Ideological Perfectionism on Judicial Panels

Similar documents
Campaign Contributions as Valence

1 Electoral Competition under Certainty

Electoral competition and corruption: Theory and evidence from India

3 Electoral Competition

Voter Participation with Collusive Parties. David K. Levine and Andrea Mattozzi

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES

Classical papers: Osborbe and Slivinski (1996) and Besley and Coate (1997)

Enriqueta Aragones Harvard University and Universitat Pompeu Fabra Andrew Postlewaite University of Pennsylvania. March 9, 2000

Supporting Information for Signaling and Counter-Signaling in the Judicial Hierarchy: An Empirical Analysis of En Banc Review

Published in Canadian Journal of Economics 27 (1995), Copyright c 1995 by Canadian Economics Association

MIDTERM EXAM 1: Political Economy Winter 2017

How Political Parties Shape Electoral Competition

Choosing Among Signalling Equilibria in Lobbying Games

Party Platforms with Endogenous Party Membership

Does the Median Justice Control. the Content of Supreme Court Opinions? Cliff Carrubba. Barry Friedman. Andrew Martin.

The Robustness of Herrera, Levine and Martinelli s Policy platforms, campaign spending and voter participation

Reputation and Rhetoric in Elections

ON IGNORANT VOTERS AND BUSY POLITICIANS

Median voter theorem - continuous choice

How Political Parties Shape Electoral Competition

Ideological extremism and primaries.

Correlation neglect, voting behaviour and polarization

Sincere versus sophisticated voting when legislators vote sequentially

Sincere Versus Sophisticated Voting When Legislators Vote Sequentially

ELECTORAL SELECTION WITH PARTIES AND PRIMARIES

Coalition Governments and Political Rents

Essays in Political Economy

'Wave riding' or 'Owning the issue': How do candidates determine campaign agendas?

Economics 470 Some Notes on Simple Alternatives to Majority Rule

MULTIPLE VOTES, MULTIPLE CANDIDACIES AND POLARIZATION ARNAUD DELLIS

ESSAYS ON STRATEGIC VOTING. by Sun-Tak Kim B. A. in English Language and Literature, Hankuk University of Foreign Studies, Seoul, Korea, 1998

Mathematics and Social Choice Theory. Topic 4 Voting methods with more than 2 alternatives. 4.1 Social choice procedures

Case Study: Get out the Vote

Publicizing malfeasance:

Disasters and Incumbent Electoral Fortunes: No Implications for Democratic Competence

The electoral strategies of a populist candidate: Does charisma discourage experience and encourage extremism?

With Friends Like These, Who Needs Enemies?

Supporting Information Political Quid Pro Quo Agreements: An Experimental Study

Duverger s Hypothesis, the Run-Off Rule, and Electoral Competition

Who Emerges from Smoke-Filled Rooms? Political Parties and Candidate Selection

Prof. Bryan Caplan Econ 812

Who Emerges from Smoke-Filled Rooms? Political Parties and Candidate Selection

Social Polarization and Political Selection in Representative Democracies

Online Appendix 1: Treatment Stimuli

Voting Paradoxes and Group Coherence

Priming Ideology? Electoral Cycles Without Electoral Incentives Among Elite U.S. Judges

Party Labels and Information: The Implications of Contagion in Coelection Environments

MATH4999 Capstone Projects in Mathematics and Economics Topic 3 Voting methods and social choice theory

POLITICAL EQUILIBRIUM SOCIAL SECURITY WITH MIGRATION

A positive correlation between turnout and plurality does not refute the rational voter model

Introduction to Theory of Voting. Chapter 2 of Computational Social Choice by William Zwicker

Sciences Po Grenoble working paper n.15

Women as Policy Makers: Evidence from a Randomized Policy Experiment in India

A Higher Calling: Career Concerns and the Number of Political Parties

Problems with Group Decision Making

Approval Voting and Scoring Rules with Common Values

Homework 6 Answers PS 30 November 2012

Party Responsiveness and Mandate Balancing *

Should We Tax or Cap Political Contributions? A Lobbying Model With Policy Favors and Access

Electing the President. Chapter 12 Mathematical Modeling

University of Toronto Department of Economics. Party formation in single-issue politics [revised]

Answers to Practice Problems. Median voter theorem, supermajority rule, & bicameralism.

