.2005) Unemployment benefit I (Arbeitslosengeld I, SGB III) Unemployment assistance (Arbeitslosenhilfe) Unemployment benefit II (Arbeitslosengeld II, SGB II) Social assistance (Sozialhilfe, BSHG) Social assistance (Sozialhilfe, SGB XII) dependent. Before the reform, until the age of 45, unemployment benefits could be received for up to one year. Above the age of 45, the time period of possible benefit receipt was extended gradually, up to a maximum of 32 months for those over 57 years. After the reform, there was a cut in the maximum duration of eligibility. Unemployed persons receive the unemployment insurance benefit, which is more precisely now referred to as unemployment benefit I, for a period of 12 months. For persons above the age of 50, this period is extended to up to 24 months. Until the end of 2004, those who had exhausted their unemployment benefit entitlement were eligible for unemployment assistance (Arbeitslosenhilfe). Unemployment assistance was a tax-financed means-tested benefit with means-test regulations that varied by age. Unemployment assistance was also related to previous earnings, but less generous than unemployment benefits. The net replacement rate could only reach a maximum of 57%. Nevertheless, as unemployment assistance was generally paid without time limit at the latest until the recipient reached the statutory retirement age replacement rates for long term unemployed were higher in Germany than in any other OECD country (cf. Jacobi and Kluve 2007). If in cases of low previous labor incomes unemployment benefits or unemployment assistance fell below the legally defined subsistence level, individuals could additionally claim social assistance (Sozialhilfe) benefits as a top-up payment. Social assistance was introduced in 1962 as a general means-tested program. The aim of the general income support was to guarantee that every legal resident in Germany could lead a dignified life based on a socio-culturally

2. Legal framework and previous empirical findings 5 determined minimum income level. Although social assistance was never intended to support employable clients, about one in six of the unemployment assistance claimants also received a regular social assistance payment. Hence, it became rather difficult to distinguish between unemployment and social assistance clients (cf. Adema et al. 2003). In January 2005, the reform of the income support system for the long-term unemployed came into effect and unemployment assistance and social assistance were combined in the socalled unemployment benefit II. Since the reform, persons who exhausted their unemployment benefit I entitlements are eligible to unemployment benefit II. This is a means-tested flat-rate benefit financed by taxes, oriented at the legally defined social minimum of household incomes and, in contrast to the previous unemployment assistance, not related to prior earnings. For the majority of former unemployment assistance recipients, this meant a benefit cut. Individuals in need who had never contributed to unemployment insurance could claim unemployment benefit II without receiving unemployment benefit I first. With the introduction of the reform, access to benefits became conditional on the ability to work at least 15 hours per week. Those deemed not capable to work, e.g., due to sickness, disability, or care responsibilities, are entitled to social assistance instead of unemployment benefit II. The stipulations of the social assistance program were generally maintained unchanged compared to the pre-reform situation. Immigrants are treated in this system as follows. Because eligibility for unemployment benefit I, as before the reform, depends only on the contributory record with the unemployment insurance, unemployed immigrant workers who are covered by unemployment insurance are entitled to unemployment benefits. Eligibility for both, social assistance and unemployment benefit II, depends on residence in Germany and is independent of citizenship. However, there are different regulations for the different immigrant groups: asylum seekers receive benefits that are less generous than social assistance or unemployment benefit II. Ethnic Germans 1 (Aussiedler) as well as naturalized immigrants, i.e., those having German citizenship, are treated 1 The term ethnic Germans is used for Germans, who moved to the former Soviet Union before World War II. After World War II, they and their offspring often had to suffer forced resettlement and ethnic discrimination, and hence they were allowed to remigrate to Germany. They automatically receive German citizenship when entering Germany (e.g., Kurthen 1995, Dietz 1999).

