Human Capital Formation, International Labor Mobility and the Optimal Design of. Educational Grants. Bernard Franck* and. Robert F. Owen** August 2012

Similar documents
Human Capital Formation, International Labor Mobility and the Optimal Design of Educational Grants

Brain drain and Human Capital Formation in Developing Countries. Are there Really Winners?

International Remittances and Brain Drain in Ghana

Tilburg University. Can a brain drain be good for growth? Mountford, A.W. Publication date: Link to publication

Migration and Education Decisions in a Dynamic General Equilibrium Framework

Unemployment and the Immigration Surplus

Remittances and the Brain Drain: Evidence from Microdata for Sub-Saharan Africa

Innovation and Intellectual Property Rights in a. Product-cycle Model of Skills Accumulation

SKILLED MIGRATION: WHEN SHOULD A GOVERNMENT RESTRICT MIGRATION OF SKILLED WORKERS?* Gabriel Romero

The Analytics of the Wage Effect of Immigration. George J. Borjas Harvard University September 2009

INTERNATIONAL LABOR STANDARDS AND THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF CHILD-LABOR REGULATION

Immigration and Unemployment of Skilled and Unskilled Labor

Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

Brain Gain: Claims about Its Size and Impact on Welfare and Growth Are Greatly Exaggerated

Riccardo Faini (Università di Roma Tor Vergata, IZA and CEPR)

involving 58,000 foreig n students in the U.S. and 11,000 American students $1.0 billion. Third, the role of foreigners in the American economics

A Comparison of Capital Region Residents on Selected Aspects of Their Wellbeing

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY. Executive Summary

Tax Competition and Migration: The Race-to-the-Bottom Hypothesis Revisited

Migration and Employment Interactions in a Crisis Context

THE BRAIN DRAIN + Frédéric Docquier a and Hillel Rapoport b. FNRS and IRES, Université Catholique de Louvain

Skilled Worker Migration and Trade: Inequality and Welfare

Distributive justice: Rawlsian and utilitarian rules

Rural-urban Migration and Minimum Wage A Case Study in China

Migration Options for Skilled Labor and Optimal Investment in Human Capital

The Transfer of the Remittance Fee from the Migrant to the Household

AND WEST UKRAINE (N=173)

Cumulative Causation at Work: Intergenerational Transfers and Social Capital in a Spatially Varied Economy

The Impact of Migration on Children Left Behind in Developing Countries

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES

Schooling, Nation Building, and Industrialization

ONLINE APPENDIX: Why Do Voters Dismantle Checks and Balances? Extensions and Robustness

Toil and Tolerance: A Tale of Illegal Migration

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE LABOR MARKET EFFECTS OF REDUCING THE NUMBER OF ILLEGAL IMMIGRANTS. Andri Chassamboulli Giovanni Peri

The Political Economy of State-Owned Enterprises. Carlos Seiglie, Rutgers University, N.J. and Luis Locay, University of Miami. FL.

Preferential votes and minority representation in open list proportional representation systems

Globalization, Child Labour, and Adult Unemployment

The new economics of the brain drain

Illegal Immigration, Immigration Quotas, and Employer Sanctions. Akira Shimada Faculty of Economics, Nagasaki University

Chapter 4 Specific Factors and Income Distribution

Do Disappointing Pay Raises Lower Productivity? Final-Offer Arbitration and the Performance of New Jersey Police Officers *

Gender Gap of Immigrant Groups in the United States

WORLD ECONOMICS. The New Economics of the Brain Drain. Volume 6 Number 2 April - June By ODED STARK. Reprinted from

Jens Hainmueller Massachusetts Institute of Technology Michael J. Hiscox Harvard University. First version: July 2008 This version: December 2009

Private versus Social Costs in Bringing Suit

Educated Migrants: Is There Brain Waste?

The political economy of public sector reforms: Redistributive promises, and transfers to special interests

Illegal Migration and Policy Enforcement

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

Public Education in an Integrated Europe: Studying to Migrate and Teaching to Stay?

A Theoretical Approach: Examining the Educated Unemployment Rate and International Skilled Migration of Developing Countries.

A Three-Party Game of Institutional Resilience versus Transition A Model and Comparative History of China-Japan Revisited

Commentary on Session IV

Labour market trends and prospects for economic competitiveness of Lithuania

Measuring International Skilled Migration: New Estimates Controlling for Age of Entry

The Poor in the Indian Labour Force in the 1990s. Working Paper No. 128

English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap

5. Destination Consumption

Immigration and Poverty in the United States

Brain Drain and Emigration: How Do They Affect Source Countries?

The Impact of Foreign Workers on the Labour Market of Cyprus

The (Self-)Selection of International Migrants Reconsidered: Theory and New Evidence

Brain Drain, Fiscal Competition, and Public Education Expenditure

Chapter 10 Worker Mobility: Migration, Immigration, and Turnover

The Provision of Public Goods Under Alternative. Electoral Incentives

THE EFFECT OF OFFER-OF-SETTLEMENT RULES ON THE TERMS OF SETTLEMENT

Planning versus Free Choice in Scientific Research

Volume Author/Editor: Jagdish N. Bhagwati, editor. Volume URL:

International Mobility of the Highly-Skilled, Endogenous R&D, and Public Infrastructure Investment

Macroeconomic Implications of Shifts in the Relative Demand for Skills

Cyclical Upgrading of Labor and Unemployment Dierences Across Skill Groups

Does Temporary Migration Have to Be Permanent? March Mohammad Amin and Aaditya Mattoo

Immigration Policy In The OECD: Why So Different?

The Brain Drain: Curse or Boon?

What Makes Brain Drain More Likely? Evidence from Sub-Saharan Africa

The Labor Market Effects of Reducing Undocumented Immigrants

Quantitative Analysis of Migration and Development in South Asia

Remittances and Savings from International Migration:

Debapriya Bhattacharya Executive Director, CPD. Mustafizur Rahman Research Director, CPD. Ananya Raihan Research Fellow, CPD

1. Introduction. Michael Finus

Does High Skilled Immigration Harm Low Skilled Employment and Overall Income?

