China has been the focus of much attention in the

Similar documents
The Chinese Economy. Elliott Parker, Ph.D. Professor of Economics University of Nevada, Reno

Lecture 1 Introduction to the Chinese Society

WEEK 1 - Lecture Introduction

China s Response to the Global Slowdown: The Best Macro is Good Micro

11/7/2011. Section 1: Answering the Three Economic Questions. Section 2: The Free Market

The role of the private sector in generating new investments, employment and financing for development

China s New Political Economy

POLI 12D: International Relations Sections 1, 6

Political Economy of. Post-Communism

Lecture 3 THE CHINESE ECONOMY

Trans-Pacific Trade and Investment Relations Region Is Key Driver of Global Economic Growth

Economic Development and Transition

Speech on East Asia Conference

Asia Pacific Region 15/09/2015. Learning Objectives. Dynamic Growth in the Asia Pacific Region. Chapter 11

Chapter 18 Development and Globalization

A STATISTICAL MEASUREMENT OF HONG KONG S ECONOMIC IMPACT ON CHINA

CHAPTER 34 - EAST ASIA: THE RECENT DECADES

Teacher Overview Objectives: Deng Xiaoping, The Four Modernizations and Tiananmen Square Protests

Rural Labor Force Emigration on the Impact. and Effect of Macro-Economy in China

Overview The Dualistic System Urbanization Rural-Urban Migration Consequences of Urban-Rural Divide Conclusions

Issue Brief for Congress Received through the CRS Web

China s Economic Rise: History, Trends, Challenges, and Implications for the United States

Chapter 11. Trade Policy in Developing Countries

China s Economic Rise: History, Trends, Challenges, and Implications for the United States

Some Possible Lessons for Japan from China's Economic Reforms

The Role of the State in the Process of Institutional Evolvement in Agricultural Land after the Founding of PRC

HOW ECONOMIES GROW AND DEVELOP Macroeconomics In Context (Goodwin, et al.)

Vietnam s Current Development Policies: An Overview

Since the Vietnam War ended in 1975, the

TRADE IN THE GLOBAL ECONOMY

Technology Hygiene Highly efficient land use Efficient premodern agriculture. As a result, China s population reached 450 million by 1949.

Industrialization, Innovation and Industrial Policy

Chapter 10 Trade Policy in Developing Countries

China s Economic Rise: History, Trends, Challenges, and Implications for the United States

International Business & Economics Research Journal November 2013 Volume 12, Number 11

Support Materials. GCE Economics H061/H461: Exemplar Materials. AS/A Level Economics

Chapter Organization. Introduction. Introduction. Import-Substituting Industrialization. Import-Substituting Industrialization

America in the Global Economy

Issue Brief for Congress Received through the CRS Web

October 2006 APB Globalization: Benefits and Costs

CRS Issue Brief for Congress

History route 2 Higher level and standard level Paper 1 communism in crisis

China s meteoric rise over the past half century is one of the most striking examples of the impact of opening an economy up to global markets.

WORLD ECONOMIC EXPANSION in the first half of the 1960's has

PROGRAM ON HOUSING AND URBAN POLICY

Development Strategy. for. Myanmar

China s Economic Conditions

Chapter 10: Long-run Economic Growth: Sources and Policies

Foreign Trade of China

China s Economic Reform

An Overview of the Chinese Economy Foundation Part: Macro-economy of the Mainland

Can Japan Take Standpoint Promoting Establishment of Common Currency in East Asia?

The Comparative Advantage of Nations: Shifting Trends and Policy Implications

VIETNAM FOCUS. The Next Growth Story In Asia?

Report on Progress of Economic and Social Rights in China

The Change of Employment Structure in China's Urban Areas

Contemporary Human Geography, 2e. Chapter 9. Development. Lectures. Karl Byrand, University of Wisconsin-Sheboygan Pearson Education, Inc.

Has Globalization Helped or Hindered Economic Development? (EA)

Introduction to World Trade. Economia Internacional I International Trade theory August 15 th, Lecture 1

9.1 Human Development Index Development improving the material conditions diffusion of knowledge and technology Measure by HDI

CRS Report for Congress

6. China s economic transformation 1

Markscheme May 2015 History route 2 Higher level and standard level Paper 1 communism in crisis

The Development of FTA Rules of Origin Functions

Chapter 5: Internationalization & Industrialization

DEVELOPMENT AID IN NORTHEAST ASIA

China s Reform and Opening-up

Social fairness and justice in the perspective of modernization

The Nanning-Singapore Economic Corridor:

CRS Report for Congress

4 Rebuilding a World Economy: The Post-war Era

GLOBALIZATION S CHALLENGES FOR THE DEVELOPED COUNTRIES

Trade Basics. January 2019 Why Trade? Globalization and the benefits of trade By Dr. Robert L. Thompson

HIGHLIGHTS. There is a clear trend in the OECD area towards. which is reflected in the economic and innovative performance of certain OECD countries.

Hong Kong and the Pearl River Delta: The Emergence of a Super Zone

China s Economic Conditions

3) The European Union is an example of integration. A) regional B) relative C) global D) bilateral

China: The Dragon's Effect on Southeast Asia

Public Schools: Make Them Private by Milton Friedman (1995)

Introduction to the Economy of China

The History and Political Economy of the Peoples Republic of China ( )

FOREIGN TRADE DEPENDENCE AND INTERDEPENDENCE: AN INFLUENCE ON THE RESILIENCE OF THE NATIONAL ECONOMY

PART 1B NAME & SURNAME: THE EFFECTS OF GLOBALIZATION

Floor. explains why. the fallout from the

DRIVERS OF DEMOGRAPHIC CHANGE AND HOW THEY AFFECT THE PROVISION OF EDUCATION

One Belt and One Road and Free Trade Zones China s New Opening-up Initiatives 1

Economic Systems. Essential Questions. How do different societies around the world meet their economic systems?