2. Legal framework and previous empirical findings 6 as Germans. Foreigners without a permanent residence right who receive social assistance or unemployment benefit II can lose their right to stay or to get their residence permit prolonged. In 2005, the Immigration Act became effective. It reregulated residence status, and that was changed again in 2007 with the Act to Implement Residence- and Asylum-Related Directives of the European Union. Because of the simultaneous implementation of the reform of the income support system and the Immigration Act, there was and there still is some confusion with regard to the residence status of some immigrant groups and thus of their entitlement to unemployment benefit II. As in our sample mainly immigrants from former guest worker countries with a rather long duration of residence and ethnic Germans are included, it can be assumed that these problems will not influence our results. Moreover, the Immigration Act and the EU-Directives Implementation Act promote integration following the principle of supporting and challenging immigrants. Since 2007 immigrants can be obliged to participate in integration courses. If they fail to participate in the course they can be sanctioned by a cut of 30% of their unemployment benefit II transfers. Substantial literature has applied different indicators of economic integration in Germany. Economic integration and the labor market situation of immigrants has been studied by, for example, Kogan (2004), who explores the unemployment dynamics of different immigrant groups in Germany using data from the SOEP. She concludes that the higher risk of unemployment among immigrants is only partially related to their inferior human capital. Instead it is also due to immigrants overrepresentation in vulnerable occupations and economic branches. Earnings are also an often analyzed indicator: upon arrival, the earnings of immigrants tend to be lower than those of natives, but with increasing duration of residence, the difference between immigrants and natives earnings has been found to decrease (e.g., Chiswick 1978). Despite this assimilation process, an immigrant-native wage gap can still be persistent (e.g. due to the exclusion of foreigners from public sector jobs). For Germany, Fertig and Schurer (2007) find that there are quite different earnings assimilation patterns among different immigrant groups. Whereas ethnic Germans and immigrants who arrived between 1988 and 2002 are found to

2. Legal framework and previous empirical findings 7 catch up with natives after 10 years, those immigrants who arrived between 1969 and 1973 only catch up after 16 years. Welfare dependence, as another indicator of economic integration, has long been rather neglected in Germany and research has only recently started to analyze questions related to welfare dependence or minimum income protection of immigrants (e.g., Riphahn 1998, Castronova et al. 2001, Riphahn 2004). 2 It is important to analyze the determinants of immigrants welfare dependence, because in Germany, as well as in other countries, the share of immigrants in welfare programs exceeds their population share. For example, in 2007, 19% of all unemployment benefit II recipients were foreigners compared with a population share of about 9%. This holds also for social housing: in 2006, 9.5% of all immigrant households benefited from social housing benefits, in comparison with only 2.9% of non-immigrant households (cf. Friedrich 2008). Hence, the important question arises why welfare dependence is so much higher among immigrants than among natives: can the observed gap between immigrants and natives be attributed to the immigrant status per se or to other contextual factors (e.g., socioeconomic characteristics)? In addition, not only the immigrant status per se, but also variables directly related to immigrant status such as years since migration, language skills, or country of origin seem to be of special importance to answer this question. As we have already noted, for Germany, thus far there are not many studies analyzing the welfare dependence of immigrants. Castronova et al. (2001) used cross-sectional data from the German Socio-Economic Panel Study (SOEP) to analyze whether immigrants are on welfare because they are more likely to be eligible or because they are more likely to claim benefits for which they are eligible. Their results show that the greater propensity of immigrants to take-up benefits is not related to the immigrant status per se. If other sociodemographic characteristics are controlled for, immigrant households are no more likely to take-up benefits than native households. Using the waves 1984-1996 of the SOEP, Riphahn (2004) jointly modeled panel attrition, labor force status, and household social assistance dependence. She found that the 2 Most of the earlier studies on welfare dependence of immigrants come from the United States and Canada (e.g., Borjas and Trejo 1991, 1993, Borjas 1994, Baker and Benjamin 1995, Borjas and Hilton 1996, Bean et al. 1997).

