Planning the American Dream: The Case for an Office of Opportunity

Similar documents
FRBSF Joint Board of Directors Meeting Economic Research Seminar Session April 11, U.S. Income Inequality in Perspective

download slides at: Mobility Inequality in the United States 1

Race and Economic Opportunity in the United States

A Regional Look at Single Moms and Upward Mobility. Family-Friendly Policies Can Be Linked to Greater Economic Mobility Among Single Mothers

Statement of Sally Katzen. Visiting Professor of Law, New York University School of Law And Senior Advisor at the Podesta Group.

GETTING AHEAD OR LOSING GROUND:

THE MEASURE OF AMERICA

ECON 361: Income Distributions and Problems of Inequality

Equitable Growth. Patterns of Economic Mobility in the United States. Washington Center for

American Inequality in Six Charts

Inequality, Life Chances, and Public Policy

The Past, Present and Future. of U.S. Income Inequality

Inclusion and Gender Equality in China

Do Our Children Have A Chance? The 2010 Human Opportunity Report for Latin America and the Caribbean

Charles I Plosser: A progress report on our monetary policy framework

How does having immigrant parents affect the outcomes of children in Europe?

Qatar. Switzerland Russian Federation Saudi Arabia Brazil. New Zealand India Pakistan Philippines Nicaragua Chad Yemen

The Importance of Economic Mobility

Widening of Inequality in Japan: Its Implications

Economic Inequality and Mobility. Looking at the Evidence to Inform Philanthropy s Actions

Cross-Country Intergenerational Status Mobility: Is There a Great Gatsby Curve?

Persistent Poverty on Indian Reservations: New Perspectives and Responses 1

Prosperity in Central and Eastern Europe A Legatum Institute Prosperity Report

World of Labor. John V. Winters Oklahoma State University, USA, and IZA, Germany. Cons. Pros

Jeffrey M. Stonecash Maxwell Professor

Intergenerational mobility during South Africa s mineral revolution. Jeanne Cilliers 1 and Johan Fourie 2. RESEP Policy Brief

UK Productivity Gap: Skills, management and innovation

AirPlus International Travel Management Study 2015 Part 1 A comparison of global trends and costs in business travel management.

We the People: The Citizen and the Constitution

The Future of Inequality

CHARLOTTE: FACING THE CHALLENGES OF ECONOMIC OPPORTUNITY AND MOBILITY

The only way is up? Social Mobility and Equal Opportunities. The Issues Note

Rural America Competitive Bush Problems and Economic Stress Put Rural America in play in 2008

Comparative Political Economy. David Soskice Nuffield College

Persistent Poverty on Indian Reservations: New Perspectives and Responses 1

Stratification: Rich and Famous or Rags and Famine? 2015 SAGE Publications, Inc.

U.S. Family Income Growth

It s Time to Begin An Adult Conversation on PISA. CTF Research and Information December 2013

Making Government Work For The People Again

HIGHLIGHTS. There is a clear trend in the OECD area towards. which is reflected in the economic and innovative performance of certain OECD countries.

An Increased Incumbency Effect: Reconsidering Evidence

PART 1 INTRODUCTION SCOPE OF THIS REPORT

The Battleground: Democratic Perspective September 7 th, 2016

Chapter 17. The Labor Market and The Distribution of Income. Microeconomics: Principles, Applications, and Tools NINTH EDITION

Great Gatsby Curve: Empirical Background. Steven N. Durlauf University of Wisconsin

THE WORKMEN S CIRCLE SURVEY OF AMERICAN JEWS. Jews, Economic Justice & the Vote in Steven M. Cohen and Samuel Abrams

Blues Public Policy Brief *Customer Edition* February 24, 2012

HOW CONGRESS WORKS. The key to deciphering the legislative process is in understanding that legislation is grouped into three main categories:

AFRICAN INSTITUTE FOR REMITTANCES (AIR)

Local participation: How where you live influences what crimes you commit. Danny Dorling Keble, Oxford 1 October 2012

An Agenda for America

New Ideas About Income Inequality in A Digitalizing World

Promoting Work in Public Housing

The Canada We Want in Equality of opportunity

Survey of US Voters Issues and Attitudes June 2014

1. Global Disparities Overview

WHEN MOVING MATTERS Residential and Economic Mobility Trends in America,

How does education affect the economy?

