The Determination of Optimal Fines in Cartel Cases: The Myth of Underdeterrence

Similar documents
Penalising on the basis of the severity of the offence: A sophisticated revenue-based cartel penalty

Comment on The Empirical Basis for Antitrust: Cartels, Mergers, and Remedies

The Econometrics of Cartel Overcharges

Does enforcement deter cartels? A tale of two tails

Quantifying Harm for Breaches of Antitrust Rules A European Union Perspective

Separation of Powers: The Case of Antitrust

rules, including whether and how the state should intervene in market activity.

Bid-rigging and deterrence under EU law. ICN Cartel Workshop, Ottawa Kris Van Hove 5 October 2017

Pork Barrel as a Signaling Tool: The Case of US Environmental Policy

PROCEDURE OF SETTING FINES IMPOSED PURSUANT TO THE ACT ON THE PROTECTION OF COMPETITION

PUBLIC AND PRIVATE ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT FOR CARTELS: SHOULD THERE BE A COMMON APPROACH TO SANCTIONING BASED ON THE OVERCHARGE RATE?

Family Values and the Regulation of Labor

Antitrust: Commission introduces settlement procedure for cartels frequently asked questions (see also IP/08/1056)

English - Or. English DIRECTORATE FOR FINANCIAL AND ENTERPRISE AFFAIRS COMPETITION COMMITTEE

Calculating Damages in Price-Fixing Cases in the United States, Canada, and the European Union

PROJECTION OF NET MIGRATION USING A GRAVITY MODEL 1. Laboratory of Populations 2

Testing Leniency Programs Experimentally

IPSA International Conference Concordia University, Montreal (Quebec), Canada April 30 May 2, 2008

Integrity and Incentives Leniency, Whistleblowers, and the Deterrence of Corruption and Collusion in Public Procurement

January 25, 2012 INTRODUCTION & EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

INVESTIGATIVE POWER IN PRACTICE - Contribution from Brazil

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES

Immigration Enforcement, Child-Parent Separations and Recidivism by Central American Deportees

The European School of Thought in EU Merger Control

Immigrant Legalization

The economic analysis of interaction of fines and damages under European and American antitrust laws

The Cost-Benefit Analysis of Crime*

(V) Migration Flows and Policies. Bocconi University,

Why Antitrust Damage Levels Should Be Raised

STANDARD OF PROOF IN CARTEL CASES

Anthony Norton Norton's Inc. Criminalisation of cartel behaviour: Implications for corporates in South Africa

Notice of 16 May 2011 on the Method Relating to the Setting of Financial Penalties

DU PhD in Home Science

3 Electoral Competition

Case3:11-cr WHA Document40 Filed08/08/11 Page1 of 10

Kristen E. Manderscheid

EXPORT, MIGRATION, AND COSTS OF MARKET ENTRY EVIDENCE FROM CENTRAL EUROPEAN FIRMS

Model of Voting. February 15, Abstract. This paper uses United States congressional district level data to identify how incumbency,

What are the potential benefits and pitfalls of a free trade area in the Southern African region

Summary of Discussion Points. Presented by the Business and Industry Advisory Committee (BIAC) to the OECD Competition Committee Working Party No.

Assessing the impact of the Sentencing Council s Environmental offences definitive guideline

Matthew A. Cole and Eric Neumayer. The pitfalls of convergence analysis : is the income gap really widening?

Female Migration, Human Capital and Fertility

Global Forum on Competition

General Overview of the EU Cartel Settlement Procedure. Jean-François Bellis (Partner, Van Bael & Bellis, Brussels)

The Proposed Damages Directive: The Real Lessons from the United States

Trade Flows and Migration to New Zealand

The future of abuse control in a more economic approach to competition law Meeting of the Working Group on Competition Law on 20 September 2007

Executive summary. Part I. Major trends in wages

American Law & Economics Association Annual Meetings

Chapter. Estimating the Value of a Parameter Using Confidence Intervals Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved

Language Proficiency and Earnings of Non-Official Language. Mother Tongue Immigrants: The Case of Toronto, Montreal and Quebec City

Macroeconomic Implications of Shifts in the Relative Demand for Skills

THE PREDICTABILITY OF DOJ CARTEL FINES*

BID RIGGING CARTELS IN PUBLIC PROCUREMENT

Case: 1:16-cr MRB Doc #: 18 Filed: 02/06/17 Page: 1 of 19 PAGEID #: 98 UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT SOUTHERN DISTRICT OF OHIO WESTERN DIVISION

Trading Goods or Human Capital

GENDER EQUALITY IN THE LABOUR MARKET AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT

Incumbency Advantages in the Canadian Parliament

M E M O R A N D U M. Bill Smith, Esquire Attorney for John Doe. Meredith Patti, Esquire Mary Cate Rush, Chief Statistician. DATE: August 5, 2014

Determinants and Effects of Negative Advertising in Politics

Intra-Industry Trade in Europe Lionel Fontagné

Prof. Bryan Caplan Econ 812

Global Forum on Competition

Penalties for Anti-Competitive Conduct: Sharpening the sting of South Africa s competition authorities

Essays on Incentives and Regulation

Document and Author Promotion Strategies in the Secure Wiki Model

Immigration and Conflict in Democracies

Voter Participation with Collusive Parties. David K. Levine and Andrea Mattozzi

Private enforcement of EU competition law

Escalating Penalties for Repeat Offenders

COMMENTS OF THE ABA SECTION OF ANTITRUST LAW ON THE PROPOSED AMENDMENTS TO THE ANTITRUST RECOMMENDATIONS OF THE UNITED STATES SENTENCING GUIDELINES