3. Data 8 longer the immigrant lives in the host country, the more likely the person is to receive social assistance ( assimilation effect ). In addition, she also concluded that age at migration plays an important role in the predicted probability of welfare dependence of immigrants to Germany. In contrast, she could not find evidence for differences with respect to the country of origin or for different entry cohorts. 3 Data Our empirical analysis uses data from the Socio-Economic Panel Study (SOEP) that provides information about private households in Germany (cf. Wagner et al. 2007). 3 A special focus of the SOEP is on the immigrant population. From its beginning in 1984, the SOEP gathered information on foreigners from the following guest worker countries: Turkey, Greece, (ex-)yugoslavia, Spain, and Italy. These respondents were oversampled in order to provide sufficiently large samples for each immigrant subgroup (cf. Haisken-DeNew and Frick 2005). Furthermore, starting in 1994, the SOEP introduced a special subsample of households with persons who had immigrated to West Germany after 1984. This subsample mainly includes ethnic Germans who resettled to Germany after 1988. Its sample design makes the SOEP one of the most important data sets in the field of empirical research on immigration in Germany (for an overview of data sets and migration statistics for Germany, cf. Haug 2009). We consider all respondents that are not born in Germany as first-generation immigrants independent of their citizenship. 4 With the immigration year at hand, we are able to determine the number of years those persons have lived in Germany. In addition, we define secondgeneration immigrants as respondents who are not first-generation immigrants and who (1) are born in Germany and have a foreign nationality, or (2) are born in Germany and acquired 3 The data used in this paper were extracted using the Add-On package PanelWhiz v2.0 (Nov 2007) for Stata. PanelWhiz was written by Dr. John P. Haisken-DeNew (john@panelwhiz.eu). The PanelWhiz generated DO file to retrieve the SOEP data used here and any Panelwhiz Plugins are available upon request. Haisken-DeNew and Hahn (2006) describe PanelWhiz in detail. 4 The definition of first-generation immigrants is based on the information about the country of origin (variable CORIGIN). In general, this information is equivalent to the country of birth. In the case of missing values, the variable is imputed using proxy information, such as citizenship (for details, cf. Frick et al. 2007).

3. Data 9 German citizenship later in life, or (3) are descendants of first-generation immigrants. 5 In principle, this might include third-generation immigrants. We look at the receipt of unemployment benefit II to study whether immigrants receive minimum income transfers. As the survey asks about benefit receipt in the previous year and unemployment benefit II was introduced in 2005, we can use only the 2006 and 2007 waves of the SOEP. For comparison, we use the waves 2003 and 2004 and analyze the receipt of unemployment assistance and social assistance to describe immigrants situation prior to the reform. Because the benefit reform occurred rather unexpectedly in 2005, we expect substantial measurement error in the benefit information collected in 2005. Therefore, we omit data collected in the 2005 survey. Table 1 Share of households by immigration status Citizenship Country of origin Total Natives German-born 2nd generation Born abroad German 81.87% 3.15% 5.90% 90.92% (4,215) (168) (397) (4,780) Non-German 1.86% 7.22% 9.08% (103) (357) (460) Total 81.87% 5.01% 13.12% 100% (4,215) (271) (754) (5,240) Note: Sample is restricted to working-age household heads (18-65 years of age). Number of observations in parentheses. Data are weighted using cross-sectional weights. Percentages indicate a group s share in total number of households in the population. Source: SOEP 2007. We consider households as the unit of analysis, because unemployment benefit II as well as social assistance are income transfers made at the household level. Because unemployment assistance is coded at the individual level, we define a pre-reform household as a welfare recipient if at least one person in the household received unemployment assistance. In addition to variables measured at the household level, such as the number of persons living in a household, we 5 Because the SOEP follows grown up children when they move out of the parents household, we are able to use parents information to determine the children s immigrant status.

3. Data 10 use the characteristics of the household head to describe the household. The sample excludes household heads that are disabled at the time of the interview, because unemployment benefit II and unemployment assistance are granted only to individuals with full earning capacity. Finally, the sample is restricted to household heads of working age (18-65 years of age). As the proportion of immigrant households is negligible in East Germany, the present analysis refers only to West Germany. The exclusion of East Germany is in line with other studies on German immigrants, such as Kogan (2004) and Riphahn (2004). Based on the definition of immigrant status adopted above, approximately 18% of the working-age household heads in 2007 are first- or second-generation immigrants; 82% are natives (cf. Table 1). 13% are firstgeneration immigrants, and almost 5% are second-generation immigrants born in Germany. In comparison, only 9% hold a foreign citizenship. Table 1 surveys the distribution of immigrant households across categories. First-generation immigrants can be divided into two basic categories of nearly equal-size: the first group of immigrants retained their original citizenship and are legally considered as foreigners (7% of households). These are mostly immigrants who came from typical guest worker countries to Germany during the late 1960s and early 1970s. Ethnic Germans represent the second important group of first-generation immigrants (6% of households). They mostly arrived after the fall of the iron curtain in 1989. Figure 2 shows the relative share of first-generation immigrants from the main source countries. Representing one-fifth of the immigrant population, Turks are the largest single ethnic group in Germany. All in all, immigrants from the typical guest worker countries represent approximately 35% of the immigrant population. Immigrants from the Central and East European (CEE) countries constitute almost 30%. 6 6 The CEE countries here comprise the following countries: Albania, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Bulgaria, Croatia, Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, Macedonia, Poland, Romania, Slovakia, and Slovenia. In contrast to the definition of CEE countries provided by the OECD (http:// www.oecd.org/ document/ 45/ 0,3343,fr_2649_34291_1963117_1_1_1_1,00.html), we do not include Yugoslavia (Serbia and Montenegro) in the CEE countries, but rather in the guest worker countries.