Immigration and Employment:

Emerging Asian economies lead Global Pay Gap rankings

Executive Summary. International mobility of human resources in science and technology is of growing importance

Thomas Piketty. Human Capital. 21st. in the. Century. by alan b. krueger. 48 The Milken Institute Review

Economic Mobility & Housing

The Central Florida Workforce in Today s Recession. Presented by: Gary Earl WORKFORCE CENTRAL FLORIDA President and CEO

REFLECTIONS OF A PARTICIPANT ON AMERICAN DEMOCRACY AND THE CONSTITUTION

OECD SKILLS STRATEGY FLANDERS DIAGNOSTIC WORKSHOP

Where are the Middle Class in OECD Countries? Nathaniel Johnson (CUNY and LIS) David Johnson (University of Michigan)

AirPlus International Travel Management Study 2015 Part 1 A comparison of global trends and costs in business travel management.

5A. Wage Structures in the Electronics Industry. Benjamin A. Campbell and Vincent M. Valvano

LEGISLATIVE GLOSSARY

epub WU Institutional Repository

The Economic and Social Outcomes of Children of Migrants in New Zealand

Increasing the Participation of Refugee Seniors in the Civic Life of Their Communities: A Guide for Community-Based Organizations

Cons. Pros. Vanderbilt University, USA, CASE, Poland, and IZA, Germany. Keywords: immigration, wages, inequality, assimilation, integration

Gender pay gap in public services: an initial report

A Barometer of the Economic Recovery in Our State

How s Life in New Zealand?

Guided Reading & Analysis: The Legislative Branch- Chapter 3, pp

The Big Decisions Ahead on Economic Renewal and Reduced Debt

Chapter Four Presidential and Congressional Constraints

Issue Overview: Immigration reform

Outline. Why is international mobility an important policy issue? The International Mobility of Researchers. IMHE Conference

European Parliament Eurobarometer (EB79.5) ONE YEAR TO GO UNTIL THE 2014 EUROPEAN ELECTIONS Institutional Part ANALYTICAL OVERVIEW

INTERNAL SECURITY. Publication: November 2011

Executive Summary Don t Always Stay on Message: Using Strategic Framing to Move the Public Discourse On Immigration

The Future of Inequality: The Other Reason Education Matters So Much

Testimony to the United States Senate Budget Committee Hearing on Opportunity, Mobility, and Inequality in Today's Economy April 1, 2014

Learning from Other Countries---and from Ourselves: the case of demography. Cliff Adelman, Institute for Higher Education Policy March 5, 2013

CO3.6: Percentage of immigrant children and their educational outcomes

The Report of the Commission on Immigration Reform (i.e., the Jordan Commission): A Beacon for Real Immigration Reform

Rising Share of Americans See Conflict Between Rich and Poor

An in-depth examination of North Carolina voter attitudes on important current issues

Wide and growing divides in views of racial discrimination

Funding Outlook for the Ryan White HIV/AIDS Program

PARTISANSHIP AND WINNER-TAKE-ALL ELECTIONS

The Exceptional Economy

How s Life in Denmark?

What to Look for as Congress Begins Work on 2017 Appropriations By David Reich

BLISS INSTITUTE 2006 GENERAL ELECTION SURVEY

CHASING THE SAME DREAM, CLIMBING DIFFERENT LADDERS:

Transcription:

Center on Children and Families at BROOKINGS May 2014 CCF Brief # 53 Planning the American Dream: The Case for an Office of Opportunity Richard V. Reeves

Opportunity is a Bipartisan Issue U.S. politics is short on bipartisanship. But there is one issue on which the major players on both sides of the aisle are in agreement. Upward intergenerational mobility is too low which is both a symptom and a cause of unfairness in American society. Take these two quotes, one from President Obama and the other from Representative Paul Ryan: Upward mobility is the central promise of life in America: but right now, America s engines of upward mobility aren t working the way they should. Opportunity is who we are but upward mobility has stalled. Hard to know which one is which, isn t it? The first is Ryan, the second Obama. Rhetorical agreement that America ought to be a land of opportunity is, of course, hardly news. But it is significant that most senior political figures now agree that we are falling way short of this ideal. Mounting empirical evidence that rates of intergenerational social mobility in the U.S. are low and flat has finally penetrated the American political consciousness. A chance for some bipartisan work to address social mobility has presented itself. This is a precious moment, which ought to be seized. But even if the two sides agree there is a problem, they are very far from agreeing on any solution. Quite the opposite: while Democrats are pushing state action pre-k education, Race to the Top in schools, a higher minimum wage, new metrics for college performance Republicans emphasize wealth creation, trust, and civic capital in communities, and focus on reducing welfare rolls. For now, then, efforts to gain bipartisan support for specific policy programs are likely to be unsuccessful. Policies will have to stand or fall on the political battleground. But there is space for bipartisanship in the creation of an institutional framework designed to measure the nation s progress towards greater opportunity, keep the attention of policy-makers on this long-term task, and dispassionately assess initiatives intended to improve rates of social mobility. The Mobility Challenge Intergenerational mobility can be measured using a variety of different scales and over different time periods. An important, basic distinction is between absolute and relative mobility. Absolute mobility is a measure of how people fare compared to their parents, particularly in terms of income, education or occupation. Most people, given economic growth, will achieve a standard of living higher than their parents managed by the same age. The latest data suggests that 84% of people are upwardly mobile in this sense. Relative mobility is a measure of where people end up on the income ladder, compared to their peers, on the basis of their background: the extent to which the circumstances of birth determine the outcomes in life. A common approach is to examine the relationship between the income quintile (fifth of the income distribution) people end up in as adults, compared to the quintile they were born or raised in. The transitions between generations can be shown clearly on a graph: 2