Compulsory versus Voluntary Voting Mechanisms: An Experimental Study

Chapter 4: Voting and Social Choice.

THE MEDIAN VOTER THEOREM (ONE DIMENSION)

THE INEVITABILITY OF GERRYMANDERING: WINNERS AND LOSERS UNDER ALTERNATIVE APPROACHES TO REDISTRICTING

Rhetoric in Legislative Bargaining with Asymmetric Information 1

Problems with Group Decision Making

policy-making. footnote We adopt a simple parametric specification which allows us to go between the two polar cases studied in this literature.

A MODEL OF POLITICAL COMPETITION WITH CITIZEN-CANDIDATES. Martin J. Osborne and Al Slivinski. Abstract

David R. M. Thompson, Omer Lev, Kevin Leyton-Brown & Jeffrey S. Rosenschein COMSOC 2012 Kraków, Poland

SENIORITY AND INCUMBENCY IN LEGISLATURES

The Interdependence of Sequential Senate Elections: Evidence from

The Role of the Trade Policy Committee in EU Trade Policy: A Political-Economic Analysis

SPECIALIZED LEARNING AND POLITICAL POLARIZATION

Candidate Citizen Models

Ideological Externalities, Social Pressures, and Political Parties

Campaign finance regulations and policy convergence: The role of interest groups and valence

Game theory and applications: Lecture 12

Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries)

Europe and the US: Preferences for Redistribution

Appendix for: The Electoral Implications. of Coalition Policy-Making

WHEN PARTIES ARE NOT TEAMS: PARTY POSITIONS IN SINGLE MEMBER DISTRICT AND PROPORTIONAL REPRESENTATION SYSTEMS 1

Electoral Engineering: One Man, One Vote Bid

4.1 Efficient Electoral Competition

Single Round vs Runoff Elections under Plurality Rule: A Theoretical Analysis

Supplementary/Online Appendix for The Swing Justice

Web Chapter 3 Political Economy

Electoral Engineering: One Man, One Vote Bid

Immigration and Conflict in Democracies

On the influence of extreme parties in electoral competition with policy-motivated candidates

Voting and Electoral Competition

Sampling Equilibrium, with an Application to Strategic Voting Martin J. Osborne 1 and Ariel Rubinstein 2 September 12th, 2002.

Handcuffs for the Grabbing Hand? Media Capture and Government Accountability by Timothy Besley and Andrea Prat (2006)

DOES GERRYMANDERING VIOLATE THE FOURTEENTH AMENDMENT?: INSIGHT FROM THE MEDIAN VOTER THEOREM

Technical Appendix for Selecting Among Acquitted Defendants Andrew F. Daughety and Jennifer F. Reinganum April 2015

Accountability, Ideology, and Judicial Review

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants

Institutionalization: New Concepts and New Methods. Randolph Stevenson--- Rice University. Keith E. Hamm---Rice University

Helping Friends or Influencing Foes: Electoral and Policy Effects of Campaign Finance Contributions

Transcription:

Ideological Perfectionism on Judicial Panels Daniel L. Chen (ETH) and Moti Michaeli (EUI) and Daniel Spiro (UiO) Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 1 / 46

Behavioral Judging Formation of Normative Commitments Priming Priming Ideology? Electoral Cycles Without Electoral Incentives Among U.S. Judges Gambler s Fallacy Decision-Making Under the Gambler s Fallacy: Evidence From Asylum Courts, Loan Officers, and Baseball Umpires Extraneous Events This Morning s Breakfast, Last Night s Game: Detecting Extraneous Factors in Judging Voice Overtones of Justice: Concealable Characteristics and Perceptions of Voice in the U.S. Supreme Court Peer Effects Is Ideology Infectious? Evidence from Repeated Random Exposure in U.S. Circuit Courts Deontological Motivations - today s paper Measurement of Normative Commitments Social Preferences or Sacred Values? Theory and Evidence of Deontological Motivations A Theory of Experiments: Invariance of Equilibrium to the Strategy Method of Elicitation and Implications for Social Preferences Markets, Morality, and Economic Growth: Does Competition Affect Utilitarian Commitments? Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 2 / 46