Trade Costs and Export Decisions

Chinese Economic Reform from an International Perspective

Final exam: Political Economy of Development. Question 2:

* Economies and Values

1. Introduction: the reform and opening- up of a large, developing country

This document is downloaded from DR-NTU, Nanyang Technological University Library, Singapore.

Analysis of current economic and trade relations between China and Vietnam. Dr. Chen Bingxian Guangxi University for Nationalities

INTERNATIONAL TRADE. To accompany the Georgia International Business Curriculum. CTAE Resource Network, Instructional Resources Office, 2010

Survey on International Operations of Japanese Firms (FY2007)

Youth labour market overview

3.1 How does the economy of the globalised world function in different places?

The Asian Development Bank. Transportation Infrastructure in Asia and the Pacific

1 Introduction. The rise of China in the world economy

Transcription:

THE CONCORD REVIEW 57 CHINESE ECONOMIC REFORM: AN ANALYSIS IN THREE SECTORS Pamela Ban China has been the focus of much attention in the past few years; hardly a day goes by without a newspaper article explaining the impact China has on the world. This impact has come as a result of significant economic reforms that China has implemented within the past few decades. This reform process is of particular interest. Market-oriented reforms have created a new economy that differs immensely from the pre-reform strict, doctrinaire socialist economy. Some reform measures were forced by popular pressure while others were established through trial and error; some were based on conventional thought, while others broke prevalent norms. Nevertheless, China s reform path has introduced market mechanisms, increased efficiency, and pushed the Chinese economy into international importance. Economic reform has resulted in an improved, market-oriented Chinese economy. This can be clearly seen through three specific areas. Reform of the agricultural system has forged the link between work and income with the introduction of contracting systems, creating a new economic environment for Chinese peasants. In Pamela Ban is a Senior at Thomas Worthington High School in Worthington, Ohio, where she wrote this paper as an independent study for Mr. Mark McCart in the 2006/2007 academic year.

58 Pamela Ban the enterprise sector, trial and error developed a unique gradualist strategy, which has improved state-owned enterprises, developed private sectors, and progressively diminished the state s influence in enterprise. In the area of foreign trade, evolving attitudes have caused China to open its trade, encourage foreign direct investment, and integrate its reformed economy in the world market. How has economic reform been implemented and how has it resulted in an improved economy? To answer this question, this paper will concentrate on the reform paths that China has taken in agriculture, enterprise, and foreign trade. Focus will begin on reforms starting in 1978, and follow the Chinese economy as economic reform measures are introduced and implemented in each of the three sectors. I. Agricultural Reform Before 1978, China s agricultural system was characterized by strict control and slow agricultural growth. Within a mere decade however, this all changed, and China increased its agricultural output by almost 50 percent. The reason behind this remarkable shift is China s market-oriented reform of its institutional system beginning in 1978. Agricultural reform centered on the link between work and income and created a new economic environment for Chinese peasants, which increased agricultural output and growth. The agricultural system in place under China s traditional economic system revolved around government leaders goal of implementing heavy industry. The state needed to control the production of grain and other raw materials in order to create a favorable economy for heavy industry to thrive in. Thus, in 1955, the Cooperative Transformation Campaign organized peasants into collective economic units to facilitate control, and state-operated advanced cooperatives were established. Three years later in 1958, the government further tightened control and began to combine the advanced cooperatives into people s communes during the

THE CONCORD REVIEW 59 People s Communes Campaign. The government mandated what the collective farming units produced, how much they produced, and from where they received the means of production. Opposition to this strictly-planned agricultural system found leadership under Deng Zihui, the director of rural affairs in the Central Committee of the Communist Party of China (CCCPC). This faction believed that peasants engaged in farming should have freedom in management, and advocated a form of private ownership. To them, peasants should have the power to buy, sell, or lease land, and to manage and employ labor. Zihui saw collectivization as a dangerous and detrimental practice to the Chinese economy. The production-team system that was practiced under collective farming did not maximize agricultural output. Production teams were comprised of around 20 to 30 households in the neighborhood, and net income was based on the performance of the production team as a whole. Individual peasants did not see direct returns for their efforts, and therefore the incentive to work hard did not exist under the production-team system. Consequently, agricultural outputs and farmers per capita net income were significantly low; in 1957, each farmer received an average net income of 73.37 yuan. 2 Peasants began to support Deng Zihui s stance against the collective farming policy and demanded a household responsibility system, under which income would be linked to work. Specifically, peasants desired household contracting, a form of the household responsibility system which operated using task rates. Under this system, a number of work points were set for each job, and peasants received those work points based on the number of jobs they did. These work points would determine the peasants annual net income. Demand for this household contracting system was directly proportional to the political and economic environment, as shown in three specific time periods when agriculture production and the living standard of farmers suffered greatly. The first major push occurred in 1956, after the Cooperative Transformation Campaign established advanced cooperatives. Wenzhou Prefecture in Zhejiang Province, Chengdu Prefecture in Sichuan Province, and Wuhu Prefecture in Anhui