Percent of Adult Children in Each Family Income Group 100% 90% 80% 70% 60% 50% 40% 30% 10% 0% Figure 1: Children's Chances of Getting Ahead or Falling Behind, by Parents' Family Income 4% 9% 17% 27% 43% Bottom 14% 18% 24% 25% Second 19% 24% 23% 14% Middle 24% 24% 23% 40% 23% 19% 10% 9% 8% Fourth Parents' Family Income Group Top Top Source: Leonard Lopoo and Thomas DeLeire. "Pursuing the American Dream: Economic Mobility Across Generations." Pew Charitable Trusts, 2012. Fourth Middle Second Bottom This shows that the U.S. income distribution has sticky ends: four out of ten of those raised in the bottom quintile remain on the bottom rung as adults, and almost the same proportion raised at the top manage to remain there. Only one in twenty move from the bottom to the top. Studies adopting more sophisticated methods, such as rank directional mobility (which measures movement up and down the whole range of percentiles of the income distribution) produce similar results but can provide more detail. One finding, for example, is that rates of downward mobility from the top 5% of the U.S. income distribution are much lower than in Canada. Importantly, and contrary to some political rhetoric, this picture has not changed in recent decades. The chances of someone from the bottom quintile moving up looks to have been low for at least half a century: Probability Child in Top Fifth of Income Distribution Figure 2: Probability of Reaching Top at Age 26 by Birth Cohort 35% 30% 25% 15% 10% 5% Parents' Income 0% 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 Child's Birth Cohort Source: Raj Chetty et al. "Is The United States Still A Land Of Opportunity? Recent Trends in Intergenerational Mobility" NBER Working Paper 19844, 2014. Figure 3. Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Q5 3

Sluggish upward mobility is not a new problem for the U.S. What is new is the general acceptance and widespread discussion of the problem among policy-makers. Another mobility measure, often used for the purposes of international comparison, is of intergenerational earnings elasticity the extent to which a person s wages relate to their parents wages. More mobile societies will show a lower correlation between the earnings of parents and children, and there is significant variation across economically developed nations on this measure: Figure 3: Intergenerational Elasticity between Father and Son Earnings United Kingdom United States 0.47 0.50 France 0.41 Germany 0.32 Sweden 0.27 Canada Finland Norway Denmark 0.19 0.18 0.17 0.15 0.00 0.10 0.20 0.30 0.40 0.50 0.60 Intergenerational Earnings Elasticity Source: Miles Corak. Do Poor Children Become Poor Adults? Lessons from a Cross Country Comparison of Generational Earnings Mobility. IZA Discussion Paper No. 1993, 2006. Table 1. All I have provided here is a lightning sketch of a complex, growing research literature. But suffice it to say, U.S. mobility rates are low by international standards, flat over time, and too low for most observers of all political stripes. There is now the possibility of greater political commitment to act on the opportunity challenge, but the first steps need to be taken carefully. Needed: An Office of Opportunity Having identified a problem, the temptation is to jump immediately to policy solutions. But there are two good reasons to be careful about making this leap. First, there is only a very slender consensus among scholars on which specific policies or programs will effectively promote mobility (although few would argue closing gaps in the quality of K-12 education is not a priority). Second, there is no consensus among politicians on the same question. There is, however, an important space between agreeing, in general terms, that we have a mobility problem, and agreeing on policy solutions. It should be possible to at least agree to officially measure trends in mobility, track interim indicators of our direction of travel, and assess the likely effects of various policies on mobility. We should, in short, be able to set a goal increased intergenerational social mobility and agree to start officially measuring our progress towards it. If we can agree on the ends, the political argument can continue over the means. At the moment, politicians and policymakers rely on academic studies of mobility trends. We have official measures of growth, federal spending, employment, productivity and poverty but 4

