Pirates. Peter T. Leeson

Similar documents
DISARMAMENT AND INTERNATIONAL SECURITY COMMITTEE (DISEC) Director: Guerlain Ulysse MIMUN 2011

Poking Hobbes in the Eye: A Plea for Mechanism in Anarchist History

How much benevolence is benevolent enough?

New institutional economic theories of non-profits and cooperatives: a critique from an evolutionary perspective

G7 Foreign Ministers Declaration on Maritime Security Lübeck, 15 April 2015

MINISTER OF NATIONAL SECURITY P.O. BOX N NASSAU BAHAMAS DEMOCRACY 31 ST SMALL BRANCHES CONFERENCE PLENARY 2 DISCUSSION PAPER BY

CNO Africa Advisory Conference. Dr. Eric V. Thompson CAPT Rick Williams, USN. Summary Report

Operation Sophia Before and After UN Security Council Resolution No 2240 (2015) Mireia Estrada-Cañamares *

!,!,!,!, !,!, !,!, !,!, !,!, !,!,!,!,!,!, !,!, !,!, KEY FINDINGS:

Review of Virgil Henry Storr, Enterprising Slaves & Master Pirates: Understanding Economic Life in the Bahamas, New York: Peter Lang, 2004, 147pp.

American Revolution : A Message From Below

British imperial expansion and the transformation of violence at sea, : introduction

The Growth of the Chinese Military

Police and the Community. Wesley G. Skogan and Megan Alderden

The EU fight against piracy in the Horn of Africa

Prospects for the Code of Conduct in the South China Sea after Hague decision

CRIME AND PUBLIC POLICY Follow-up Report 1 John Jay Poll November-December 2007

Non-State Actors in Maritime Security

Criminal Constitutions *

GOALS 9 ISSUE AREAS. page 7. page 5. page 6. page 8. page 1 page 2. page 9

Pacem in Maribus XXXIII. Beijing, China 3 to 4 September Statement by Ms. Patricia O Brien. Under-Secretary-General for Legal affairs

Updated: 13 February 2012 MEDIA INFORMATION

Chapter 9, Section 3 A Time of Conflict

India and China at Sea: Competition for Naval Dominance in the Indian Ocean

Do Now. Who do you think has more power a representative/senator, the president, or a Supreme Court justice? Why?

HERE WAS BURIED THOMAS JEFFERSON AUTHOR OF THE DECLARATION OF AMERICAN INDEPENDENCE OF THE STATUTE OF VIRGINIA FOR RELIGIOUS FREEDOM AND FATHER OF

Chinese Reactions to Japan s Defence White Paper

Port of Mombasa: Comparative Position

EU-India relations post-lisbon: cooperation in a changing world New Delhi, 23 June 2010

Minnesota Transportation Museum

PERTH COUNTER-PIRACY CONFERENCE JULY 2012 CHAIRMAN S FINAL STATEMENT OF THE MEETING

Conference of the German Federal Foreign Office, the Robert Bosch Stiftung and the Friedrich Ebert Stiftung

10238/17 FP/aga 1 DGC 2B

proof A Common Answer to Disparate Questions Envisioning Caribbean Federation in the Late Nineteenth and Early Twentieth Century

The Educational and Labour Market Outcomes of the Children of Immigrants: A Success to be Preserved

In U.S. security policy, as would be expected, adversaries pose the

Public Policy in an Entrepreneurial Economy

LESSONS IDENTIFIED FROM SOMALI PIRACY

Invited Reaction Putting Theories of the Firm in Their Place: A Supplemental Digest of the New Institutional Economics

This document is downloaded from DR-NTU, Nanyang Technological University Library, Singapore.

: Organizational Economics (CentER) Fall Jens Prüfer Office: K 311,

Definition of key terms

Law & Economics Center at George Mason University School of Law Invited Attendee 16 th Law Institute for Economics Professors (July 2012)

THE CONCEPT OF EQUALITY IN INDIAN LAW

p o l i c y q & a An Australian Perspective on U.S. Rebalancing toward Asia

OCCASIONAL PAPER 1 A CODE OF CONDUCT FOR THE INDIAN OCEAN. 2 nd January, 2018 CENTRE FOR THE LAW OF THE SEA PATHFINDER FOUNDATION

Can the COC Establish a Framework for a Cooperative Mechanism in the South China Sea? Robert Beckman

Introduction TONIO ANDRADE

Intelligence brief 19 March 2014

4 Rebuilding a World Economy: The Post-war Era

The Interception of Vessels on the High Seas

Economic Assistance to Russia: Ineffectual, Politicized, and Corrupt?