60 Pamela Ban Province began practicing household contracting. However, the Communist Party, especially its chairman Mao Zedong, steadfastly opposed household contracting, viewing it as private in nature and completely against the principles of Communism. On August 8, 1957, the government took direct action to suppress the practice and commenced a campaign of mass debates between socialist and capitalist roads, and household contracting was branded as part of the road leading to capitalism. 3 The second major press for household contracting took place in 1959, after a Communism revival and the establishment of the commune system under the People s Commune Campaign. As Jinglian Wu described in his book Understanding and Interpreting Chinese Economic Reform, rural China was dominated by the go-communism craze, the tendency to exaggerate, the tendency to be authoritarian, the tendency to give arbitrary orders, and the tendency for cadres to behave as the privileged... all these did great harm to farmers. 4 Farmers were victimized to the point where their minimum living standards could not be sustained. For themselves, villages began to practice household contracting. However, unfortunately for the peasants, the timing of this coincided with the government s Anti-Right Opportunism campaign, and household contracting was condemned as right opportunism, or liberalist practices. This can be clearly seen through the government-controlled press. The newspaper People s Daily published an article on November 2, 1959 labeling household contracting as a practice of extreme backwardness, retrogression, and reaction and that this poisonous weed...must be uprooted and burned up completely, not even a mite of it is to be retained! 5 Guangming Daily, reinforcing the government s view that household contracting was a malicious effort to restore capitalism, released an article on December 4, 1959 reporting that household contracting was a program of right opportunists for capitalist restoration in the countryside. 6 The third key push for household contracting occurred in 1962, when the catastrophic and disastrous effects of the failed Great Leap Forward and People s Communes Campaign became

THE CONCORD REVIEW 61 increasingly evident. The collectives could not support the lives of commune members, and more and more farmers were dying from starvation. Anhui Province, in desperation, once again returned to household contracting. Output quota was fixed for each plot, each worker was designated certain responsibilities, and eventually agricultural production was restored. Anhui Province s actions were, however, publicly disparaged by Mao at a CCCPC conference in January 1962. According to David Zweig, to Mao, a link between work and income represented the ultimate in material incentives. 7 In response to Mao s criticism, the Anhui Provincial Committee issued a Resolution on Rectifying the Practice of Responsibility Plots. In spite of this, household contracting had by this time rooted itself as a potential solution to agriculture s problems of low outputs. As long as the practice could increase outputs, as it did in Anhui, some leaders were willing to entertain the idea. This was evident in June 1962, when the Secretariat of the CCCPC received a work report from rural areas of East China. Half the Secretariat backed the practice of household contracting, while half opposed it. Mao, seeing that more and more leaders were accepting the idea of household contracting, turned the issue into a topic of class struggle to garner support. In the summer of 1962 at another conference of the CCCPC, Mao proclaimed that if any type of household contracting was implemented, the struggle and strife between social classes would be disastrous. 8 In September of that same year, Mao gave a speech which intertwined the problem of class struggle with household contracting, stating that household contracting would paint everything black. 9 Nevertheless, household contracting was tolerated. In 1978, the CCCPC allowed household contracting in remote and poor areas. This alone led to a huge increase in production teams practicing household contracting. In the beginning of 1980, 1.1 percent of all production teams in China participated in household contracting. By the middle of 1980, this figure had increased to 20 percent. 10 By 1981, the government, seeing the success resulting from linking work to income, eliminated any other restrictions

62 Pamela Ban on practicing the household responsibility system, and gave it its full acceptance. By 1984, nearly all agricultural production teams were under the household responsibility system. 11 Around the same time of its official acceptance, the household responsibility system underwent a few changes as well. Production teams began to disband into smaller work groups to better recognize individual accountability. The practice of work points was gradually replaced by quota and above-quota prices as the household responsibility system evolved. Peasants were obligated to sell to the state a certain amount of produce at the quota price, but also received an above-quota price for any excess produce. Furthermore, price reform was implemented in 1979, and quota and above-quota prices were increased. The government raised the quota prices of grain, cotton, sugar crops, oil crops, and pork by 17.1 percent, and above-quota prices of grain and oil crops were raised from 30 percent to half their corresponding quota prices. 12 Another stage of reform occurred in 1984 when these fixed quotas were abolished and replaced by procurement contracts. Procurement contracts were compulsory sales to the government, and the contract price was a weighted average of the basic quota price and the above-quota price. Peasants were only responsible for paying the State Agricultural Tax and upholding the procurement contracts, and were allowed to dispose of excess produce after this in any way they pleased. What was the reason behind the government s shift to procurement contracts in 1984? The motivation came from the government s financial burden. The increases made in quota and above-quota prices resulted in a growth in output starting around 1982. 13 According to 1988 figures in the China Statistical yearbook, the government s financial burden in this area increased from 8.4 percent of the budget in 1982 to approximately 24.6 percent of the budget in 1984. 14 Procurement contracts were introduced in part to alleviate the government s financial burden. Peasants were allowed to continue to dispose of excess produce in any way they wished. Most sold the excess in market

THE CONCORD REVIEW 63 fairs, or, in the specific case of grain, to private grain traders who traveled across the countryside. The number of rural market fairs in operation increased from 50,356 in 1984 to 66,569 within a decade. 15 According to Justin Yifu Lin s figures in his study on rural reform in China, the market prices of these market fairs were generally higher than the procurement prices paid by the government. 16 Furthermore, another study conducted by Jean C. Oi concluded that the government went as far as to encourage its grain stations to pay market prices to compete with the private grain traders for peasant grain. 17 However, this practice was abruptly stopped by the government in 1998, when the government declared that all grain was to be sold to the state. Private grain operators were allowed to continue operating, but they were restricted to purchasing grain from state grain stores and were forbidden to continue purchasing grain directly from peasants. Why did China come so close to market freedom and then reverse its policies? To answer this question, one must first consider why China did not permit a complete market to develop or privatize the ownership of land. By this time, China s land policy was extremely outdated; each peasant household was registered as a farm and was obligated to pay the State Agricultural Tax and meet the compulsory sales stipulated in the procurement contracts, whether or not the household wanted to engage in farming. As reforms were implemented in all economic sectors, the Chinese economy had greatly diversified and allowed peasants the opportunity to engage in labor other than farming. Millions of peasants left farming to go into various types of industry, rural and urban. Farming was not the priority, and land was not worked to produce maximum yields. The state could have easily subsidized the peasants who chose to farm the land, and farm technology advancements would be able to further increase produce yields. This strategy was not implausible, and could have been a possible solution. For example, even in the early 1980s, some highly technologically advanced peasant villages delegated the task of farming to a few households and were still able to meet the terms of the procurement contracts. However, in light of this, the government did not privatize land nor let a complete market to develop due to two main objec-