Deontological Motivations How do individuals perceive the cost of taking actions they disagree with politically or morally? Economics tends to gravitate towards the assumption that costs be they economic, effort or cognitive are convex. One rationale for this assumption is that it makes theoretical models analytically tractable. Another rationale is that it seems intuitively plausible. However, such intuition has proved fragile following a number of recent experiments even small deviations from convictions are perceived to be very costly, but once a small deviation has been made, further deviations will entail relatively little additional cost. implies individuals tend to give up on their morals if they cannot follow them fully, suggesting a concave cost of deviation. This paper presents a novel and puzzling phenomenon in judicial decisions and shows that concave ideological preferences explains this phenomenon along with a number of related empirical facts. Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 3 / 46

Lab Experiments For instance, individuals with concave moral costs will tend to give up on their morals if they cannot follow them fully. This pattern of behavior has been popularly labeled the what-the-hell-effect (Ariely 2012; Baumeister et al. 1996). The decision whether to lie is often insensitive to the outcome of lying once it it preferred over the outcome of being truthful (Hurkens et al. 2009; Gneezy et al. 2013). Once individuals are induced to cheat, they succumb to full-blown cheating (Gino et al. 2010). In politics it may be more sensible to assume concave preferences. A voter on the far right would be more or less indifferent between two candidates on the left (both are equally bad), but would care greatly about which of the right wing candidates wins (Osbourne 1995). The question remains whether concave preferences have empirically observable implications for important real world decision situations. Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 4 / 46

The Spider Result 0.06 0.05 0.04 0.03 Average Dissent Rate 0.02 0.01 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15-0.01-0.02 Ideology Score rela5ve to Center of Judge Pool Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 5 / 46

Intuition Judges feel bad when signing unfavorable verdicts. They are ideological perfectionists: signing even one unfavorable verdict comes at high cost, signing many is marginally less costly. Not signing (=dissenting) implies a collegial pressure. Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 6 / 46

Intuition The marginal cost of signing unfavorable verdicts falls while the marginal benefit of signing unfavorable verdicts stays high, so you just sign all of others verdicts. Whereas for moderate and centrist judges, the marginal cost of signing unfavorable verdicts remains high while the marginal benefit is low, so there s a corner solution and the # of dissents is determined by the natural normal distribution of judge scores. Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 7 / 46

Circuit Courts 12 Circuit courts decide on appeals from lower courts Three judges are randomly picked to a case Set precedent for future cases Around 20 judges in each circuit, politically appointed by president, for life The opinion (interpretation of the law) is what sets precedent and is a continuous variable. Judges can dissent by not signing opinion and then write motivation why. Circuit Map.ai -- Page 1 3/24/14, 7:56 PM Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 8 / 46

Ideology What role does ideology play in determining whether a judge dissents? Use proxy for ideology by weighing voting behavior of appointing president and voting behavior of home state senators (Judicial Common Space) Yearly data 1950-2007 (Openjurist), 5% sample (1925-2002) (Songer-Auburn) Proxy goes from -1 (leftist/liberal/democrat) to +1 (rightist/conservative/republican) Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 9 / 46

Stylized Fact Dissent is as a non-monotonic function of ideological extremeness: Centrists dissent seldom Moderates dissent often Extremists dissent seldom 0.06 0.05 0.04 0.03 Average Dissent Rate 0.02 0.01 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15-0.01-0.02 Ideology Score rela5ve to Center of Judge Pool Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 10 / 46

The Spider Result 0.035 0.03 0.025 0.02 Average Concurrence Rate 0.015 0.01 0.005 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15-0.005-0.01 Ideology Score rela4ve to Center of Judge Pool Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 11 / 46

How Can the Spider Be Explained? Note: The result is driven by ideological distance between judges, not by the ideology per se. Example: A very liberal judge (-1) will dissent seldom when in circuit of very conservative judges (+1), but dissent often in circuit of moderate liberals (-0.5). This is about interaction between judges with different ideologies. Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 12 / 46

Dissent More When a Judge s Ideology Far From Panel Median Table: Dissents and Concurrences vs. Distance to Center of Judge Panel (1950-2007) Dissents or Concurs Distance to Center of Panel 0.0399*** (0.00580) Circuit Fixed Effects Y Year Fixed Effects Y N 541182 R-sq 0.008 Extremists more often distant to panel center, should dissent more often, yet dissent less according to spider Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 13 / 46