Notes on exam in International Economics, 16 January, Answer the following five questions in a short and concise fashion: (5 points each)

IDE DISCUSSION PAPER No. 517

Berkeley Review of Latin American Studies, Fall 2013

Citation 經營と經濟, vol.90(4), pp.1-25; Issue Date Right.

Economics Honors Exam 2009 Solutions: Macroeconomics, Questions 6-7

International Trade Theory College of International Studies University of Tsukuba Hisahiro Naito

Reducing income inequality by economics growth in Georgia

The Integer Arithmetic of Legislative Dynamics

Social Polarization and Political Selection in Representative Democracies

The Determinants and the Selection. of Mexico-US Migrations

WHO MIGRATES? SELECTIVITY IN MIGRATION

International migration and human capital formation. Abstract. Faculté des Sciences Economiques, Rabat, Morocco and Conseils Eco, Toulouse, France

1 Electoral Competition under Certainty

Discussion Paper Series

Emigration and source countries; Brain drain and brain gain; Remittances.

School of Economics Shandong University Jinan, China Pr JOSSELIN March 2010

DETERMINANTS OF IMMIGRANTS EARNINGS IN THE ITALIAN LABOUR MARKET: THE ROLE OF HUMAN CAPITAL AND COUNTRY OF ORIGIN

2 Political-Economic Equilibrium Direct Democracy

Differences in remittances from US and Spanish migrants in Colombia. Abstract

Transcription:

Human Capital Formation, International Laor Moility and the Optimal Design of Educational Grants y Bernard Franck* and Roert F. Owen** August 01 (suject to revision) Astract A two-country, two-period model of international migration highlights microeconomic foundations for examining the interrelation etween rain drain, rain gain and the location of human capital formation, at home or aroad. Ex ante choices regarding where to study depend on relative qualities of university systems, individuals ailities, sunk educational investment costs, government grants, and expected employment prospects in oth countries. The analysis underscores an inherently widerange of conceivale positive or negative effects on domestic net welfare. Such welfare implications depend critically on the foregoing factors, as well as the optimal design of educational grant schemes, given eventual informational imperfections regarding individuals capailities. JEL classification codes: F, F15, D8, H5 Key words: human capital formation, rain gain, rain drain, international migration, sunk costs, educational grants, asymmetric information Acknowledgement: The insightful suggestions of Sven Arndt and Vincent Merlin are appreciated. *Faculty of Economics and Business Administration, University of Caen and CREM (CNRS), Esplanade de la Paix, 1403 Caen Cedex, France. Telephone numers: 33-31565695 (direct) and 33-3156557. Fax numer: 33-31936194. E-mail: ernard.franck@unicaen.fr **LEMNA Research Center, Nantes School of Economics and Management - I.A.E., University of Nantes, Chemin de la Censive du Tertre, B. P. 531, 443 Nantes Cedex 3, Telephone Numers: 33--40141761 (direct) and 33--40141717. Fax numer: 33-1- 3919096. E-mail: roertfowen@gmail.com 1

Section I: Introduction Spawned, notaly, y the contriution of Bhagwati and Hamada (1974), there has now een considerale research concern regarding the potentially adverse impact, for a home country s growth and welfare, of the migration of skilled workers. Nonetheless, early investigations also recognized potentially advantageous effects for source countries, due to possile remittances and the eventual return of migrants with enhanced skills due to foreign jo training. More recently, what Schiff (006) has termed the new rain drain literature, which was initiated y Mountford (1997) and Stark, Helmenstein and Prskawetz (1997), has identified another potentially important source of rain gain, which is independent from return migration. Specifically, although migration can generate a loss of domestic talent, it can also prompt an upsurge in the overall educational level of a home country, as a result of higher propensities to invest in human capital. Attractive foreign laour market conditions offer heightened incentives for domestic workers to strive to attain higher qualification levels, whether or not they ultimately find jos aroad, therey fostering, ceteris parius, increases in average productivity levels at home. While certain existing approaches to modelling rain drain and rain gain effects entail macroeconomic frameworks with representative agents, as in Vidal (1998), many also consider microeconomic decisions at the level of individual agents, including choices regarding optimal investment levels in education. Stark, Helmenstein and Prskawetz(1997) have proposed a framework, which demonstrates how, given the opportunity to migrate, choices regarding educational attainment will determine an individual s wage on the foreign laour market. In other modelling frameworks, as proposed y Stark, Helmenstein, and Prskawetz (1998), the potential migrant takes into account a proaility of finding a jo aroad, which is identical for all individuals, or, as in Stark (004), constrained y a minimum threshold level of qualification. Mountford (1997) and Beine, Docquier, and Rapoport (001, 008)) propose models where an individual s decision is of a inary form whether to undertake education or not, while the proaility of finding foreign employment is exogenous. This does not allow a role for differences in individuals characteristics, so that migrants are randomly selected. In contrast, Chiswick (1999) provides for selfselection y migrants, since, assuming two categories of individuals, the rate of return to migration is greater for those with high-aility, relative to loweraility persons. Nonetheless, the literature has principally focused on the links etween incentives to invest in human capital at home and susequent migration flows. The evaluation of rain drain/rain gain effects is made in the literature y assessing the impact of migration on a variety of specific