64 Pamela Ban tives. First, the government did not want to become dependent on food imports. The Chinese government was extremely concerned with food security and supply. Although the state encouraged development of rural industries, it did not want grain production to become a minor or secondary task for peasants. Second, as the government began to reform state-owned enterprises, a significant number of these workers were laid off. The state found it easier to make former peasants leave industry and keep the original workers if the peasants were able to go back to farming. By keeping all households registered as farms, the government was maintaining a job cushion. 18 Look at the state of grain outputs during 1984-1987, and the government s anxiety over maintaining food security and supply can be seen a little easier. In 1985 the government went as far as to even set aside procurement contracts. Peasants were enjoying great economic freedom. They began to increase the proportion of cash crops in their farming to increase their profit margin. Naturally, the percentage of field area dedicated to grain production decreased while the percentage of the field area devoted to producing cash crops increased. 19 With grain outputs stalled and even dropping, state interference began to increase in order to ensure food security and supply, and state procurement contracts were once again initiated. Data shows that after this occurred, grain production reversed its decline and started increasing again. 20 1985 remains the year in which peasants had the most economic freedom. Going back to 1998 with this information, the reason behind the government s action of reversing its policies and eliminating market forces is more obvious. State interference increased and culminated in 1998, all due to grain production. Although market fairs still continued to operate at a reasonable rate, from 1998 to 1999, the number in existence dropped from 65,050 to 63,593; within another year this figure dropped even lower to 62,416. 21 The state s anxiety over food security and supply, especially in the area of grain production, has jeopardized and threatened the future status of market freedom. The agricultural market

THE CONCORD REVIEW 65 continues to be regulated by a combination of market forces and state intervention. Nevertheless, the agricultural reforms that China took were extremely significant. The institution of the household responsibility system increased agricultural output. Since households were allowed, in most cases, to control any excess produce after state quotas or compulsory sales were met, the incentive to increase output existed. The formation of the link between work and income created an incentive and successfully increased agricultural output and growth; from 1978-1984 alone, total agricultural growth increased 48.64 percent. 22 46.89 percent of this growth is directly related to the institutional shift to linking work to income. 23 This increase in growth was extraordinary. Figures such as these had not existed since 1949, when the People s Republic of China was founded. 24 China was able to change its agricultural system in such a short time period because farmers were not only supportive but they also pressed for change. Disastrous effects on agricultural production from events such as the Great Leap Forward and the Great Cultural Revolution nearly wiped out all rural economics, making local leaders more inclined to break the law and implement a new system. The rest of the population did not object to the reform since it did not have any negative effects on other social groups. 25 National leaders saw the positive effect of linking work to income on agricultural outputs, and gradually accepted the new system. Although the government s anxiety over food security and supply has curtailed and prevented market freedom from reaching its full extent, China s agricultural system has nevertheless established the link between work and income, incorporated market forces, and increased agricultural production and growth. II. Enterprise Reform The reform of the enterprise sector is integral in transforming a centrally planned economy to a more market-oriented one as it establishes the microeconomic foundation that is required

66 Pamela Ban for a modern market economy. China s reform path in this area broke prevalent norms. Instead of the mass privatization, big bang strategies that were applied in Central and Eastern Europe, China s enterprise reform took on a more gradualist transition. This gradualist strategy has proven to be extremely successful. State-owned enterprises (SOEs) were reformed through several central ideologies and private sectors were established steadily and flourished quickly, overall progressively diminishing the state s influence in enterprise. The traditional SOEs, as they existed before reform, were seen by the government as a way to fulfill political and economic objectives in line with their goal of promoting heavy industry. The government completely controlled the allocation of the factors of production. Just as in the traditional agricultural system, the government determined what, how many, and how to produce, in addition to mandating where raw material came from and who the consumers would be. Output was sold to the state at governmentregulated prices. Market forces were eliminated. There was neither a product market nor a production factors market, and supply and demand was, in most part, ignored. The process of meeting demand was replaced by the role of meeting government goals. Furthermore, SOEs operated in extremely broad and wide-ranging fields, sometimes in fields ill-suited for government interference. 26 In addition, important economic factors such as input and output prices, investments, and taxes, were all determined and regulated by the state. SOEs close relationship with the government gave them the power to greatly influence the modification of these barriers to their favor, instead of being forced to optimize business plans. Naturally, this system was characterized by various problems. Those who allocated resources did not have the essential information required to do so efficiently; decision-making power concentrated in the central government was detrimental because the central government was too separated from the environments, interests, and problems facing enterprises. Enterprises did not have sufficient funds to spend on technological advancements