Rough Story Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 14 / 46

Rough Story Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 15 / 46

Rough Story Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 16 / 46

Rough Story Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 17 / 46

Rough Story Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 18 / 46

Rough Story Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 19 / 46

Rough Story Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 20 / 46

Rough Story Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 21 / 46

Main Model Result Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 22 / 46

Further Predictions From Theory Prediction: In all cases v median judge in panel. Prediction: The further a judge is from panel median, the higher the probability (s)he will dissent. Prediction: Extreme judges sign verdicts which are more unfavorable to them than what moderate judges sign. Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 23 / 46

Does the Median Judge Decide? (1) Liberal Verdict Score -0.0915*** (0.0138) Center Judge -0.00492*** (0.00108) Score * Center Judge -0.153*** (0.0278) N 23031 R-sq 0.003 Determine who in each panel has median ideology, and who among other two is closest to median and furthest from median. Use database of handcoded ideology (liberal=+1, conservative=-1) of each opinion. Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 24 / 46

Extreme Judges Sign Verdicts Which Are More Unfavorable? Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 25 / 46

Extreme Judges Sign Verdicts Which Are More Unfavorable? Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 26 / 46

Conclusions Document non-monotonicity of dissents: extreme judges dissent less than others, moderate judges dissent the most Can be explained by model of ideological perfectionism and collegial pressure Test auxiliary model results Judges are sensitive to interaction with judges with distant ideologies But extremist judges get numb and give up on their ideology Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 27 / 46

Thank You Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 29 / 46

Dissent in Polynomial Distance to Expected Center (1) (2) Dissent Concur Distance to Center of Judge Pool 0.0404*** 0.0285*** (0.00756) (0.00570) Distance 2-0.0334*** -0.0313*** (0.0118) (0.00862) Circuit Fixed Effects Y Y Year Fixed Effects Y Y N 10043 10043 R-sq 0.109 0.086 Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 30 / 46

Dissent in Polynomial Distance to Expected Center 0.04 Dissent rate 0.02 0 1 0.5 0 0.5 1 Ideology Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 31 / 46

Distribution of Ideology Scores (1950-2007) Density 0.5 1 1.5 1.5 0.5 1 Ideology Score relative to Center of Judge Pool Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 32 / 46

Distance to Panel Median and Distance to Center of Judge Pool Distance to Center of Panel.1.2.3.4.5 0.2.4.6 Distance to Center of Judge Pool Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 33 / 46

Alternative Explanations Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 34 / 46

Do the results come from preferences? No: result is driven by peer pressure Are extreme judges different? e.g., to signal non-bias No: spider shows up mainly for relative measures of extremeness Do outliers explain dissent (and concurrence) spider? No: would need low dissent rates for outliers, and dissent rate is bounded by zero Convex peer pressure and linear D? Is it mechanical that the presence of extreme judges requires large variance in scores? No: there non-monotonicity in the spider Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 35 / 46

Alternative Explanations Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 35 / 46

Extremists dissent less since they want to hide their private (extremist) type. Judges feel collegial pressure for their private views and not for their behavior i.e. judges try to hide their private preferences from each other. Judges know each other well; still requires a concave D Extremist judges think that if the verdict equals their (extremist) type then nobody will take the verdict seriously anyway it s precedential power will be weak. Requires that the ones who are supposed to cite the verdict have concave costs of deviating from it. If they had convex costs of deviating from a precedent then an extremist would always like extreme verdicts that set precedent. Are moderate and centrist judges who happen to sit in a panel with two extremists being backed up by others on the circuit? Does the peer pressure function increase with how extreme you are? Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 36 / 46

Model Bell-shaped continuous distribution of judge types (t between -1 and +1) Continuum of cases, three judges picked randomly for each case Each judge foresees all cases she will sit in (alt: cases are decided upon simulatenously). For verdict v R, judge feels an outer disutility of O( v t ), O is increasing fn Judge feels an inner disutility D which is increasing in the cumulative unfavorable verdicts s/he has signed (s(v) = 1): D = D( v t v g(v)s(v)dv) For each dissent (s(v) = 0) judge feels collegial pressure W Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 36 / 46