economic ojectives, which, however, do not include an explicit social welfare per se. Notaly, migration is shown to influence the growth rate of the home economy, as in Beine, Docquier, and Rapoport (001), the average educational level, as highlighted y Stark et al. (1997, 1998) and Lien and Wang (005), average productivity in Mountford (1997), as well as the wages of non-migrants in Stark (004). Although there is now a urgeoning numer of empirical studies, assessing different dimensions of the potential impact of rain drain and gain, there remains a lack of consensus regarding the size of conjectured positive effects of migration upon levels of education, welfare and/or growth. Notaly, Beine, Docquier, and Rapoport (001, 008) find that the proportion of migrants must e low for such effects to e apparent. According to Schiff (006), preliminary studies y the World Bank show no positive impact, while Groizard and Llull (006) indicate a similar finding. A critique y Rosenzweig (006), which faults existing approaches to the analysis of rain drain and gain in two crucial respects, is particularly germane for motivating the modelling framework proposed in the current research. First, he contends that the potential impact of the risk of emigrating for domestically-educated tertiary educated person(s) is de facto quite minimal. Second, Rosenzweig goes on to suggest that the literature ignores the endogeneity of the emigration proaility, while arguing that, in fact, the choice of the location of tertiary education significantly affects the proaility that the person can emigrate. 1 (p. -3) Critically, existing analytical research has paid relatively little attention to the question of whether distinctive rain drain and gain effects may arise, depending on the extent to which educational investments take place either in home and/or host countries. Nonetheless, the policy stakes of the international moility of high-skilled workers are increasingly recognized as a source of sustantial policy concern. The research in the current paper proposes a two-country model, which offers a new theoretical paradigm for understanding the nexus etween locational choices regarding human capital formation, international laour market conditions, and distinctive categories of rain drain and rain gain effects. The analysis underscores an inherently wide-range of conceivale positive or negative effects on a home country s net welfare. More specifically, distinctive elements of the proposed conceptual framework include the following: 1 While the analytical framework proposed y Rosenzweig does not allow for differences in individual ailities, his empirical findings are consistent with a numer of the modeling assumptions which are susequently invoked here. Notaly, he reports evidence that students are motivated y foreign studies in order to otain employment in a host country and that quality differences in university systems also appear to trigger the decision to study aroad. See, for example, Leipziger (008) and Solimano (008). 3

1) Individuals, from a home country, choose whether to undertake studies aroad, which entail an incrementally higher sunk cost relative to studying at home. While foreign studies are understood to generate greater improvements in laour-market productivity, as compared with levels achievale through domestic human capital formation, the realized extent of the gains depends on an individual student s underlying ailities. If susequently offered foreign employment, students opt to stay aroad ecause of higher wages, therey generating rain drain. However, if individuals are unale to find suitale foreign employment, they still enjoy heightened productivity levels and wages, when returning home, as compared to not having studied aroad. This generates rain gain. 3 ) When modelling an individual s choice of whether to study aroad or stay at home, a crucial variale is the proaility of eing hired in the foreign laour market. Contrarily to other models in which this proaility is exogenous and identical for all graduates, it is assumed here to e a function of each individual s expected level of qualification or, alternatively, productivity level, which, in turn, depends on aility. As a consequence, migrants are favouraly self-selected to use the terminology of Chiswick(1999). 3) The criterion chosen to assess rain drain/rain gain effects is the net impact on the home national welfare. This is represented, in a static framework, in terms of the change in domestic value-added resulting from foreign studies and eventual migration. This welfare calculation depends, in turn, on the associated consequences for the country s level of productivity, as well as the additional costs of investment in education aroad. It is assumed there are no remittances. 4 4) Since foreign studies enhance productivity and therey potentially lead to eneficial welfare effects, pulic authorities in the home country may seek, under certain conditions, to encourage foreign studies y susidizing the candidates through alternative grant schemes, suject to a given overall udgetary constraint. Welfare implications of three conceivale grant policies are compared under alternative assumptions regarding the extent of a government s knowledge of students underlying ailities. Under a first, uniform susidy scheme, grants are offered to an aritrary suset of students, assuming that the government cannot oserve underlying ailities. The associated net 3 There are certain similarities etween the proposed framework and the model of Kwok and Leland (198), ut their scenario does not include a rain gain effect. 4 It is relatively straightforward to modify the proposed modeling framework, in order to allow for remittances, which would partially offset the negative welfare effects of rain drain. While such an extension potentially impacts specific quantitative results, it does not modify the essential qualitative insights summarized in susequent propositions. 4

welfare effects are then compared with those of two alternative schemes, merit and selective, which invoke the alternative assumption that the authorities can actually distinguish etween students capailities. Whereas in the former case grants are only offered to the rightest students, in the latter scenario financing is restricted to a su-set of students, corresponding to a particular talent-pool. The rest of this paper is structured as follows. In Section the asic modelling analysis starts with a su-model of ex ante individual choice, regarding whether to undertake human capital formation at home or aroad. An individual s underlying aility determines known productivity gains from studying aroad, along with expected proailities of susequently otaining foreign market employment at higher wages. The evaluation of the ex post net impact of rain drain and rain gain depends on the size of the su-populations of individuals who migrate permanently, as compared with those who return home with enhanced productivity, relative to wholly domestic trained workers. Section 3 presents some comparative static results, relating to the welfare effects of changing certain model parameters, which are essential for estalishing susequent propositions. In Section 4 the relative welfare implications of alternative educational grant schemes, susidizing studies aroad, are considered. The analysis highlights a critical role for alternative assumptions regarding the extent of a pulic authority s knowledge of underlying ailities, which are assumed known y the individuals themselves. A concluding section riefly summarizes certain salient findings, while identifying a numer of directions for further inquiry. Section II: Basic Modelling Framework II. A. Su-Model of Individual Investment in Human Capital Formation and International Migration The initial focus is on the human capital investment decisions, in a first period, y heterogeneous individuals, who decide whether to pursue further studies at home, or aroad. Both their specific ailities and where they undertake further studies determine prospects for achieving enhanced productivity at the end of the period. Within the two-country setting, individuals, who initially choose to study at home, know that their jo prospects, in a second period, will e confined to a lower-wage domestic market. In contrast, the pursuit of foreign studies offers prospects of higher productivity gains due to a conjectured superior quality of the foreign 5