Grade Strand Substrand Standard Code Benchmark Critical Research Question(s) 1. Democratic government depends on informed and engaged

Explaining differences in access to home computers and the Internet: A comparison of Latino groups to other ethnic and racial groups

DISSENTING OPINION OF JUDGES PARK, NELSON, CHANDRASEKHARA RAO, VUKAS AND NDIAYE

Be afraid of the Chinese bearing gifts

Third Session ROYAL MOROCCAN NAVY: NEW PERSPECTIVES FOR BETTER MARITIME SECURITY AWARENESS" Captain Abdelkrim MAALOUF

Citizens in a Global Society From Skepticism to Engagement The Kettering Foundation and US-China Relations Kettering s Multinational Research

Fight against piracy

Differences in Media Framing of Otto Warmbier

INTERNATIONAL TRIBUNAL FOR THE LAW OF THE SEA

Episteme: A Journal of Social Epistemology, Volume 5, Issue 1, 2008, pp. 1-4 (Article) DOI: /epi

Frances Kunreuther. To be clear about what I mean by this, I plan to cover four areas:

Chapter 7 5/7/09. Problem 7. Social Inequality. The Cultural Construction of Social Hierarchy

PC.DEL/754/17 8 June 2017

Illinois Redistricting Collaborative Talking Points Feb. Update

Miracle Obeta, M.A. Miami University, Oxford, Ohio. Reviewed

CSCAP WORKSHOP ON UNCLOS AND MARITIME SECURITY IN EAST ASIA MANILA, MAY 27, 2014

The EU in the Asia-Pacific: Crisis Management Roles?

THE ADMIRALTY (JURISDICTION AND SETTLEMENT OF MARITIME CLAIMS) ACT, 2017 ARRANGEMENT OF SECTIONS

Original language: English CoP17 Inf. 94 (English only / Únicamente en inglés / Seulement en anglais)

Preliminary results. Fieldwork: June 2008 Report: June

Malavika Nair. Gokhale Institute of Politics and Economics, Pune, India M.A. Economics

I. Background: An Exclusive Economic Zone (EEZ) is an area of water a certain distance off the coast where countries have sovereign rights to

Coalition Building in ASEAN. Orlando S. Mercado, PhD

SOURCES OF GOVERNMENTAL FAILURE AND IMPERFECT INFORMATION AS POLITICAL FAILURE

China's Strategy. Jan. 11, Originally produced Jan. 4, 2016 for Mauldin Economics, LLC. By George Friedman

Future EU Trade Policy: Achieving Europe's Strategic Goals

From Leadership among Nations to Leadership among Peoples

JUDGE JOSE LUIS JESUS, President of the International Tribunal for the Law of the Sea

The Provision of Public Goods, and the Matter of the Revelation of True Preferences: Two Views

Internal migration within China

IS CHINA S SOFT POWER DOMINATING SOUTHEAST ASIA? VIEWS FROM THE CITIZENS

The changing role of central banking opening speech by Klaas Knot for symposium in celebration of DNB s bicentennial, 24 april 2014

South China Sea: Realpolitik Trumps International Law

Frequently Asked Questions & Answers: Waiver Cases

ENFORCEABILITY AND THE RESOLUTION OF INTERNATIONAL JURISDICTIONAL CONFLICTS: COMMENTS ON ABBOTT, ATWOOD, AND ORDOVER

A VERY ELUSIVE TREASURE San Jose`s Shipwreck Judicial Development By: Juan Carlos Uribe and Jaime Escobar

Legal Change: Integrating Selective Litigation, Judicial Preferences, and Precedent

Origin, Persistence and Institutional Change. Lecture 10 based on Acemoglu s Lionel Robins Lecture at LSE

America from Washington to Madison by James Folta

ISAS Brief. China-India Defence Diplomacy: Weaving a New Sense of Stability. P S Suryanarayana 1. No September 2012

Mini-case study: The impact of culture in medical tourism

Carl Mosk Economics 306, Spring International Economics [CRN: 23311] Course Outline and Reading List

Countering offences committed at sea through criminal justice mechanisms: Interplay between existing international instruments

Corruption's Effect on Socioeconomic Factors

Harry Ridgewell: So how have islands in the South Pacific been affected by rising sea levels in the last 10 years?