Model Bell-shaped continuous distribution of judge types (t between -1 and +1) Continuum of cases, three judges picked randomly for each case Each judge foresees all cases she will sit in (alt: cases are decided upon simulatenously). For verdict v R, judge feels an outer disutility of O( v t ), O is increasing fn Judge feels an inner disutility D which is increasing in the cumulative unfavorable verdicts s/he has signed (s(v) = 1): D = D( v t v g(v)s(v)dv) For each dissent (s(v) = 0) judge feels collegial pressure W Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 36 / 46

Model Bell-shaped continuous distribution of judge types (t between -1 and +1) Continuum of cases, three judges picked randomly for each case Each judge foresees all cases she will sit in (alt: cases are decided upon simulatenously). For verdict v R, judge feels an outer disutility of O( v t ), O is increasing fn Judge feels an inner disutility D which is increasing in the cumulative unfavorable verdicts s/he has signed (s(v) = 1): D = D( v t v g(v)s(v)dv) For each dissent (s(v) = 0) judge feels collegial pressure W Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 36 / 46

Model Bell-shaped continuous distribution of judge types (t between -1 and +1) Continuum of cases, three judges picked randomly for each case Each judge foresees all cases she will sit in (alt: cases are decided upon simulatenously). For verdict v R, judge feels an outer disutility of O( v t ), O is increasing fn Judge feels an inner disutility D which is increasing in the cumulative unfavorable verdicts s/he has signed (s(v) = 1): D = D( v t v g(v)s(v)dv) For each dissent (s(v) = 0) judge feels collegial pressure W Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 36 / 46

Model Bell-shaped continuous distribution of judge types (t between -1 and +1) Continuum of cases, three judges picked randomly for each case Each judge foresees all cases she will sit in (alt: cases are decided upon simulatenously). For verdict v R, judge feels an outer disutility of O( v t ), O is increasing fn Judge feels an inner disutility D which is increasing in the cumulative unfavorable verdicts s/he has signed (s(v) = 1): D = D( v t v g(v)s(v)dv) For each dissent (s(v) = 0) judge feels collegial pressure W Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 36 / 46

Model Bell-shaped continuous distribution of judge types (t between -1 and +1) Continuum of cases, three judges picked randomly for each case Each judge foresees all cases she will sit in (alt: cases are decided upon simulatenously). For verdict v R, judge feels an outer disutility of O( v t ), O is increasing fn Judge feels an inner disutility D which is increasing in the cumulative unfavorable verdicts s/he has signed (s(v) = 1): D = D( v t v g(v)s(v)dv) For each dissent (s(v) = 0) judge feels collegial pressure W Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 36 / 46

Timing within Case 1 The three judges suggest and vote about verdict. 2 Each judge decides whether to sign or not. 3 Disutility is applied ˆ L = O( v t )g(v t)dv v v ˆ +D( ( t v )g(v)s(v)dv) ˆ +W (1 s(v))g(v t)dv v Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 37 / 46

Voting Procedure and Outcome Each of the three judges suggests a verdict. Condorcet winner determines final verdict v. Since L is increasing in v t : Lemma (prediction): In all cases v = t m median type Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 38 / 46

Voting Procedure and Outcome Each of the three judges suggests a verdict. Condorcet winner determines final verdict v. Since L is increasing in v t : Lemma (prediction): In all cases v = t m median type Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 38 / 46

Voting Procedure and Outcome Each of the three judges suggests a verdict. Condorcet winner determines final verdict v. Since L is increasing in v t : Lemma (prediction): In all cases v = t m median type Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 38 / 46

Voting Procedure and Outcome Each of the three judges suggests a verdict. Condorcet winner determines final verdict v. Since L is increasing in v t : Lemma (prediction): In all cases v = t m median type Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 38 / 46

To Sign or Not to Sign After v has been determined, outer disutility plays no role in decision making. ˆ L = O( v t )g(v t)dv v +D( v t v g(v)s(v)dv) +W v (1 s(v))g(v t)dv Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 39 / 46