educational system. Individuals face a critical aritrage, since there is an ex ante trade-off etween improved employment prospects and higher sunk costs. While the pursuit of foreign studies offers higher salaries, individuals are initially uncertain regarding whether, or not, they will e susequently hired aroad. More specifically, out of an overall population of N individuals in the domestic country, N 0 represents the numer of domestic individuals who remain at home for oth their education and work, while N* is the total numer of persons who choose to undertake foreign studies and, susequently, work either at home, or aroad. Thus, there are two distinct su-populations of N*, corresponding to the phenomena of rain gain and rain drain. In particular, N 1 * designates the numer of domestic individuals who chose to get educated aroad and susequently work in the foreign country, while N 1 corresponds to the numer of domestic individuals who are educated aroad, ut then return home to work. In sum, whereas higher values of N 1 *generate greater rain drain, increases in N 1 results in more rain gain. The overall domestic population of N individuals are understood to differ in terms of their innate intellectual and work capacities, which for the kth individual, can e denoted as c k. Whereas these heterogeneous individuals know their own ailities, alternative hypotheses will e susequently considered regarding the extent of the pulic authority s information, aout these capacities. The attainale productivity levels for students depend not only on their underlying ailities, the quality of the initial educational system in the home country, designated as q 1, ut also on where further educational investments are to e undertaken. More specifically, it is hypothesized that the quality of the domestic higher educational system, Q 1, is inferior to that offered in the foreign country, Q. Hence, there is an educational production function that determines how investments of fixed amounts of time in a particular educational system map individuals capacities into their effective qualifications or productivity levels, e k, such that e k =f(c k, q j,q j ), where j=1,. 5 This functional relation results in a range of attainale productivity levels, measured on a scale etween, e 0 and e. For susequent simplicity, a value of e 0 is used as a numeraire to designate a unique level of productivity for all of the N 0 domestically educated workers, regardless of their inherent capacities. However, workers trained aroad, N 1 * or N 1, enjoy higher final productivity 5 More generally, the value of the kth individual s human capital investments depends on the amount of time spent on education, the quality of university educational systems and his/her aility. While the analysis here only provides for individuals undertaking higher educational studies in a single period and in only one country, it could e extended to allow for students spending different periods of time, either at home or aroad. The returns from educational investments would then, depend on the specific stage of university, or earlier, studies, as well as country-specific differences in educational quality, which could e highly variale according to educational levels. 6

levels. Individuals productivity levels are distriuted, according to their innate ailities, on an interval from e 1 to e,as represented y a density function, h(e). While offering the prospect of higher productivity gains, the decision to undertake foreign studies is understood to entail higher educational costs, I*, compared to the costs of pursuing further education in the home country, I 0. Hence, in the asence of educational grants, students will e willing to incur this difference etween the foreign and domestic educational costs, designated as i = I* - I 0, provided two conditions are met. First, the expected higher wage returns arising from enhanced productivity gains must offset the net cost differential for paying for higher quality studies aroad. Second, financial markets are assumed to e perfect. Accordingly, students can readily orrow against their expected future earnings, in order to finance the immediate sunk costs of educational investments, inclusive of financing charges. Individuals ex ante willingness to incur sunk costs of educational investments is clearly impacted y anticipations regarding the laour market conditions they face after graduating - oth at home and aroad. The latter are reflected oth y hiring prospects and y oth wage differentials etween the two countries. In the proposed framework, individuals have een educated aroad have the ex post option of seeking employment aroad at a higher wage, than in their home market. For the overall population of N* workers, who are educated aroad, each individual, designated y the suscript k, faces a proaility, p k, of finding qualified employment aroad. This proaility plays a crucial role in the analysis, as it delineates rain drain from rain gain effects. Notaly, two extreme cases, where p k equals either 1, or 0, correspond, respectively, to pure rain drain or rain gain effects. For more intermediate value of p k oth the phenomena of rain drain and rain gain will arise, respectively, in the proportions p k and 1 p k across the overall population N*. Nonetheless, in the proposed model, the proaility of finding employment aroad varies across the heterogeneous population of individuals, since it depends on their expected levels of productivity, which, in turn, are related to underlying ailities and educational choices. More specifically, each of the p k values is taken to depend linearly on the level of the effective qualifications realized y the kth individual, e k, relative to a threshold value, E 1, reflecting a minimum standard in the foreign laour market, and negatively on the range of skill requirements, E - E 1, such that: 7

(1.) p k (ek p(ek ) (E E ) 1 E ) 1 Figure 1 offers a representative illustration of the assumed distriution of effective qualification levels for domestic individuals, in relation to the skill requirements of the foreign laour market. Intermediate values for the parameters E 1 and E are assumed, where these threshold values, respectively, preclude or guarantee foreign market employment. Thus, in the proposed model, each foreign-trained, domestic-origin, student faces a non-zero proaility of finding employment aroad. A previously indicated simplification is that individuals, who chose to remain at home for their education, are unale to work aroad. 6 Figure 1 The Assumed Structure of Skill Levels Attainale at Home or Aroad, Relative to Foreign Laour Market Requirements e 0 E 1 e 1 e E The parameters, E 1 and E, can e understood to reflect foreign laour market conditions, as well as educational and employment policies. For example, employment standards aroad can e influenced y the overall quality of the foreign educational system (including that of pre-university studies), as well as y technology-driven, laour-demand requirements. Different cominations of these parameter values can also e interpreted to represent alternative immigration policies, since higher values could correspond to more restricted laour market access, while depending on the skill intensities of availale jos in the foreign country. Moreover, lower values of E could, ceteris parius, represent a situation of relative shortages for specific categories of highly skilled workers. Finally, lower (higher) values of oth of these foreign market parameters can e interpreted as corresponding to alternative foreign immigration policies, facilitating (hindering) the immigration of foreign skilled workers. Following their studies, foreign-trained domestic students have an incentive to seek employment aroad due to the higher foreign salaries, w*, for skilled jos, whereas returning students can only earn a lower 6 Eventual rationale for this assumption include an inadequate relative quality, or high-degree of specificity, of the domestic educational system, positive social network effects on employment arising from foreign studies, and/or restrictive immigration policies, favouring students trained aroad. 8