no official measure of mobility. Given the central importance of mobility to a shared definition of American fairness, this is a serious omission. It is a fact that what gets measured gets talked about, worried about, and acted on. Whatever the shortcomings of the official poverty line (and they are many), its existence galvanizes political debate and policy development. Adopting an official mobility measure is unlikely to require vast new data collection though some investments will need to be made. It is more a question of deciding that mobility is worth measuring and promoting. As my colleague Isabel Sawhill put it, arguing for a wider range of social indicators: The principal barrier to quantification, in the long run at least, is not a lack of meaningful data but a failure to define what is meaningful to give operational content to our ideals. There is a strong case for the mobility measure, and related activity, to be owned and promoted by an independent institution. In part, this is to increase the chances of bipartisan support. But it is also because improving the rate of social mobility is a long-term task, spanning many administrations and congresses. Giving mobility an institutional home in the form of an Office of Opportunity will help maintain a commitment to the mobility cause over the longerterm. An Office of Opportunity would not deliver programs or allocate funds. The role of the Office would be to produce the official mobility measure, promote key indicators of social and economic mobility, and evaluate policy options for boosting rates of mobility. The new Office of Opportunity will act, then, as a commitment device, a measuring device, and an accountability device. Here I make the case for such an Office at a national level but a virtually identical case can be made to forward-looking states and cities. What the Office of Opportunity Should Do The Office will focus on measures, metrics, and empirical assessments. It will be for its leaders to determine which precise gauges to apply. But it should undertake three broad tasks: First, define and measure success. By contrast to other areas of bipartisan enthusiasm (such as economic growth), there is a dearth of clear, comparable, consistent data on progress on social mobility. And there is no official measure that is tracked and published on a regular basis, unlike, for example, the poverty statistics. The Office should produce an annual official mobility report, with a selection of different yardsticks. But it should also highlight a single measure of progress. For instance, the official mobility measure might be the proportion of people born in the bottom quintile making it to one of the top two quintiles: right now, that number is 13%. Over time, that measure has been fairly stable: Figure 4: Geographical Variation in Chances of Transitioning from the Bottom to One of the Top Two s Note: This map was produced by Alex Olssen and Nathaniel Hendren of the Equality of Opportunity Project. For a description of the underlying data used to generate this figure, see Raj Chetty et al. Where is the Land of Opportunity? The Geography of Intergenerational Mobility in the United States. NBER Working Paper 19843, 2014. 5

This is a relative rather than absolute measure of mobility. The Office should report on trends in both. But the mobility challenge, as expressed by most politicians, is typically a relative one. The Office may also choose to invest in higher-quality data. Because intergenerational mobility is a long-term goal, longitudinal studies are vital. So the Office could promote and if necessary fund high-quality longitudinal data collection. It may also choose to develop lifecycle models designed to estimate the long-run impact of policy interventions and/or social and economic changes. The New Zealand Treasury has pioneered a number of models for use in and by the government, including, most recently, a lifecycle model. Scholars at the Brookings Institution have also developed a lifecycle micro-simulation model, the Social Genome Model, which is now being further developed in partnership with the Urban Institute and Child Trends. Second, produce leading indicators of likely future mobility trends. Clearly, shifting the official mobility rate will be a long-term, difficult task. The Office should also produce annual reports on shorter-term trends that based on the best available evidence will likely lead to more upward mobility in the long run. This creates a dashboard from which overall progress can be estimated. The Office might be able to learn from similar approaches elsewhere: for example, the U.K. government publishes 17 such indicators which have been independently judged to be powerful predictors of long-run mobility. The leading indicators might be organized around key life stages, or the strong starts necessary to be successful in life. Note the emphasis here is not just on overall rates for each indicator, but the gap between different groups (in these examples, between poor and non-poor). There is an important issue of substance here, highlighting the distinction between absolute and relative mobility. Increasing the overall rate in any area will mean more people doing better than their parents (i.e., absolute mobility). But improving rates of relative intergenerational mobility (how people fare compared to others in their own generation) will typically require a closing of the gap on key indicators, at least as much as raising the overall rate. Importantly, the key metric in terms of relative mobility is not raising the overall level of achievement but narrowing the achievement gaps between different groups. Increasing college graduation rates will not improve mobility rates if most of the increase is made up of students from affluent backgrounds. Expanding the size of the professional class generates greater absolute mobility by creating more room at the top, but may do nothing to alter relative mobility (i.e., the chances of ending up in that class by social background). For mobility, the mantra is always: mind the gap. Here are some illustrative leading indicators: Figure 5: Possible Leading Indicators for Social Mobility To the extent that certain government agencies will be focused on many of these gaps, the Office of Opportunity will help to coordinate and assess the efforts of multiple actors in improving overall mobility. Third, assess policies for improving social mobility. Many policies aim to narrow the opportunity gap (i.e., promote upward relative mobility). Whether they work or not is another matter. Importantly, policy here means not just public policy, but also policies adopted by businesses or voluntary organizations. Corporate hiring policies, for example, may have as great an impact on mobility as any number of federal K-12 initiatives. The Office ought to be evangelical about the 6