To Sign or Not to Sign Problem can be rewritten so: Lemma (prediction): Each judge chooses a cutoff verdict distance, c: if verdict is beyond then dissent, if verdict is closer then sign. Probability of dissent P(t, c) = Pr(v < t c) + Pr(v > t + c) = Pr(t m < t c) + Pr(t m > t + c) For given c, P(t, c) increasing with extremeness t. (For spider we need P(t, c) to decrease(!) to fall for large t.) Hence, necessary condition for P(t, c(t)) to fall in t is for c(t) to increase in t : Lemma (prediction): For spider to appear, necessary that extreme judges sign verdicts which are more unfavorable to them than what moderate judges sign. Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 40 / 46

To Sign or Not to Sign Problem can be rewritten so: Lemma (prediction): Each judge chooses a cutoff verdict distance, c: if verdict is beyond then dissent, if verdict is closer then sign. Probability of dissent P(t, c) = Pr(v < t c) + Pr(v > t + c) = Pr(t m < t c) + Pr(t m > t + c) For given c, P(t, c) increasing with extremeness t. (For spider we need P(t, c) to decrease(!) to fall for large t.) Hence, necessary condition for P(t, c(t)) to fall in t is for c(t) to increase in t : Lemma (prediction): For spider to appear, necessary that extreme judges sign verdicts which are more unfavorable to them than what moderate judges sign. Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 40 / 46

To Sign or Not to Sign Problem can be rewritten so: Lemma (prediction): Each judge chooses a cutoff verdict distance, c: if verdict is beyond then dissent, if verdict is closer then sign. Probability of dissent P(t, c) = Pr(v < t c) + Pr(v > t + c) = Pr(t m < t c) + Pr(t m > t + c) For given c, P(t, c) increasing with extremeness t. (For spider we need P(t, c) to decrease(!) to fall for large t.) Hence, necessary condition for P(t, c(t)) to fall in t is for c(t) to increase in t : Lemma (prediction): For spider to appear, necessary that extreme judges sign verdicts which are more unfavorable to them than what moderate judges sign. Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 40 / 46

To Sign or Not to Sign Problem can be rewritten so: Lemma (prediction): Each judge chooses a cutoff verdict distance, c: if verdict is beyond then dissent, if verdict is closer then sign. Probability of dissent P(t, c) = Pr(v < t c) + Pr(v > t + c) = Pr(t m < t c) + Pr(t m > t + c) For given c, P(t, c) increasing with extremeness t. (For spider we need P(t, c) to decrease(!) to fall for large t.) Hence, necessary condition for P(t, c(t)) to fall in t is for c(t) to increase in t : Lemma (prediction): For spider to appear, necessary that extreme judges sign verdicts which are more unfavorable to them than what moderate judges sign. Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 40 / 46

To Sign or Not to Sign Problem can be rewritten so: Lemma (prediction): Each judge chooses a cutoff verdict distance, c: if verdict is beyond then dissent, if verdict is closer then sign. Probability of dissent P(t, c) = Pr(v < t c) + Pr(v > t + c) = Pr(t m < t c) + Pr(t m > t + c) For given c, P(t, c) increasing with extremeness t. (For spider we need P(t, c) to decrease(!) to fall for large t.) Hence, necessary condition for P(t, c(t)) to fall in t is for c(t) to increase in t : Lemma (prediction): For spider to appear, necessary that extreme judges sign verdicts which are more unfavorable to them than what moderate judges sign. Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 40 / 46

To Sign or Not to Sign Problem can be rewritten so: Lemma (prediction): Each judge chooses a cutoff verdict distance, c: if verdict is beyond then dissent, if verdict is closer then sign. Probability of dissent P(t, c) = Pr(v < t c) + Pr(v > t + c) = Pr(t m < t c) + Pr(t m > t + c) For given c, P(t, c) increasing with extremeness t. (For spider we need P(t, c) to decrease(!) to fall for large t.) Hence, necessary condition for P(t, c(t)) to fall in t is for c(t) to increase in t : Lemma (prediction): For spider to appear, necessary that extreme judges sign verdicts which are more unfavorable to them than what moderate judges sign. Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 40 / 46

What the Spider Needs Lemma: If D is linear or convex then c(t) is (weakly) decreasing in t and hence P(t, c(t)) is increasing in t. Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 41 / 46

What the Spider Needs Lemma: If D is linear or convex then c(t) is weakly decreasing in t and hence P(t, c(t)) is increasing in t. Proposition: A necessary condition for the spider is that D is concave. Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 42 / 46