reservation wage in their home country, equal to w 1. 7 For tractaility, oth of these salaries are assumed to e unique values, which are independent of students effective qualification levels achieved through their pursuit of studies aroad. Furthermore, it is assumed that the reservation wage, facing returning students, is higher than oth the remuneration offered to wholly domestically trained workers, w 0, and the foreign wage, which they can earn in less skilled jos aroad, w 0 *. Within this proposed framework, students, who are unsuccessful in finding appropriate skilled work in the foreign country, will return home. 8 While the wage rates are taken to e exogenous, the susequent analysis will consider comparative static changes in their values, reflecting the relative attractiveness of laour market conditions internationally. Figure summarizes, then, the overall international structure of wages, depending on jo locations and educational ackgrounds Figure The Structure of International Wages According to Jo Location and Educational Background w 0 w 0 * w 1 w* The ex ante, optimal educational choice, for the representative kth student involves a trade-off, which can e formulated in terms of an aritrage condition. Specifically, the net returns from studying and working at home, with lower overall effective qualifications, need to e compared to expected higher wage earnings, arising from enhanced productivity due to foreign studies, aleit at a greater investment cost. The expected wage remuneration involves a proaility-weighted average of wages for more skilled workers in the foreign and domestic markets. Accordingly, a representative student will decide to study in the foreign country if: (.) pkw * (1 pk )w1 I* w 0 I0 7 An exchange rate of unity is assumed. 8 Of course, other factors, such as personal and family considerations could offset the locational incentives of these ex post wage differentials etween the two countries. Such additional factors can e modeled in terms of complementary or sustitutale, agent-specific assets and associated sunk costs. It can e noted that, ceteris parius, if students have a preference to return home, there will e an increase in rain gain effects, relative to those identified in the susequent analysis. 9

Hence, the kth individual will decide to study aroad if his/her individual proaility of eing hired aroad, p k is higher than a critical proaility value, p. This proaility is assumed to depend on a student s, potentially private, information regarding his/her future productivity level, e k. More specifically, the interrelation etween this critical proaility value, p, and the prevailing international wage rates and educational costs are given y: (3.) i-(w1-w 0) i-(w1-w 0) p if [0,1] w*-w1 w*-w1 i-(w1-w 0) p = 0 if < 0, that is if i < w w*-w 1 w 0 1 i-(w1-w 0) p = 1 if > 1,that is if i > w* - w w*-w 0 1 From (1.), it follows that the productivity level corresponding to p is: e~ (E E )p E 1 1 However, ~ e does not necessarily elong to the segment of productivity levels attainale from foreign studies, [e 1, e ], so that the actual productivity threshold is e such that (4.) e = e~ (E E )p E 1 1 if e~ [e1, e ], e = e 1 if ~ e < e 1, e = e if ~ e > e. The foregoing specifications permit a characterization of the distinctive populations of students, depending on oth ex ante educational choices and the ex post employment prospects. In particular, out of the overall population of N students, the numer of students choosing to remain e at home is given y N N h(e) de 0, whereas the complementary set of individuals studying aroad amount to e 1 e N - N0 N h(e) de. The latter group can e su-divided into two sets of individuals, corresponding to rain drain and rain gain effects, represented, respectively, y N 1 * = e N e e N p(e)h(e) de and N 1 = 1 p(e) h(e)de. Whereas the foregoing analysis assumes exogeneous e wages, an analogous decomposition of the overall population of students also applies where salaries depend positively on productivity levels. Provided the salary differential etween the two markets, w*(e) w 1 (e), is a nondecreasing function of productivity, the expected wage returns from opting to study aroad remain an increasing function of e. Consequently, there also e 10

exists a threshold level e determining whether, or not, individuals will undertake foreign studies. As a result, the susequently reported findings in this section are roust to such an alternative formulation. II. B. Production and Welfare in the Home Country Production, or value-added at home is taken to e characterized y a linear function, reflecting a proportional relation to productivity. Thus, if individuals were not ale to study aroad, national output would e Y 0 = e 0 N, which constitutes an essential enchmark under educational autarchy, since workers are only trained domestically. The contriution to national production generated y the foreign-educated individuals returning home e e 1 corresponds, then, to Y 1 = N p(e) h(e)de, which constitutes the incremental increase in national income resulting from rain gain. e A distinctive feature of the proposed analysis is the explicit consideration of how rain drain and rain gain effects, linked to international human capital formation, impact domestic social welfare, relative to the level under autarchy, Y 0. In this perspective, changes in welfare generated y international educational and employment moility can e viewed in terms of a cost-enefit analysis relating to changes in national aggregate productivity and the net costs of educational expenditures orne y the home country. Nonetheless, such a focus will astract from potential distriutional issues concerning relative returns in terms of wages, firms profits, as well as transfers etween the domestic government and the private sector. The net return in productivity generated y a student returning home amounts to e e 0, while the net cost of that person s education equals I*- c. The latter variale reflects an opportunity cost, corresponding to the social cost of educating an individual domestically. For the case of a student remaining aroad, the corresponding effects involve a loss of national productivity, e 0, minus a gain in terms of an opportunity cost, c, since there is no need to incur domestic educational costs. In this regard, it should e noted that future salary gains are used to pay off the costs of a foreign education, I*, so that there is no associated social cost at home. In sum, the net cost-enefit evaluation for the rain gain resulting from a representative student returning home amounts to e e 0 (I* - c), whereas that for an individual entailing a rain drain effect equals e 0 c. 9 9 The educational costs for society of training students, prior to their deciding to study aroad and, susequently, working permanently there, could also, argualy, e considered to negatively impact domestic social welfare. There would then e an additional term, negatively impacting domestic welfare, as a result of rain drain. On the 11