THE CONCORD REVIEW 67 and research; managers did not have the opportunity to develop, innovate, or plan. 27 Even authority over seemingly routine issues such as wage determination, employment levels, production scheduling and forecasts, and raw material acquisitions was not given to managers. 28 In addition, there was no effective way for administrators to monitor enterprises and check whether enterprises were putting resources to optimal use. Since input and output prices were fixed, enterprise accounting profits or losses could not reflect whether resources were being used efficiently. 29 There was no incentive for workers or managers to increase productivity. Furthermore, during the decades before reform, the total factor productivity (TFP), which measures the efficiency of capital and labor use of SOEs, remained the same or even dropped. 30 During the period 1957-1978, SOEs experienced an annual TFP growth rate that fluctuated closely around zero, conditional on the capital and labor weights chosen. 31 Capital and labor were directed into industries, but the enterprise system was not efficient in using them. The first mainstream program reforming SOEs concentrated on the idea of expanding enterprise autonomy. During the Third Plenum of the 11th CCCPC in December 1978, government leaders admitted that enterprises lacked autonomy. In 1979, the economist Hong Ma advocated that the economic management system reform should begin with expanding enterprise autonomy to expand the enterprise decision-making power concerning human, financial, and material resources, as well as planning. 32 The idea of expanding enterprise autonomy was the process of transferring more decision-making power and control from the government to enterprise management; this was a type of powerdelegating reform. This idea spread successfully, and in July 1979, the State Council released documents which encouraged reform by expanding enterprise autonomy nationwide. By June 1980, enterprises running under this system accounted for over 94 percent of total enterprise profit. In Shanghai and Tianjin, the figure was 80 percent. 33 At the end of 1980, the Chinese government also adopted

68 Pamela Ban the idea of profit retention. SOEs no longer had to relinquish all profit to the state; rather, they were permitted to keep a negotiated, preset percentage of the profit. In essence, this practice of profit retention, a type of profit-sharing reform, echoed the system of linking work to income that was incorporated in Chinese agricultural reform. Variations of power-delegating and profit-sharing comprised the first major enterprise reform program. However, although this reform increased production and income initially, the newly found enthusiasm for efficiency was not long lasting. Shortly, fiscal deficits returned and increased, inflation materialized, and economic order, in general, was lost. The increased fiscal deficits that were generated by the profit retention program were, according to Robert Hsu, inconsistent with the fiscal balance of the state macroeconomic plan, and was accordingly replaced with profit taxes around 1983-1984. 34 This tax system, which levied a 55 percent 35 profit tax for large and medium sized SOEs, was designed to make enterprises more liable for business profits and losses. 36 Around the approximate time period, in 1983, the contracting system was introduced to the enterprise sector. This was the same contracting system used in agriculture, but adapted for SOEs. The enterprise contracting system was essentially a specific form of power-delegating and profit-sharing. A contract is established between the contracting party, which was one of many state organizations, and the contracted party, which was the business. The terms of how decision-making power and profit are divided are stipulated in each contract. In most cases, any superfluous profit would be retained by the contracted party or be divided and shared between the two parties by a pre-negotiated proportion. In addition, any commodities produced beyond the plans could be sold on a newly developed dual-price system, which operated with market forces. In early 1983, the Secretariat leader of the CCCPC strongly encouraged the implementation of the enterprise contracting system in all urban industries and commercial enterprises, and within two to three months, the practice was allowed nationwide. 37 By the end of 1987, 78 percent of SOEs were operating under the enterprise contracting system. 38

THE CONCORD REVIEW 69 However, the effectiveness of the system was yet to be revealed. The enterprise contracting system did not alleviate the problems plaguing the Chinese economy; it upset the economic balance once again and led to rising inflation. The decentralization of fiscal power granted local governments the ability to influence local economies; consequently, local leaders earnestly pursued quick growth, causing inflation to rise rapidly. The central government, in turn, reestablished central control and implemented price ceilings and credit quotas in an effort to rein the economy back in. 39 In addition, even with the implementation of the enterprise contracting system, the heart of the problem still existed. Enterprise property rights remained undefined, which caused discord between the contracting and contracted parties and led to mutual contract breaches. Furthermore, enterprises still had no complete accountability for profits or losses. Why was full accountability not granted to enterprises? Enterprise leaders shared residual control with the state, as decision-making power was divided between the two. Residual claim on income was also shared between enterprise leaders and the state, as profit was divided between the two. However, the state is the only one with an equity investment, as the state is the sole owner of the enterprise. Therefore, enterprise leaders share residual claim and control, but do not share risk. They never assume responsibility for the losses, but always have a claim on profit. This problem was present in any reform that consisted of any type of power-delegating and profit-sharing, leading to a circle of problems with reform. 40 Government intervention was the only way to check insider control, but government intervention was the direct opposite of reform intentions. Furthermore, full accountability could not be given to enterprises without the transfer of ownership. This would remain a crucial problem in SOE reform. By the early 1990s, a new avenue of enterprise reform took shape. The Third Plenary Session of the 14th CCCPC in November 1993 marked the ending of power-delegating and profit-sharing reform and began the period of corporatization. The Decision on Issues Regarding the Establishment of a Social-