ends intergenerational mobility but agnostic about the various means to it. What matters is what works. The Office could select certain areas of focus each year, or certain policy proposals on an ad hoc basis. For example, in its first year of life, the U.K. Commission for Social Mobility and Child Poverty produced reports on access to the professions, and to higher education. How to Create the Office: Three Approaches The Office should require only a modest budget of, say, $10 million a year. It is a small institution with a big message. There are at least three models: 1. Executive office, created by presidential order 2. Congressional office, created by legislation 3. Hybrid agency, commission, or board In an ideal world, the new Office of Opportunity would enjoy bipartisan support and the respect and attention of both the executive and legislative branches of government. Of course, we do not live in an ideal world. It may be that the only way such an Office will be created is through Executive Order which, given current political dynamics, may also mean it will have a short life and difficulty attracting resources in terms of talent, political energy, and money. Each model for the proposed Office of Opportunity comes with pros and cons, and there will be different views about the best way forward. There will also, of course, be alternatives to the approaches listed here. Perhaps the CBO could set up a new unit? Or a joint unit might be established between the CBO and OMB. There are doubtless many other options. Table 1: Office of Opportunity: Three Models MODEL ANALOGUES MECHANISM LEADERSHIP PROS CONS Executive Office Congressional Office Agency/ Commission Office of Social Innovation and Civic Participation CBO NLRB or GAO Exec. Order: funding split between education, HUD & HHS. Law: Funding appropriated regularly Law: President appoints head; money from discretionary funds Presidential appointees & career staff Independent expert appointed by Congress Bipartisan Board, including governors & key Congressional Chairs Quick Focused on the President s goals Improves coordination in Executive branch Political appeal for incumbent Bipartisan appeal Independent Likely to endure Bipartisan appeal Some independence Involve states Unlikely to outlast the current President If opposed in Congress, impact blunted, and funding hard to secure Unlikely in current Congress Antagonistic relationship with the Executive branch, making bipartisan action more difficult Weaker foundations & therefore credibility Danger of descending into a talking shop 7

Conclusion It is always tempting, especially for those of us outside government, to prescribe the creation of a new institution to fix a prevailing social or economic problem. As a rule, the better path is to make better use of existing institutions. But there is at least a plausible argument that intergenerational mobility could be an exception, that a new institution is justified. This is not to say that even a modestly-funded, narrowly-focused Office of Opportunity will have an easy birth. Building an institution is always hard: and never more so, perhaps, than in a congressional political system, during a partisan period of political life. In itself, a new Office of Opportunity would do nothing to promote mobility. But it would help to create a shared understanding of the facts, a clear assessment of our challenges and progress, and a better foundation for developing policies likely to make America a more socially mobile, more open society. If opportunity is who we are, we should do a better job of finding out how we are faring, and holding ourselves and our successors to greater account for our efforts to restore its promise. Author Richard V. Reeves is a fellow in Economic Studies, and policy director of the Center on Children and Families at Brookings. The views expressed in this policy brief are those of the author and should not be attributed to the staff, officers, or trustees of The Brookings Institution or the other sponsors of this policy brief. Additional Reading Deputy Prime Minister s Office. Research and Analysis: Social Mobility Indicators. November 16, 2013. Isabel V. Sawhill. The Role of Social Indicators and Social Reporting in Public Expenditure Decisions. In The Analysis and Evaluation of Public Expenditures: the PPB System: A Compendium of Papers Submitted to the Subcommittee on Economy in Government of the Joint Economic Committee, Congress of the United States. Washington: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1969. Paul Gregg and Lindsey Macmillan. Measuring Mobility. Swindon: Economic and Social Research Council, 2011. To learn more about the Center on Children and Families at the Brookings Institution, please visit our website, www.brookings.edu/ccf. 8