Basic Maritime Zones. Scope. Maritime Zones. Internal Waters (UNCLOS Art. 8) Territorial Sea and Contiguous Zone

Interview with Philippe Kirsch, President of the International Criminal Court *

The Virginia House of Burgesses (1619)

Transcription:

Rev Austrian Econ (2010) 23:315 319 DOI 10.1007/s11138-010-0116-2 Pirates Peter T. Leeson Published online: 23 June 2010 # Springer Science+Business Media, LLC 2010 Abstract In my recent book, The Invisible Hook: The Hidden Economics of Pirates (Princeton University Press, 2009), I use basic economic theory to analyze late seventeenth- and early-eighteenth-century pirates. Bylund, Carden, North, and Storr raise important questions about, and offer important challenges to, some of the particular ways in which I do so. I offer a few reactions to each of their papers. Keywords Pirates. Organized crime JEL codes K42. N80 1 Introduction I am very grateful to Per Bylund, Art Carden, Charles North, and Virgil Storr for their thought-provoking papers discussing my recent book, The Invisible Hook: The Hidden Economics of Pirates (Princeton University Press, 2009). I am especially grateful to Carden who arranged for this symposium and the papers that comprise it to be presented in a session at the Southern Economic Association. My goal in The Invisible Hook was to apply rational choice theory to pirates and, in doing so, to shed light on their unusual, entertaining, and sometimes shocking practices. I would like to interpret the fact that all the papers in this symposium discuss pirates as rational decision makers as a sign of success. None of the contributors object to my basic, overarching argument: pirates were economic actors. Of course, all of them are economists. So this may not be saying much. My goal in this article is to offer a few reactions to each of the contributors' papers on my book. These papers accept that we can and should analyze pirates using economic theory. But they raise important questions about, and offer important P. T. Leeson (*) Department of Economics, George Mason University, MSN 3G4, Fairfax, VA 22030, USA e-mail: pleeson@gmu.edu

316 P.T. Leeson challenges to, some of the particular ways in which I use that theory to understand pirates in The Invisible Hook. 2 Firms, societies, or something else? Storr criticizes me for depicting pirate crews as societies. A society, he notes, does not have a telos. It has many. In contrast, pirate crewmembers were bound together in the pursuit of a single goal: illicit profit. Bylund criticizes me for the opposite sin: depicting pirate crews as firms. A firm, he notes, is more than just a collection of individuals pursuing profit. A firm involves authority relations (a la Coase), residual claimant managers (a la Alchian and Demsetz), or centralized asset control rights (a la Grossman, Hart, and Moore). Pirate crews do not fit well into any of these boxes. Both contributors put their finger on a key difficulty of talking about pirate crews: are they societies, firms, or something else? In The Invisible Hook I talk about pirate crews as societies and firms. The reason for this is simple: they were both. Storr is quite right that pirate crews had a unitary, profit-making purpose. They are firm-like in important respects. Bylund is quite right that pirate crews do not fit well into existing theories of the firm and had governance arrangements foreign to traditional firms. They are society-like in important respects. Criminality accounts for pirate crews' dual nature. It accounts for the societylike elements of pirate firms and the firm-like elements of pirate societies. Pirate crews organized team production for the purpose of profit. There is something definitely firm-like about this. However, pirate firms' employees equally owned them and earned equal incomes features that do not fit well into traditional theories of the firm. As my book points out, pirate crews flat, sharebased pay and ownership structure partly reflected pirates' need to find selfenforcing solutions to inter-temporal conflicts of interest in an environment in which they could not rely on government. This is an example of pirate criminality making pirate firms look more like what Bylund calls cooperatives and less like the traditional, legitimate firms that existing theories of the firm are concerned with. I am fine with calling pirate crews cooperatives provided that we recognize that pirate cooperatives organized team production for the purpose or making profit i. e., as long as we consider a cooperative a variety of firm rather than a separate category of economic organization. I do not care much what we call pirate crews. But if we want to understand them, we cannot ignore their fundamentally firm-like features. Neither can we ignore pirate crews' fundamentally society-like features, as Storr would have us do. These crews exhibited important firm-like features. But they are not reducible to firms. Since pirate crews were criminal, they required encompassing rules of order that go well beyond the rules traditional firms create. Besides requiring rules about economic relations, such as pay, work duties, and so on, pirate crews required rules relating to theft and violence. They also required judicial institutions to enforce these rules. Pirate crews developed both.