70 Pamela Ban ist Market Economy was released, proclaiming that future SOE reform should concentrate on the institutional innovation of enterprises and establish a modern enterprise system [modern corporations]. 41 According to the Decision, the corporate system should be characterized by clearly defined property rights, power, and responsibilities, scientific management, and the distinct separation between enterprise and government. 42 The Decision also had many ramifications on the Chinese economy as a whole; it established the socialist market economy, and finally allowed market forces to play a larger role in the allocation of resources. However, sweeping privatization fell short of acceptance and public ownership was still emphasized as a core idea. 43 Nevertheless, the Decision was a step toward a more market-oriented economy. The Decision was closely followed by the Company Law of the People s Republic of China in December 1993, which more clearly stipulated how corporatization was to work. Going into effect midyear in 1994, 100 SOEs were chosen to be the first to be corporatized. Within two years, these SOEs were to become limited liability companies (LLCs) or shareholding enterprises (SHEs). Article 3 of the Company Law stipulated the difference between the two: in LLCs, a shareholder is liable to the extent of his capital input, in SHEs, the company s capital is equally divided into shares and a shareholder is liable to the extent of his shareholdings. 44 However, in a LLC, the state is the only one with equity investment. LLCs can either be a wholly state-owned LLC, when there is only one state entity investing, or an ordinary state-owned LLC, when there are multiple state entities investing. In either case, a LLC remains a state-owned enterprise; the only difference between a LLC and a traditional SOE is that the state may divide its investments by investing in the company through various entities. On the other hand, SHEs must, according to the Company Law, be incorporated through share offer. With SHEs the state must hold, at minimum, 35 percent of the total shares, with the rest offered to the general public. The state does not have to invest in 51 percent of the shares and be the majority owner; the shares held by the general public often are so spread out that the 35 percent requirement often ensures that the state

THE CONCORD REVIEW 71 is the largest shareholder. 45 Therefore, the state could reduce its expenditures in this area without relinquishing control. While this shareholding system was introduced in the enterprise sector, it was not filtered through the enterprise sector as much to make an effect. The corporatization plan was not a radical change in enterprise ownership, as it included mostly LLCs and only a handful of SHEs. With the state still as the owner, the former problem of enterprise leaders sharing residual claim but not risk still existed. Accordingly, financial performance of enterprises did not improve, as managers still did not strive to minimize costs and losses. From 1994-1997, losses increased 64 percent, jumping from 48 billion to 78 billion yuan. 46 In 1997, the corporatization program was discontinued. The government, seeing the success that the SHEs had during the corporatization reform, decided to transform loss-making enterprises into publicly listed companies, thereby beginning the period of shareholding system reform. The government mandated that SOEs be reformed by restructuring corporate governance, by breaking up monopolies, and by converting SOEs into shareholding enterprises by initial public offering (IPO). In 1998, administrative function was separated from enterprise function, and monopolies were broken up and reorganized into competitive enterprises. In the case of natural monopolies, the government limited those monopolies functions down to a narrow and most-needed extent and strictly monitored their actions. 47 Lastly, IPOs were listed in domestic and foreign securities market. No analysis of Chinese enterprise reform is complete without a look at the development of the private sector. In 1987, the 13th National Congress of the Communist Party encouraged the development of the private sector, and in April 1988, at the First Session of the National People s Congress, the Constitution of the People s Republic of China was successfully amended to include a reference to developing private sectors. Article 11 of the Constitution mandates that the State permits the private sector to exist and develop within the limits prescribed by law. The private sector is a supplement to socialist private sectors. The

72 Pamela Ban State protects the lawful rights and interests of the private sector, and exercises guidance, supervision, and control over the private sector. 48 In 1993, the Third Plenary Session of the 14th CCCPC reorganized and accepted the increasing number of non-state enterprises, while once again emphasizing that the focus of the economy would still be public ownership. SOEs could not meet every need of the market, and private businesses met the missing needs. They also helped with the problem of unemployment, which gave them the support of local governments. 49 In 1998, the government faced a critical problem when SOE reform forced more than 10 million people into unemployment. The development of the non-state sector became a high priority. In the late 1980s and early 1990s, the annual real growth rate of private firms was 140.6 percent, and state firms output share was 48.4 percent. 50 As non-state enterprises became more critical, the federal government began to modify its policies and regulations to allow the gradual development of larger private enterprises. This gradual development is a key characteristic of China s reform. Non-state sectors developed gradually while state sectors maintained the prominent position. When this was attempted in the Soviet Union and other Eastern European countries, it failed. China was able to do this, according to Jeffrey Sachs and Wing T. Woo, because there was a surplus labor force, which was absent in the Soviet Union, and because Chinese SOEs were still in the dynamic process of reform. 51 Overall, enterprise reform has influenced the autonomy, incentives, and competitiveness of SOEs. Decision-making power was decentralized and transferred to enterprise management, giving managers authority over amounts and types of inputs, methods of production, and output prices. Incentives were created with the advent of various profit retention practices, corporatization was introduced, and the shareholding system was evolved. With the development of the non-state sector and the reform of SOEs, state influence in enterprise and industry has gradually declined. Back in 1978, the state sector was responsible for 77.63 percent of gross output value, and the non-state sector accounted for 22.37

THE CONCORD REVIEW 73 percent of gross output value. 52 As enterprise reform continued, the state sector s share declined while the non-state sector s share increased. By 1994, the state sector only accounted for 34.06 percent of gross output value, with the non-state sector being responsible for 65.94 percent. 53 Competition is now common within the non-state sector, between the non-state and state sectors, and within the state sector. Furthermore, as competition affects the state sector, state enterprises press for additional release from state regulation. Enterprise profits have soared, averaging 36 percent annual increases since 1999 among both non-state and state sectors. 54 Returns on equity have also increased. From 1998 to 2005, state-owned enterprises returns went from 2 percent to 13 percent, and private enterprises rose from 7 percent to 16 percent. 55 In addition, China s TFP is no longer the stagnate rate of the 1960s and 1970s. In the past decade, China s TFP growth rate has been the fastest in the world. 56 These results reflect the success from expanding the private sector and restructuring SOEs. Economic reform in China s enterprise sector is a dynamic process. As reform creates new environments, new problems will arise. However, what is significant is the extent of reform that China was able to undergo within the period of approximately two decades. Trial and error has yielded an improved state sector, and the acceptance of non-state sectors has created a new economy that differs immensely from the pre-reform doctrinaire socialist economy. The success from enterprise reform forecasts more years of robust growth. III. Reform of Foreign Trade Attitudes Ten years ago, a Chinese assistant foreign minister stated, China is not any kind of power. It is not at present. And it will not be one in the future. 57 How perspectives have changed. Today, not a single person doubts China s rising economic power. It is hard to believe that merely three decades ago, China was nearly completely isolated from the rest of the world. Since then, China