3. Data 11 Figure 2 First-generation immigrants by country of origin Turkey Poland Russia Italy Kazakhstan Austria Romania Croatia Ex Yugoslavia USA Greece Czech Republic Bosnia Herzegovina Holland Spain other nationality 6.3 5.3 4.0 3.2 2.9 2.7 2.4 2.3 2.1 1.7 0.7 10.2 9.1 8.3 18.4 20.3 0 5 10 15 20 Relative share (in percent) Note: Sample is restricted to working-age household heads (18-65 years of age). Household heads, weighted using cross-sectional weights. Source: SOEP 2007. n = 754. Table 2 describes the observed probability of unemployment benefit II receipt in 2006. 12% of all working-age heads of household are transfer recipients. The proportion among immigrants amounts to 24% which is more than twice as high as the number for natives. A special case are single parent households that are characterized by the highest transfer frequency about 46% of the immigrants and 33% of natives. For them, immigrant status is associated with a risk that is is only approximately 1.4-fold higher than on average for household types. All other types of households display a clearly more pronounced difference in the incidence of transfers between immigrants and natives. Especially for couples with children above and below 16 years of age, the immigration status is associated with a substantially increased risk of income transfer. Table 2 shows that immigrants more often than natives live in a household context with children: children live in 56% of all immigrant households and 39% of all native households.

4. Econometric model 12 Table 2 Observed probability of unemployment benefit II receipt (in %) Household type Immigrant status Total Natives All immig. 1st gen. 2nd gen. Single person 10.41 28.24 28.47 27.93 12.82 (33.95) (23.71) (18.60) (37.09) (32.09) Couple without children 4.92 12.07 14.47 4.69 5.86 (25.96) (17.69) (18.47) (15.65) (24.46) Single parent 32.60 45.62 44.76 49.04 35.63 (7.04) (9.07) (10.08) (6.44) (7.41) Couple with children 16 9.54 21.21 17.29 29.80 12.39 (20.28) (28.76) (26.96) (33.48) (21.82) Couple with children> 16 7.86 17.03 17.12 0.0 9.58 (7.74) (8.64) (11.16) (2.05) (7.90) Couple with children above and below 16 6.65 30.99 33.41 0.0 15.09 (3.92) (9.48) (12.19) (2.38) (4.93) Multiple generation household 23.76 5.85 5.85 15.53 (0.32) (1.26) (1.74) (0.49) Other combination 2.22 0.0 0.0 0.0 1.60 (0.80) (1.38) (0.80) (2.90) (0.90) Total 9.96 23.68 23.32 24.63 12.45 (81.87) (18.13) (13.12) (5.00) (100) Note: Calculation is based on less than 30 observations. No observations. Percentage of households with given characteristic is provided in parentheses. Household heads, weighted using cross-sectional weights. First- and second-generation immigrants. Source: SOEP 2007. 4 Econometric model The focus of the analysis is on the question as to what extent immigrants and natives participate in welfare programs. In particular, we discuss whether immigrants differ in their unemployment benefit II receipt and what contextual factors are associated with the receipt of minimum income support. We use natives probability of receiving transfers as a benchmark. We assume that immigrants integrate successfully into the German welfare state if welfare dependency is not more prevalent among immigrants than among natives. We conduct the analysis of the integration process relying on a framework introduced by Chiswick (1978). Chiswick s framework may provide interesting insights, because one can, for example, infer the number of years since migration to the host country after which the