What the Spider Needs Lemma: If D is linear or convex then c(t) is weakly decreasing in t and hence P(t, c(t)) is increasing in t. Proposition: A necessary condition for the spider is that D is concave. Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 42 / 46

What Suffices for the Spider Suppose D is a step function Then signing any one v t gives same ideological cost as signing many v t. Meanwhile, collegial cost is increasing in dissent. If you sign once, then sign always! If you dissent, then dissent any time t tm. { Pr(t t m ) if t < t cutoff P(t) = 0 if t t cutoff Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 43 / 46

What Suffices for the Spider Suppose D is a step function Then signing any one v t gives same ideological cost as signing many v t. Meanwhile, collegial cost is increasing in dissent. If you sign once, then sign always! If you dissent, then dissent any time t tm. { Pr(t t m ) if t < t cutoff P(t) = 0 if t t cutoff Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 43 / 46

What Suffices for the Spider Suppose D is a step function Then signing any one v t gives same ideological cost as signing many v t. Meanwhile, collegial cost is increasing in dissent. If you sign once, then sign always! If you dissent, then dissent any time t tm. { Pr(t t m ) if t < t cutoff P(t) = 0 if t t cutoff Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 43 / 46

What Suffices for the Spider Suppose D is a step function Then signing any one v t gives same ideological cost as signing many v t. Meanwhile, collegial cost is increasing in dissent. If you sign once, then sign always! If you dissent, then dissent any time t tm. { Pr(t t m ) if t < t cutoff P(t) = 0 if t t cutoff Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 43 / 46

What Suffices for the Spider Suppose D is a step function Then signing any one v t gives same ideological cost as signing many v t. Meanwhile, collegial cost is increasing in dissent. If you sign once, then sign always! If you dissent, then dissent any time t tm. { Pr(t t m ) if t < t cutoff P(t) = 0 if t t cutoff Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 43 / 46

The Fixed Cost Spider Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 44 / 46

Empirical Prediction: Are Extreme Judges, More Than Others, Signing Verdicts Which Are More Unfavorable? Prob(dissent or concur) = a + b 1 abs(t) + b 2 abs(t) 2 +b 3 abs(t t m ) + b 4 abs(t t m )abs(t) +b 5 abs(t t m )abs(t) 2 Cutoff verdict increasing when judges become extreme: b 5 < 0 b 3, b 4, b 5 together such that Pr(dissent) increases in distance from t to panel median: judges dissent against unfavorable verdicts Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 45 / 46

Empirical Prediction: Are Extreme Judges, More Than Others, Signing Verdicts Which Are More Unfavorable? Prob(dissent or concur) = a + b 1 abs(t) + b 2 abs(t) 2 +b 3 abs(t t m ) + b 4 abs(t t m )abs(t) +b 5 abs(t t m )abs(t) 2 Cutoff verdict increasing when judges become extreme: b 5 < 0 b 3, b 4, b 5 together such that Pr(dissent) increases in distance from t to panel median: judges dissent against unfavorable verdicts Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 45 / 46

Empirical Prediction: Are Extreme Judges, More Than Others, Signing Verdicts Which Are More Unfavorable? Prob(dissent or concur) = a + b 1 abs(t) + b 2 abs(t) 2 +b 3 abs(t t m ) + b 4 abs(t t m )abs(t) +b 5 abs(t t m )abs(t) 2 Cutoff verdict increasing when judges become extreme: b 5 < 0 b 3, b 4, b 5 together such that Pr(dissent) increases in distance from t to panel median: judges dissent against unfavorable verdicts Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 45 / 46

Empirical Prediction: Are Extreme Judges, More Than Others, Signing Verdicts Which Are More Unfavorable? Dissents and Concurrences vs. Distance to Median of Judge Panel (1950-2007) (1) Dissents or Concurs Distance to Center of Judge Pool 0.0180 (0.0225) Distance to Center of Judge Pool 2-0.0403 (0.0389) Distance to Median of Panel -0.00335 (0.00892) Distance to Median of Panel * 0.244*** Distance to Center of Judge Pool (0.0572) Distance to Median of Panel * -0.287** Distance to Center of Judge Pool 2 (0.103) Circuit Fixed Effects Y Year Fixed Effects Y N 509022 R-sq 0.008 Chen/Michaeli/Spiro Ideological Perfectionism 46 / 46