74 Pamela Ban has opened up its economy, entered the international scene, and risen to prominence, integrating itself in the world economy. In the 1960s, the Chinese government held a monopoly over foreign trade, and completely controlled imports and exports. China ended its political and economic relationships with the USSR, withdrew from the world, and focused on becoming self-sufficient. World trade figures illustrate China s isolation from the rest of the world. In 1962, the world trade volume was $2.66 billion, and China s trade activity accounted for a mere 1.5 percent of this. Even as the world trade volume grew, reaching $14.80 billion in 1977, China retreated further and further away from international trade, accounting for only 0.6 percent of world trade. 58 Despite this, China could not remain in complete isolation. By the mid 1970s, the government realized that it could not match the industrialization of the Western world independently; China was unable to close the gap in industry, technology, or management by itself. Therefore, the government partially restored economic relations with the United States, other Western countries, and Japan. In 1978, China signed a $7.8 billion trade contract with the U.S. for chemical fertilizers and metallurgy, and in this one year, China s trade activity increased 39 percent. 59 On the other hand, China was still not willing to open its economy to foreign countries; the trade opened up in the 1970s was intended to build independence and self-reliance. However, the Chinese government slowly realized that trade was integral to economic development. In September 1978, at the Third Plenary Session of the Central Advisory Commission of the Communist Party of China, Deng Xiaoping declared that the last 30 years of closed-door policy hindered China s economic development, and pressed for reform and opening up to take advantage of foreign capital and foreign advanced technology. In his speech, he stated that if we isolate ourselves and close our doors again, it will be absolutely impossible for us to approach the level of the developed countries in 50 years. 60 Government leaders looked at Japan and Hong Kong s economic development

THE CONCORD REVIEW 75 success with export-oriented systems, and decided to pursue the policy of export-orientation. China s economy, with Deng Xiaoping s leadership, has been opened in stages on a regional basis. In the 1980s, opening began in select coastal cities that were close to other East Asian countries. In May 1980, Guandong and Fujian were granted open economic policies to develop export-oriented industries and attract foreign investment. In August 1980, Shenzhen, Shuhai, Shantou, and Xiamen became the first four Special Economic Zones (SEZs). SEZs were given special flexible policies and treatment. Imported goods for self-use were free from tariffs and industrial or commercial taxes, and imports primarily for resale were given a 50 percent discount off standard taxes. In May 1984, 14 coastal cities (Dalian, Qinhuangdao, Tianjin, Yantai, Qingdao, Lianyungang, Nantong, Shanghai, Ningbo, Wenzhou, Fuzhou, Guangshou, Zhanjiang, Beihai) were given similar open economic privileges, but were not designated SEZs. In February 1985, the Yangtze River Delta, and the Pearl River Delta, among other areas, were also declared to be open economic regions. By 1988, the last SEZ was established in Hainan. Opening up these areas allowed for rapid development in their respective regions and, in addition, encouraged the opening up of the entire nation. The open regions made successful use of international resources and were involved in international competition. The first four SEZs alone experienced an increase of 44.4 billion yuan of industrial output within the first five years, with an annual growth rate of about 50 percent. 61 China s exportoriented industries developed rapidly: in 1990 alone, the total export volume of the coastal provinces amounted to $40 billion. This number was approximately two-thirds of China s total export volume. 62 The open regions greatly strengthened themselves with the assistance of foreign capital investment, technology, and management, and experimented with new economic systems and operating mechanisms. They tested new reform models and provided a foundation for reform for the entire nation.

76 Pamela Ban The success, advancement, and experience gained by China in the 1980s, through opening up, set an extremely solid basis for further pursuits in the next decade. In the 1990s, China followed a four-along strategy of opening up. The four specific regions focused on were along the coast, from the Bohai Sea to the Gulf of Tonkin, along the border, with both northern and southern borders, along the river, in particular the Yangtze River Valley and the Pudong area in Shanghai, and along the railway, with regions located along railroads across the entire nation. 63 Pudong, a district of Shanghai, used to be mainly farmland and countryside until the government concentrated economic development reform in 1990, when the Pudong New Area was created. Pudong was to be the head of the dragon for the opening up of regions along the banks of the Yangtze River. Pudong has successfully emerged as a crucial financial and commercial center of China. It is the home to the Shanghai Stock Exchange, the major stock exchange in China (with the other being the smaller Shenzhen Stock Exchange), and the Lujiazui finance and trade zone. Foreign direct investment is crucial to China s economic development. Ever since China has begun the process of opening up, special policies have been implemented to encourage foreign countries to invest in China. In July 1979, The Law on Joint-Ventures using Chinese and Foreign Investment was adopted, legalizing foreign investment in China. In 1986, the government formally permitted the existence of entirely foreign-owned enterprises. Furthermore, the State Council backed the Provisions of the State Council of the Encouragement of Foreign Investment. The 22 articles in the Provision outlined preferential tax treatment for foreign joint-ventures, and granted them the freedom to import inputs, an increased promise of autonomy from bureaucratic intervention, and quicker licensing procedures, among others. In addition, foreign ventures were given privileged access to basic resources such as water, electricity, and transportation, and were provided with interest-free loans. 64 These preferential policies and incentives were critical in making China the largest recipient of foreign direct investment (FDI) among developing countries. It has become a norm to invest