More explicitly, the overall change in domestic welfare is determined y the rain drain and gain effects corresponding to individuals who study aroad, whose productivity levels are comprised etween e and e. This amounts to a variation in social welfare equal to: W = e N [1 p(e)][e e (I* c)] - p(e)(e 0 0 e This can e expressed equivalently as : e c) h(e) de W = N [1 p(e)](e I*) (e c) h(e) de 0 e As a simplification, the susequent analysis will assume an uniform distriution of attainale productivity levels, comprised etween lower and higher ounds of e 1 and e. In light of such a specification, the overall net change in welfare ecomes: W = e N e Φ(e) Φ(e) (e) de = N e 1 e e e1 Here, the function constitutes the overall net welfare effect for each attainale productivity level. When the overall social opportunity cost for a student who ultimately works aroad is identified as = e 0 - c, the expression for then equals: (e) = E - e (e I*) E - E 1 δ, while in equation (6.) represents the primitive of the function. As shown y equation (6.), the incremental change in domestic welfare is a function of all the parameters of the model. To summarize, it depends on: _ e 0 : the productivity of less-skilled domestically-trained workers; _ e 1 and e : the two extreme values defining the range of enhanced productivity levels for foreign-educated workers; _ E 1 and E : parameters reflecting foreign market skill requirements and laour market access conditions, which impact the proaility of finding work aroad; _ e : the threshold value of productivity, which decides whether an individual chooses to study aroad, which, in turn, is impacted y among other factors, the wages of skilled workers employed aroad, other hand, the proposed specification of the social welfare function does not allow for the positive impact of remittances, which would depend on the value of w*, along with different propensities characterizing individuals decisions to transfer funds ack home. 1

w*, skilled workers employed at home, w 1, and unskilled workers at home,w 0 ; 10 _ I*: the cost of foreign studies; _ I 0 and c: the cost of studies at home per student, orne, respectively, y each individual and y society. The expression for the primitive function in equation (6.), which critically defines the extent of the change in domestic welfare, is of the third degree in e. The underlying reason for such a functional form is the second degree form for the integrand, (e), in equation (6.), which represents the expected increase in net welfare for a representative individual. This expression involves a trade-off etween the expected increase in productivity realized through rain gain, e(1-p(e)) e 0, and the expected net social cost of educating a student aroad, (1-p(e))I* c. Since the former quadratic term in e assumes low values for either relatively low or high productivity values, the values of the integrand are initially negative, then positive (for sufficiently low i) and finally negative, as representative productivity levels for different individuals increase. As illustrated in Figure 3, the general form of the primitive function may first show a minimum, for e = ê 1, and then a maximum for e = ê. Of course, these extrema exist if and only if the equation (e) =0 admits real roots, which corresponds to the following condition: (7.) ( ) ( ). When I* and, which jointly determine the social cost of a foreign education, are too high, is always a decreasing of e. Consequently, the change in domestic welfare, W, is always negative, so that the rain drain effect dominates that of rain gain. The value for which has a minimum, ê 1, is relevant only if the latter is greater than E 1. Calculations show that the associated condition is simply: (8.) E 1 < I*+. In the rest of the paper, it is assumed that conditions (7.) and (8.) are always satisfied. It should also e noted that the integrand has a maximum. Specifically, the function takes on low values when e is itself low, since in 10 As shown y considering equations 3 and 4. 13

that case the individual productivity gains are too weak to compensate for the cost of foreign studies. For high values of e, when few students come ack home, there is a loss of productivity for society as a whole, so the value of is also low. Its maximum occurs for e = (E + I*)/, which corresponds to an inflection point for the curve representing function such that the marginal increase in social welfare associated with a marginal decrease of the productivity threshold is the highest. Figure 3 Representation of the Functional Form for which Determines the Overall Change in Domestic Welfare 3.5 3.5 1.5 1 P 0.5 0-0.5 ê 1 ê 0 1 3 4 5 6 7 8 9-1 -1.5 Section III: An Analysis of the Effects on Economic Welfare of Changes in Key Model Parameters III.1 The Interrelation etween Threshold Productivity Levels and Changes in Welfare 14

The initial focus here is on the welfare implications of the critical value of e, which reflects the threshold productivity level for which a representative individual chooses to study aroad. The value of e in relation toê is potentially of key importance. Note again that e is a function of the critical threshold proaility, p, triggering foreign study, as well as of the foreign laour market productivity requirements, E 1 and E ; whileê is a function of E 1, E, and the social opportunity cost of foreign studies, C, 1 where: e (E E )p E 1 1 and ê E E 4(E E )C 1. Hence, it ê E E 4(E E )C E 1 1 1 follows that e > ê for p > p lim, where p lim =. E E E E 1 1 The value of p lim is always inferior to one, and while it could e negative, this would mean that E 1 > ê. However, this corresponds to a relatively uninteresting case, where domestic welfare always declines, as a result no individuals study aroad. For more relevant scenarios, there is an actual proaility threshold eyond which e > ê. It can also easily e seen that when e increases and e > ê 1, W has a maximum for e = ê 1.Thus, if initially e < ê 1, a marginal increase in e promotes welfare. However, if e > ê 1, an increase in e reduces the numer of people who study aroad, therey reducing welfare. An examination of Figure 3 and a comparison of the values taken y the function for e and e, leads then to the following: Proposition 1 For intermediate values of the threshold productivity value, e, determining whether individuals will study aroad, and of the upper limit on the associated level of enhanced productivity, e, specifically elonging to the interval [ ê 1, ê ], the change in welfare resulting from studying aroad, W, is positive. Hence, the welfare improvement from rain gain dominates the loss due to rain drain. In contrast, there are three cases where foreign studies generate a loss of welfare. Notaly, a) when e and e are oth very low, the return to foreign education, in terms of increased productivity, is weak and does not compensate for its social costs, even if many individuals study aroad and return home to work, e ; ) when e and e are oth very high, few individuals leave to study aroad, ut most of these will readily find a jo aroad, resulting in a dominance of the rain drain effect; c) when e is low and e is high, there is an accumulation of the foregoing effects a) and ). Notaly, many individuals study aroad, therey generating high additional educational investment costs, ut 15