4. Econometric model 13 immigrant-native gap disappears. A regression model that describes the probability of receiving minimum income transfers for immigrants and natives simultaneously can be written for individual i as: y i = α 0 + α 1 age i + δ 0 I i + δ 1 age i I i + θysm i + x iβ+ε i. (1) The propensity to depend on transfers, y, is correlated with age, the number of years since migration to the host country (YSM), and further socioeconomic characteristics of the household represented by the vector x. Since the model requires information about the variable YSM, the remainder of this analysis focuses on first-generation immigrants only. 7 I denotes a dummy variable that indicates whether the head of household is a first-generation immigrant. α 0,α 1,δ 0,δ 1,θ, and β denote the coefficients. ε is the usual idiosyncratic error term assumed to be i.i.d. with mean zero and constant variance. In order to allow for differences in the coefficients in the vectorβfor immigrants and natives, we estimate fully interacted models. Chiswick (1978) assumes that the acquisition of host-country-specific human capital leads to a better (labor market) integration. Thus, Chiswick s model depicts a process of assimilation of immigrants in the host country. However, Borjas (1985) pointed out that cross-sectional data is not suitable to identify an assimilation effect because assimilation is a dynamic process that occurs over time. Based on our short window of observations, we are not able to draw differentiated inferences about assimilation and changes in cohort quality, respectively. Hence, it must remain open whether a correlation between transfer receipt and years since migration is a result of assimilation or of a change in cohort quality. We extend the specification in Equation 1 using a semiparametric additive estimation with binary interaction to describe transfer receipt over the life cycle: y i = β 0 + f Ii (age i )+h(ysm i )+x iβ+ε i, (2) 7 Alternatively, we could have included second-generation immigrants in the group of natives. However, this approach is likely to results in a bias in the natives benchmark probability.

4. Econometric model 14 where f 1 and f 0 are two smooth functions of age for immigrants (I i = 1) and natives (I i = 0), respectively. h denotes a smooth function of years of migration with value zero for natives. The model allows for a highly flexible estimation of the relationship between the probability of receiving minimum income transfers and the life cycle variables, age and YSM, because it does not rely on any functional form assumption. The estimation is implemented using penalized (P-spline) regressions (for a comprehensive introduction to semi- and nonparametric regression models, cf. Ruppert et al. 2003, Wu and Zhang 2006). In particular, we follow Brumback et al. (1999) who demonstrate that the estimation of the P-spline smoother can easily be done within a mixed model framework. A formal description of the estimation framework can be found in Appendix A. For a convenient and less computationally intensive estimation of the semiparametric model, we apply some simplifying assumptions. First, we employ a linear probability specification to estimate the binary choice model that can be regarded as an approximation of the underlying probability. Second, we treat the two data waves after the reform as pooled cross sections, although the data actually have a panel structure. These simplifications come at the cost of not representing the data structure correctly. Since standard errors are likely to be biased due to the heteroskedastic and correlated errors, we base our inferences on bootstrapped standard errors for predicted probabilities. In a subsequent step, we investigate the role of contextual factors in detail using a parametric linear probability model based on Equation 1. The model is estimated with robust standard errors to correct for the heteroskedasticity in the error term. In addition, we include an individual-specific random effect to take into account that the data set contains repeated observations on the same households. Thus, reliable inferences about the statistical significance of the coefficients can be drawn based on this model specification.

5. Results 15 5 Results The descriptive statistics presented in Section 3 have revealed a clear difference in the immigrants and the natives probability of receiving transfers which we study in greater detail below. The probabilities of transfer receipt over the life cycle are described in subsection 5.1. In subsection 5.2, we illuminate the contextual factors associated with transfer receipt. 5.1 Differences in immigrant participation in welfare programs In this subsection, we use graphical representations of life cycle trajectories of the probability of transfer receipt that are plotted for first-generation immigrants and natives, respectively. In a graphical approach one can visually recognize at a glance the difference in welfare dependence for the two groups along the life cycle. We can identify combinations of age and years since migration for which immigrants exhibit a similar probability of transfer receipt compared with natives. We derive the graphical representation of the life cycle trajectories in two steps. In the first step, we estimate the semiparametric regression model introduced in Equation 2 (cf. Section 4). In the second step, we simulate the probability of transfer receipt over the life cycle for immigrants and natives, respectively, based on the estimation results obtained in the first step. The graphical representation of the predicted probabilities are rendered in Figure 3. First, the semiparametric regression was estimated including only age and years since migration without further covariates. This unconditional regression model provides a picture of the unadjusted probability of transfers over the life cycle. Next, because differences in transfer receipt between immigrants and natives may also be due to other variables that are correlated with immigrant status, we applied a regression model that controls for socioeconomic characteristics. The curves obtained from the conditional and unconditional regression models are provided in the top and bottom rows in Figure 3, respectively.