THE CONCORD REVIEW 77 in China. Out of the world s top 500 non-financial corporations, over 400 have projects in China. Over 400 research and development bases have been created by multinationals. 65 In particular, the Yangtze River Delta and the Pearl River Delta have become important areas of the information technology industry. However, most of the FDI is used towards labor-intensive production. Over half of the total foreign investment went towards the manufacturing industry; around 70 percent of foreign enterprises in China are dedicated to manufacturing. 66 By 2002, China exceeded the U.S. to become the country with the most foreign direct investment in the world. 67 East Asia is an important source of China s foreign direct investment. The numbers are staggering. Hong Kong itself is responsible for around $204.9 billion of investment as of 2002. Japan s accumulated investment amounts to $36.34 billion, and Taiwan s is $33.11 billion. 68 These East Asian countries originally held a trade surplus with the United States, a trade surplus which has since diminished due to their trade relations with China. East Asian countries take advantage of China s cheap production factors. A triangular trade is formed, China processes imports from East Asian countries and then exports the product to the United States, Europe, and other developed markets. This effect is most pronounced in Japan s case. According to a report by the Centre d Etudes Prospectives et d Informations Internationales in Paris, Japan has shifted its export market from exporting goods to Western countries to exporting product parts and components to China. 69 Japan s import market has changed from importing finished goods from Western countries to importing finished goods from China. 70 China is now East Asia s major trading partner. The trade surplus has shifted from between East Asia and the U.S. to between China and the U.S. and between East Asian countries and the U.S. By 2001, China became the primary source of U.S. trade deficits. In January 2004, China experienced a trade surplus of $11.5 billion with the U.S. alone. 71 China s trade surplus mainly comes from its manufacturing industry. China is unsurpassed in its ability to provide low-cost

78 Pamela Ban manufacturing. China is responsible for manufacturing 70 percent of the world s toys, 60 percent of the world s bicycles, and 50 percent of the world s shoes. 72 Former manufacturing intensive countries such as Mexico and South Korea will have to contend with China s manufacturing powerhouse. China can already assemble, manufacture, and ship its products over to the U.S. more cheaply than Mexico can produce them. Even though Mexico is right below the U.S. and has the privileges of NAFTA on its side, in 2003, China has surpassed Mexico in exporting to the U.S. 73 Worldwide, in 2004, China took its place behind America and Germany as the world s third-largest exporter. 74 China s opening up to foreign investment and its welcoming of international trade has greatly altered the economic makeup of the Asiatic region. World Trade Organization membership has allowed China to increase its appeal to foreign investors. East Asia is not the only region actively linked to China; China has increasingly drawn in immense quantities of parts for final assembly from countries all around Asia. Thailand, Malaysia, Singapore, the Philippines, and Indonesia are major players in the triangular trade, along with the other East Asian countries such as Taiwan and South Korea. China s accession to the WTO and the opening of its trade has benefited numerous countries. In 2003, China s demand for capital goods and components pulled Japan out of its 15-year recession. 75 Chinese demand for raw materials has been satisfied by Southern Asia s rubber, crude oil, and natural gas, to the benefit of those countries. 76 In 1978, China s dependence rate on foreign trade was 9.8 percent; by 2000, this figure increased to 43.9 percent. 77 China is being linked closer and closer with Asian production networks all over the continent, and the Chinese economy has become increasingly reliant on foreign trade. China, however, is not content with merely manufacturing toys. It has entered the high-tech product market, exporting the likes of computers, DVD players, and cell phones. In 1998, America imported $5.0 million of Chinese made notebook computers. By 2004, this figure jumped to $7.7 billion. 78 In the year after that, 43 percent of China s exports were in electronics, computers, and telecoms equipment. 79 Nevertheless, contrary to

THE CONCORD REVIEW 79 the fear that China s ascent in the high-tech industry threatens U. S. national security, China s position in the high-tech industry is not what it seems. Its high-tech exports are very much like its toy exports it assembles a computer as it assembles a toy. Most of China s high-tech exports are, in reality, exports assembled from imported components. However, that does not say that China is not developing its own place in the high-tech industry. Already, the Chinese firm Huawei is a mobile handset supplier to Vodafone, and China s own car industry has secured around 25 percent of its domestic market. 80 The isolated China is no more. Evolving attitudes have opened up China s economy to foreign trade, benefiting both China and foreign countries. China has been able to exploit its comparative advantage in areas such as manufacturing, establishing itself as a force to be reckoned with in the global market. And by integrating itself in international markets, China now affects numerous countries around the world and has aroused worldwide interest. When Deng Xiaoping made his speech pushing to open China up 30 years ago, he might not have predicted that China would achieve its current prominence. Yet, it was this push that started China s ascent as an international economic power. Within the last few decades, China has undergone a period of significant reforms that has left it with an improved, marketoriented economy. Linking work to income in agricultural production has increased agricultural output and growth, reduced the threat of chronic shortages, and established a solid foundation for economic prosperity and political stability. The development of the non-state enterprise sector is a clear indication that the market mechanism has been brought into play. In addition, the growth of the private sector and the restructuring of SOEs have resulted in productivity gains, improvement in profits, and increases in returns on equity. Furthermore, open foreign trade attitudes have allowed China to benefit from international markets and achieve a principal role in world trade. China did not easily accept market-oriented reforms. They were not implemented effortlessly, nor were they welcomed