Pirates 317 Legitimate firms do not have these institutions of encompassing order because they do not need them. They can rely on government for this purpose. In this sense pirate firms are fundamentally different from ordinary firms. They are also different from ordinary firms in that, unlike employees in pirate firms, employees in ordinary firms do not eat all their meals together, live and sleep together for months on end, and interact socially (almost) exclusively with one another. These features of pirate crews suggest that they were much more than just firms. In important respects they were societies. Pirate crews' society-like features are as fundamental for understanding them as their firm-like ones. 3 Pirates and property rights North's paper asks about the emergence of property rights in pirate crews. He points to the potential importance of compactness individuals' geographic and/or social closeness in facilitating pirates' property rights arrangements. The issue of compactness is closely connected to a broader theme in economics that tends to portray the political economic situations that individuals confront as becoming easier the smaller the relevant population becomes, the closer community members are to one another physically, and the more socially homogenous community members are. This theme appears in various forms in the literature on self-governance, for example in discussions about reputation's ability to secure cooperation. It also appears in the literature in development, for example in discussions about ethnolinguistic fractionalization. Two items should be noted about pirate crew compactness. First, I am not sure that pirate crews were compact, as North claims. It is true that compared to modern, legitimate societies, pirate crews were small and that pirate crewmembers had common backgrounds as sailors most from the merchant marine, others from naval employment. On the other hand, compared to contemporary merchant crews, pirate crews were enormous and pirate crewmembers were nationally and racially diverse. So I am not sure whether pirate crews were compact or to whom or what we are supposed be comparing them to adjudge their compactness. Second, even if we could be sure that pirate crews were compact, I do not think we can conclude from this observation what economists normally conclude after identifying a community's compactness, which is that, precisely because of that compactness, the community's political economic problems are comparatively easy ones for community members to solve. Pirate crews' most notable and important feature made pirates' political economic problem situation much harder than the one confronted in non-pirate societies, not easier: pirates were lying, murderous, thieves. Not only were pirates unable to rely on government to help them solve the political economic problems they confronted. Those problems took on new and more challenging dimensions in light of the fact that they involved persons who had demonstrated a willingness to thumb their noses at laws prohibiting violence and plunder if they could profit from it indeed, persons who had chosen to make a living by doing so. As Carden notes, it is precisely this feature of pirate crews that makes the fact that pirates managed to solve their political economic problems so remarkable. Whether

318 P.T. Leeson pirate crews were compact or not, the fact that pirates were pirates means their social problem was a worst-case one for political economic order, not a bestcase one, as the compactness view might suggest. This implies that we should be more impressed with pirate governance, not less. 4 Toward a piratical research agenda Carden identifies several strands of research building on ideas I present in The Invisible Hook that future work might explore. Among the most promising of these is that which would investigate the relationship between seventeenth- and eighteenth-century piracy and rent seeking. There are at least two aspects of this relationship worth exploring. First, as Carden indicates, the golden age of piracy was also the golden age of European mercantilism. This helped fuel piracy, for instance, by creating a profitable smuggling network, which pirates, especially in the seventeenth century, dabbled in. Second, European mercantilism created a situation in which colonial governors in North America and pirates were able to develop profitable relationships the former providing protection to pirates, the latter providing the colonies with difficult-toobtain goods plundered from Moorish vessels and specie that was in short supply. In some colonies, pirates became quasi-celebrities. Locals were grateful for the much sought-after goods and specie that pirates brought. This created a rather unusual dynamic between pirates, politicians, and citizens. Carden's paper touches on another topic worth exploring: the ninteenth-century pirates of the South China coast. In contrast to the Caribbean pirates, who were but a few thousand sea bandits strong and who primarily earned their income by seaborne plunder, the pirates of the South China coast were many tens of thousands sea bandits strong and primarily earned their income by protecting/extorting land dwellers in Chinese coastal communities. These differences contributed to the very different organizational structures Chinese pirates exhibited compared to their Caribbean brethren. The former were organized hierarchically. As The Invisible Hook describes, the latter were organized flatly. A close examination and comparison of Chinese pirates vis-à-vis their Caribbean counterparts could shed much-needed light on the theory of organization, especially as it relates to criminals. I hope to investigate this topic myself in the near future. Carden's comments sparked my thinking about another area that may also be worth investigating: What did pirates' landed pirate communities look like compared to their floating ones? The Invisible Hook considers only the latter. But pirates had important bases in Nassau in the Bahamas and off Madagascar in the Indian Ocean. How did pirates organize on these land bases? Did their democratic arrangements carry over? What did property rights look like in landed pirate communities? Were there pirate codes that governed pirates at these bases? If so, what differences did they display from the codes that pirate crews used to govern their lives at sea? The historical material relating to pirate land bases is thin thinner than it is for pirate crews at sea. But making progress on the foregoing questions could bear important fruit for our understanding of criminal organization, self-governance, and the economics of pirates.

Pirates 319 5 Conclusion Many thanks again to each of this symposium's contributors for taking the time to read my book and offering their thoughts about the tensions, unresolved questions, and areas of future inquiry it contains. I am truly flattered. I benefited greatly from reading their papers and from the opportunity to think about the issues they raise. If I had the chance to write The Invisible Hook again, these issues are ones I would want to explore. On the other hand, the contributors' comments and suggestions might be more profitably explored in a sequel. If Pirates of the Caribbean can have one, why can't I?