5.1 Differences in immigrant participation in welfare programs 16 Simulating the predicted probabilities of immigrants, it must be considered that both, age and years since migration, cannot vary independently: staying one extra year in the host country is equivalent to an increase in age by one. Thus, probabilities are predicted for the following type of immigrant: it is assumed that the immigrant enters the host country at the age of 25, so that a movement along the x-axis implies an increase in years since migration and age. 8 For natives, the x-axis represents age only. Using the conditional regression model, we simulate a specific household type. 9 We calculated confidence bands of the curves for the predicted probabilities to assess the statistical significance of the differences between immigrants and natives. For that purpose, we estimated the standard errors of the prediction using a bootstrap approach with 100 replications. The corresponding graphs are given in Figure 4 in Appendix C. 10 In general, the graphs tend to provide no evidence for overlap of the confidence bands of the unconditional probabilities (cf. row 1 in Table 4). Therefore, except for social assistance receipt, one can conclude that the immigrant-native gap in transfer receipt is statistically significantly different from zero if no further covariates are considered. With respect to unemployment benefit II, this finding confirms what has already been apparent in the descriptive statistics in Section 3: immigrants have a considerably higher probability of transfer receipt compared to natives. As the immigrant-native gap persists over the entire life cycle, one may suppose that neither assimilation nor differences in cohort quality play a role. A different conclusion results, however, when we control for further socioeconomic characteristics of the household in the regression. With the inclusion of the covariates, the immigrantnative gap disappears for all welfare programs analyzed. Compared with the results of the unconditional regression models, the curves obtained from the covariate-adjusted model are closer to each other and their confidence bands overlap very clearly. Moreover, it is evident that 8 Because the observed data do not contain all possible combinations of age and years since migration, it may happen that the predicted values of the linear probability model are outside the interval[0,1]. 9 We simulate the following household type: married couple with one child, male household head with 15 years of full-time experience and two years of previous unemployment, currently employed, and middle vocational education. For immigrants, these additional assumptions apply: non-eu citizenship, vocational degree obtained in Germany, and good language skills. 10 We present the confidence bands in a separate figure to avoid a cluttered presentation.

5.1 Differences in immigrant participation in welfare programs 17 both, the immigrants curves and the natives curves, exhibit similar profiles over a large range of x-values. Thus, we conclude that immigrant status per se is not correlated with immigrants higher probability of receiving income transfers. Instead, their socioeconomic characteristics are associated with the gap to the native transfer rate. Considering the respective welfare programs, the life cycle trajectories of transfer receipt can be characterized as follows. Before the reform, immigrants new to the country have a significantly higher probability of social assistance relative to natives. However, the relatively steep slope of the immigrants curve indicates a rapid convergence with the natives benefit receipt within 5-10 years (cf. Figures 3.1 and 3.5). This finding may reflect that immigrants who have stayed at least 5-10 years in Germany have integrated into the labor market. In subsequent life phases, the probability of social assistance is almost identical for immigrants and natives. The conditional regression line in Figure 3.5 indicates a rising probability of social assistance receipt starting from the age of 40 (and assuming 15 years since migration for immigrants). In this context, the study of Riphahn (2004) based on panel data for the years 1984-1996 also showed that the transfer probability increases with the length of stay. Our results point to an analogous pattern in the data for 2003 and 2004. With respect to unemployment assistance, the curves are characterized by a bimodal shape that is particularly pronounced among immigrants (cf. Figures 3.2 and 3.6). In particular, the second peak between 55 and 60 years of age may reflect the difficulties of older workers in finding new employment after becoming unemployed. One the one hand, many companies are unwilling to hire older workers, on the other hand older workers have lower job mobility rates (cf. Clemens et al. 2003). Thus, older individuals may take unemployment assistance to finance the transition into retirement. In order to compare the welfare programs before and after the reform (i.e., to compare social assistance and unemployment assistance with unemployment benefit II), we generated a composite indicator that measures jointly the receipt of either social assistance or unemployment assistance for 2003 and 2004. Again, once covariates are controlled for, the curves estimated show a quite similar course over the life cycle for immigrants and natives (cf. Figure 3.7). Start-