only those with lower-productivity gains return home. In sum, the welfare implications of comparative static changes in productivity levels, e and e, are inherently amiguous. III. The Configuration of Wages and Associated Welfare Effects The influence of wages on domestic welfare works through changes in the critical values for p and e. As can e expected, higher wages for domestically trained workers create, ceteris parius, a disincentive to studying aroad, so when w 0 increases, oth p and e increase. However, when the potential jo market returns to foreign studies w* or w 1 increase, the incentives to studying aroad are increased, so that p and e are lowered. The associated consequences for domestic welfare stem from the preceding analysis of the influence of e. Specifically, if e is not very low (inferior to ê 1 ), an increase (decrease) in wages for foreign-trained (domestictrained) workers, decreases (increases) e, therey enhancing welfare. III.3 Welfare Implications of Changes in the Relative Productivity Gains from Education at Home and Aroad It is also straightforward to see that a heightened efficiency for domestically-trained workers, e 0, y increasing the opportunity cost of undertaking foreign studies, generates a negative influence on the net impact on welfare of rain drain and rain gain. In contrast, an increase in the lower limit of the enhanced efficiency level attained via foreign studies, e 1, raises the returns to a foreign education, and induces a larger proportion of the population to study aroad. The effect of a variation in e is more complex to assess. By widening the span of productivity values, an increase of e, ceteris parius, has a negative influence upon W. If e >ê, (e ) also decreases, so that the overall effect is also negative. However, if e elongs to the interval [ê 1, ê ], (e ) increases and the net effect is indeterminate. More specifically, the formula for the derivative of W is: (9.) d de W N = (e e 1) { ( e ) [ (e ) (e e 1 ) (e )]}. It can e seen that, if e < ê, so that W may e positive, then the foregoing expression is negative for e = ê. Consequently, the change in the domestic country s welfare has a maximum for some value of e (also inferior to ê ). In light of the foregoing analysis, the following holds: 16

Proposition The change in the domestic country s welfare, W, is an increasing function of the level of e, the maximal level of enhanced productivity achievale y undertaking studies aroad, provided e remains under a critical level. Beyond this threshold, W decreases with e. Thus, too much of an improvement inhuman capital, or, alternatively, relative excellence in the foreign institutions, generates a dominant rain drain. The associated critical value of e is increasing with the threshold productivity level determining whether students go aroad, e, and decreasing with the lower limit of the value of enhanced productivity, e 1. Finally, if oth e 1 and e increase with a constant span etween the two values, W has a maximum for e = ê. In that case, from the perspective of domestic welfare, there is also an optimal level of relative efficiency in the foreign educative system. Any increase of efficiency aove this level will diminish home national welfare. III.4 Changes in the Sunk Cost Differential for Studying Aroad As the additional sunk costs associated with foreign studies, i, increase, the threshold proaility of finding a jo aroad increases, as does the corresponding threshold productivity level, e. Furthermore, if this increase in i comes from an increase in I*, the integrand function decreases. As a consequence, so long as e [ê 1, ê ], an increase in the incremental costs of studies aroad, i, reduces the home country s welfare. In contrast, for low values of e ( e < ê 1 ), an increase in i could possily e eneficial. In such a scenario there is initially an excessive flight of students aroad, since, for a representative student, the productivity gains from a foreign education are high, whereas the additional costs, i, are low. III.5 Alternative Immigrant Employment Policies in the Foreign Country The relative ease of access to the foreign laour market is captured here y alternative values for the laour market requirement parameters, E 1 and E. Ceteris parius, for higher values of either parameter it is more difficult for a domestic-origin, ut foreign-trained, jo-searcher with a given qualification level to e employed aroad. More specifically, when either E 1, or E increase, e increases, ut p(e k ) decreases for any value of e k. Crucially, 17

there are two offsetting effects. On the one hand, fewer individuals leave to ecome educated aroad, ut, on the other hand, a greater fraction of graduated students come ack home. Thus, the total pool of foreign trained students from the domestic country is reduced. This means that the overall exposure of the domestic country to welfare changes, arising from either rain drain or rain gain, decreases. However, the relative proportion of foreign-trained students generating a rain gain increases as a result of the more restrictive jo filtering environment in the foreign country. Consequently, the net effect on domestic welfare is potentially amiguous. As demonstrated in Appendix 1, the following summary conclusion applies: Proposition 3 Restrictions limiting entry y foreign-trained students to the host country s laour market increase home national welfare, provided the following conditions hold: a. the cost differential for undertaking foreign studies is high;. the maximum achievale productivity level, e, is relatively low; and c. relatively few individuals undertake studies aroad (i.e. p is near 1). In contrast, if the foregoing conditions are not satisfied, then less favourale foreign laour market conditions result in a negative impact on domestic welfare. Section IV: A Comparative Analysis of the Domestic Welfare Implications of Alternative Educational Grant Schemes The focus in this section is on the optimal policy design, for a home country, of educational grants, aimed at facilitating foreign study for specific categories of students. Since alternative susidy programs change the incentives to study aroad, they potentially impact the alance etween rain drain and rain gain, which, in turn, determines the net changes in domestic welfare. Initially, it will e that the government has perfect information regarding students ailities. In this scenario the government can discriminate ex ante etween individuals when allocating grants according to three different grant schemes. 11 In the first of these, termed unconditional 11 For simplicity grants, the analysis here will focus on grants entailing uniform payments for all recipients, rather than discriminating etween individuals in terms of the proposed value of the grants. 18

grants, grants are awarded without any constraints on students regarding either financial repayments, or susequent employment choices. Under the second scheme, laeled as optional return, any grant recipient, who susequently decides to work in the foreign country, must pay ack the full value of the grant. Finally, under a third scheme, identified as compulsory return, students commit to returning home to work, even if they could otherwise have een employed aroad at a higher wage. IV.1 Unconditional Grants Since the government is assumed to e omniscient, having full information regarding the underlying aility of all students, grants will e allocated as a function of a candidate s aility, or, equivalently, in light of the expected gain in an individual s productivity. Of course, individuals whose productivity is superior to the standard threshold will never e grant eneficiaries, since there is no need for any additional financial incentive to undertake foreign studies. Under this system, all individuals whose productivity levels are comprised etween a designated level,, and, may e candidates for a grant. The lower productivity limit for the grant recipients,, is endogenously determined y the per capita value of the foreign educational susidies, S. This amount depends, in turn, on the government s overall educational udget constraint. Nonetheless, it is not necessarily optimal to give a grant to the rightest students (whose productivity is relatively close to the threshold value of ), since such students are less likely to return home to work. Hence, grants will e given, a priori, to students whose productivity elongs to a certain segment of productivity values, [ ], with. The new productivity threshold,, is such that: (10) ( ) ( ) where ( ) indicates the threshold proaility for grant eneficiaries. Then, there is a standard interrelation etween such a proaility value and the associated threshold productivity level,, such that: =(E E 1 ) + E 1. It is straightforward to see that, so that, ( ) ( ) ( ) 19