Figure 3 Probability of transfer receipt Unconditional regression models (control variables omitted) Probability of receipt 0.05.1.15.2 Before the reform After the reform Fig. 3.1: Social assistance Fig. 3.2: Unemployment assistance Fig. 3.3: Composite indicator Fig. 3.4: Unemployment benefit II 30 40 50 60 Age Probability of receipt 0.05.1.15 30 40 50 60 Age Conditional regression models (control variables included) Probability of receipt 0.05.1.15 Before the reform Probability of receipt 0.05.1.15 Probability of receipt.04.06.2.08.1.12 30 40 50 60 Age Probability of receipt 0.05.1.15.2.25.3.35.4 30 40 50 60 Age After the reform Fig. 3.5: Social assistance Fig. 3.6: Unemployment assistance Fig. 3.7: Composite indicator Fig. 3.8: Unemployment benefit II 30 40 50 60 Age Probability of receipt 0.02.04.06.08 30 40 50 60 Age 30 40 50 60 Age Probability of receipt.08.1.12.14.16 30 40 50 60 Age Note: Solid lines represent natives, dashed lines are for immigrants. Immigrants are assumed to arrive in the host country at age 25. For immigrants, an increase on the x-axis is tantamount to an increase of both age and years since migration. For natives, the x-axis represents age only. Source: SOEP 2003, 2004, 2006, 2007. 5.1 Differences in immigrant participation in welfare programs 18

5.2 Parametric estimation results 19 ing with a downward sloping gradient, the minimum of the transfer probability occurs between about 35-40 years of age. Then, the curve increases considerably up to the age of almost 60 years. This development may result from the poorer labor market prospects of older workers mentioned above. The decrease after the age of 60 years may be because older individuals make more use of the possibility of early retirement, in the case of unemployment or disability, for example. A comparison of the composite indicator and unemployment benefit II leads to the conclusion that transfer receipt probabilities are very similar before and after the reform. This finding suggests that the life cycle pattern that characterizes transfer receipt has not changed substantially due to the reform. The life stages linked with a higher risk of receiving transfers before the reform are also characteristic of an increased risk after the reform. It is, however, notable that the level of the probability of transfer receipt is, on average, higher after the reform than it was before the reform. One reason for the upward shift in levels may result from the fact that many people did not claim their entitlement to social assistance before the reform (cf. Kayser and Frick 2001, Riphahn 2001). Studies have calculated that more than half of the eligible households did not take up social assistance. Possible reasons for the low take-up are low claim amounts, social stigma, and the expectation of a short period of eligibility (cf. Wilde and Kubis 2005). 5.2 Parametric estimation results In this subsection, we present results obtained from linear probability models which can be found in Tables 5-7 in Appendix D. The specification is based on Equation 1 and includes variables describing the contextual factors of the household, immigrant-specific variables, and a set of interaction terms that allow inferences about differences in the coefficients for immigrants and natives, respectively. The contextual factors that are correlated with transfer receipt are discussed below with respect to three groups: (1) characteristics of the household, (2) characteristics of the household head, and (3) immigrant-related variables. A special focus of the

5.2 Parametric estimation results 20 analysis is on differences between immigrants and natives revealed by the coefficients of the interaction terms. We begin with the question of whether the parametric regressions confirm the finding that the immigration status is uncorrelated with the transfer receipt as found in the previous subsection. Therefore, we perform an F-test on joint significance of all immigrant-related variables in the regression of unemployment benefits II. The null hypothesis is not rejected at the 5% level, so the test indicates that the group of all 37 immigrant-related variables is statistically insignificant. Thus, the parametric model indicates that the immigrant-related variables are not associated with transfer receipt, what confirms the conclusion obtained in the previous subsection. However, it may happen that a statistically significant variable is hidden in the group of insignificant variables. For that reason, we look at the coefficients in greater detail below. Next, we look at characteristics of the household. The presence of children in the household increases the probability of transfers. This finding applies to both, natives and immigrants, and holds for all three welfare programs under consideration: single parents are clearly more likely to rely on transfers than other types of households. An explanation may be seen in the fact that single parents have fewer opportunities to participate in the labor market, because of inadequate possibilities for childcare. Furthermore, the number of children in the household is positively correlated with the likelihood of receiving transfers. With respect to social assistance, the correlation between the transfer receipt and the number of children is even more pronounced for immigrants, as is evident from the statistically significant positive parameter of the interaction term. With respect to unemployment benefit II, the average education of all household members is associated with a lower probability of transfer receipt for natives only. This relationship cannot be observed for immigrants, because the coefficient of the interaction term is estimated with the opposite sign and this estimator is of even larger magnitude than the parameter of the main effect. Before the reform, the situation is, on the contrary, not characterized by a difference between natives and immigrants parameters: a higher average education is also linked to a lower probability of social assistance for immigrant households. Although the estimators have,

5.2 Parametric estimation results 21 as expected, a negative sign, the unemployment assistance regression does not show a statistically significant correlation with education for neither natives nor immigrants. However, the parameters may be estimated imprecisely because of problems of multicollinearity between the average education in the household and the variables indicating the education of the household head. The parameters on variables describing the health status of the household head indicate that economic risks are likely to increase with health risks. A negative self-assessment of health and/or a hospital stay in the previous year is associated with a higher probability of transfer receipt. This relationship seems more pronounced for immigrants, as the coefficient of the interaction terms suggests. This could be, for example, due to differences in the use of health care services. If immigrants have a greater delay in seeking medical care, then a hospital stay indicates, on average, a poorer health status for immigrants than for natives. In this context, Wittig et al. (2004) point out that ethnic Germans have a lower frequency of doctor visits than native Germans, albeit ethnic Germans self-assess their health as worse. A study by the Robert Koch-Institut (2008) reports that immigrants are less likely to participate in screening tests. The current labor market status of the household head strongly connects with all three welfare programs. Thus, the household has an increased probability of receiving transfers, if the household head is not in the labor force for reasons of parental leave or training and educational measures. Moreover, being unemployed is also associated with receiving transfers. This is an expected finding, because unemployed persons apply for minimum income support as an earnings replacement benefit. In addition to the current labor market status, the previous experience (conditional on age and education) in the labor market plays an important role: previous years of full- and part-time employment are associated with a lower probability of transfers, whereas previous periods of unemployment show a positive correlation. All variables describing the labor market status and employment history show significant coefficients with respect to unemployment benefit II and social assistance. However, only the coefficients of the current and previous unemployment are statistically significant in the unemployment assistance regression. Because none of the coefficients of the interaction terms is statistically significant, there is no reason to infer that there are differences between immigrants and natives.

5.2 Parametric estimation results 22 An individual s human capital endowment is not only determined by labor market experience, but also by educational and vocational training. Therefore, the regression includes variables measuring the educational attainment of the household head. For that purpose, we used the CASMIN scheme that provides a possibility to classify educational attainment. For Germany, Brauns and Steinmann (1999) proposed to distinguish between general qualifications and qualifications with vocational emphasis. Building on the provided CASMIN variable in the SOEP, we constructed six dummy variables (following Kogan (2004)): low general or less education, low vocational education, medium general education, medium vocational training, tertiary short education, and tertiary long education. With respect to unemployment benefit II and social assistance, individuals with a lower educational attainment have, as one would have expected, an increased probability of receiving transfers compared with those with basic or advanced vocational training (reference category), holding average education of the household constant. Natives with a higher educational attainment have an increased benefit incidence. This finding seems counter-intuitive at first sight. It could, however, reflect the fact that this group is very likely in a better position to enforce their transfer claims, because they could be expected to have fewer difficulties in overcoming administrative hurdles. With respect to unemployment benefit II, the coefficient of the interaction term for the variable indicating tertiary long education (i.e., academically oriented university education) indicates that this finding does not apply to immigrants. Among immigrants, advanced higher education is clearly linked with a lower probability of transfer receipts. The results from the social assistance regression suggest that it matters whether vocational training was acquired in Germany or abroad. The significantly positive coefficient of the variable may reflect productivity differences between vocational training acquired in Germany and abroad. It is possible that individuals with a foreign degree have difficulty in finding employment opportunities compared with individuals with a degree obtained in Germany, and are therefore dependent on social assistance. On the other hand, this relationship is not evident with respect to unemployment assistance. A possible explanation may be that unemployment