As a result, for any given proposed values for the individual foreign study grants, as well as an overall udget for the government grant program, the suset of students actually going aroad is shown in Figure 4. Figure 4 Structure of the population for unconditional grants (1) () (3) (4) e e 1 e zone 1 corresponds to individuals for whom the proposed grant is not sufficient to convince them to go aroad zone corresponds to grant recipients who undertake foreign studies due to the grant zone 3 corresponds to individuals who do not receive a grant and study at home zone 4 corresponds to individuals who while not receiving any grant, still undertake foreign studies Now let F e the gloal udget allowed for grants. The numer of eneficiaries will e, where, so that the udget constraint may e written (1),, or, equivalently, in light of equation (13.)( )( ) where k = Under this scheme, the increase of welfare generated y allowing additional individuals to study aroad is: ( ) The maximum value of W is reached for values of and, such that ê 1 and ê. Otherwise, were to e inferior to ê 1, it would e possile to increase y increasing, when is constant, while still reducing 0

the educational udgetary expenditures. Analogously, if were to e superior to ê, it would e possile to increase y decreasing with constant, while reducing again udgetary expenditures. Nonetheless, a maximum value for with = ê may not e feasile since, y construction, it must e the case that. If it is assumed that e ê, then can reach ê, which is its unconstrained optimal value. Provided the level of availale funds permits such a value for and the optimum will then e = ê and = ê 1, that is if ( ) ( ). If the availale pulic funds are too low, the udgetary constraint will e inding and the optimum value of will e inferior to. Yet, in any case the optimal value of will e strictly inferior to. Instead, if it is assumed that < ê, the constraint may ecome inding. The optimum then corresponds to = and = conditional on the level of funds eing large enough, given y the constraint ( ). However, it is shown in Appendix that, provided that the udgetary constraint is inding, there exists a threshold productivity value,, and associated intervals of values for and F, where, respectively, [ ] and [ ], such that has a maximum for some value of, where the corresponding is inferior to. When these conditions are not satisfied, is always an increasing function of.since is always inferior or equal to, the optimum is associated with the maximum value for, which corresponds to =, and is given y. This means that the segment of productivity values [ ] is fully covered y the allocation of the grants, while the value of depends on the level of the availale funds. The foregoing analysis can e summarized, as follows: Proposition 4 When a government has full knowledge regarding students ailities, a scheme of unconditional grants, which targets individuals who are not among the most qualified (relative to ), can e optimal under specific conditions. In particular, the welfare effects of such unrestricted grants are preferale when either of the following comination of productivity and udgetary conditions apply: i., or ii. [ ] and [ ]. Thus, the foregoing proposition highlights an apparent paradox in the funding of unconditional grants for studies aroad, which are aimed at promoting national welfare. Specifically, in the presence of potential rain 1

drain due to more attractive working conditions aroad, it may e preferale to offer grants to somewhat less qualified individuals in an interval of potential productivity levels lying etween and.the existence of such threshold levels is analogous to a phenomenon often encountered in the optimal design of pulic susidies, which can entail oundary conditions for susets of the population, ranked in terms of revenue. IV. Conditional Grants As previously indicated, two systems of conditional grants can e envisaged, corresponding to the case of optional or compulsory return to work in the home country. A. The Case of Optional Return In this scenario (designated as OR), a student, after graduation, will either find a jo aroad and reimurse the educational grant money, or decide to return home. Under such a scheme, the net expected income of a student who receives a conditional grant, ut with an optional return, amounting to, is: ( )[ ] [ ( )] ( ) ( ) [ ( )] [ ( )] In light of the last term in this expression, it follows that the net expected grain for such a grant recipient is always superior to the expected income without a grant, regardless of a student s productivity. As a consequence, the overall pool of grant eneficiaries will e defined y a productivity threshold level,, which is inferior to the standard threshold, and where and are, respectively, defined y: (15.) ( ) [ ( )] ( ) ( )[ ] [ ( )] ( ) By comparing equations (15.) and (16.), it can e seen that: ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) Note that or always hold. As a consequence, if a student who has accepted the grant is proposed a foreign jo, he will always accept it rather than return home. The grant will e

given to students whose productivity levels are comprised etween and. Since for each productivity value e, only a proportion of ( ) students come ack, the udgetary constraint is given y: where ( ) ( ) [ ( )] By comining (17.), (18.) and (19.), this constraint ecomes: ( ) The change in social welfare corresponds then to: ( ) ( ) B. The Case of Compulsory Return Here, a grant recipient is oliged, at the end of his/her studies, to come ack to the home laor market. Two conditions must e met for a representative student k to accept such a grant, which will amount to. First, the earnings from returning to work at home, following studies aroad, must e superior to those associated with staying at home to oth study and work. Hence, this condition corresponds to: ( ) Second, the expected net returns must also e superior to those for an individual, who chooses to study aroad without accepting such a grant with a compulsory return home: ( ) [ ( )] This condition leads to, where the threshold is an increasing function of. It follows that, when ( ), which is the minimum value, such that the proposed grant would e accepted. For higher values of, the upper productivity limit will e superior to. Certain of these higher-aility students may opt to accept the grant, despite the correspondent inding commitment, rather than assume 3