The Impact of Interprovincial Migration on Aggregate Output and Labour Productivity in Canada,

Red flags of institutionalised grand corruption in EU-regulated Polish public procurement 2

ARGUMENTS FOR PROSECUTORS OF ENVIRONMENTAL

Legislative Bargaining and Partisan Delegation

Joined Cases C-189/02 P, C-202/02 P, C-205/02 P to C-208/02 P and C-213/02 P. Dansk Rørindustri and Others v Commission of the European Communities

Fraud, bribery and money laundering: corporate offenders Definitive Guideline DEFINITIVE GUIDELINE

CORRUPTION AND GOVERNMENT. Lessons for Portugal Susan Rose-Ackerman

Chapter 1. Introduction

Migration and Tourism Flows to New Zealand

Benefit levels and US immigrants welfare receipts

Vulnerability Assessment and Targeting of Syrian Refugees in Lebanon

On the Alleged Disproportionate Sentencing of Cartel Managers

Exploring the Impact of Democratic Capital on Prosperity

What is fairness? - Justice Anthony Kennedy, Vieth v Jubelirer (2004)

Information Notice. Information Notice. Reference: ComReg 17/49

A Retrospective Study of State Aid Control in the German Broadband Market

Impact Assessment (IA)

Thinkwell s Homeschool Microeconomics Course Lesson Plan: 31 weeks

Labor Market Performance of Immigrants in Early Twentieth-Century America

WpHG Administrative Fine Guidelines II

Institutions Design for Managing Global Commons

Trade and Migration to New Zealand

Statistical Yearbook. for Asia and the Pacific

Preliminary Effects of Oversampling on the National Crime Victimization Survey

ANNUAL SURVEY REPORT: AZERBAIJAN

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

ANTITRUST CLASS ACTIONS: LESSONS FROM THE U.S.

WORKING PAPERS IN ECONOMICS & ECONOMETRICS. A Capital Mistake? The Neglected Effect of Immigration on Average Wages

Transcription:

The Determination of Optimal Fines in Cartel Cases: The Myth of Underdeterrence Marie-Laure Allain, École Polytechnique (Paris) Marcel Boyer, Université de Montréal, École Polytechnique (Paris) and CIRANO Rachidi Kotchoni, Université Laval and University of Alberta Jean-Pierre Ponssard, École Polytechnique (Paris) and CIRANO 1. «The determination of optimal fines in cartel cases: Theory and practice» Concurrences 4-2011 (Allain, Boyer, Ponssard) 2. http://www.cirano.qc.ca/pdf/publication/2011s-35.pdf (Boyer, Kotchoni) 3. http://www.cirano.qc.ca/pdf/publication/2011s-34.pdf (Allain, Boyer, Kotchoni, Ponssard) Conference in honor of Michel Moreaux, Toulouse, November 18, 2011.

THE MAIN POINTS 1. The level of fines recently inflicted by the EU antitrust authority: 293 million (10 cases) over the period 1995-1999 3 500 million (30 cases) over the period 2000-2004 9 800 million (33 cases) over the period 2005-2009. 2. A number of authors have claimed that the current level is still much too low to deter cartels: Connor (2010), Combe and Monnier (2010) are two important studies (which make the present one feasible) 3. Their arguments are based on a measure of cartel overcharges and a theory of deterrence (dissuasive fines) 4. We question their measure and theory, point out a number of flaws in their analyses, and revisit their judgment on the recent level of fines 5. Our conclusion is that the recent level of fines is appropriate and adequately dissuasive 6. Some recommendations for settings cartel fines are discussed

The cartel excess profit depends on the cartel overcharge, the competitive mark-up and the demand elasticity price But-for price Overcharge Competitive mark-up p m p c A B D C Excess or illicit profits: [A+B] [B+C] = A-C D is a deadweight loss due to the cartel Demand with positive price elasticity q m q quantity

Evaluation of the cartel overcharge (main reference Connor, 2006... 2010) Cartel overcharge Dissuasive fine Demand elasticity Cartel excess profit Competitive mark-up Restitutive fine

Determining the Representative Mean/Median of Overcharge Estimates 1. Our analysis of the Connor database, which contains 1120 studies or analyses of cartels over time and regions, shows (see Figure 3 and Table 1 of the BK paper): A large number of relatively small values, small number of very large values: outliers or influential observations create biases in the characterization of a representative mean overcharge estimate. A large number of zero overcharge estimates (7.2%) and a large number of large overcharges 50% (22.6% with an average overcharge estimate of 137.3%): zero overcharges may be negative rounded up to 0 (mass probability at 0); 50% overcharges may not be fully credible in light of economic theory. Cohen and Scheffman: Price increases of 10% or more are beyond belief The mean overcharge estimate is 45.5% overall, 49% for strictly positive estimates, which may not be fully credible as averages; when the 5% largest overcharges are left out: from 49% to 32%; the average is 20.6% for cartels with positive overcharge estimates less than 50%. (For more, see Table 1 of the BK paper) Some overcharge estimates are misinterpreted (p m versus p) and/or exaggerated (Lerner index)

2. Overcharge estimates are explained by two different sets of variables: a) those logically and directly related to overcharges, the Y variables: duration scope (domestic or international) bid-rigging or not found or pleaded guilty or not region period (law regime) b) those that are not, the Z variables: estimation method publication media 3. Meta-analysis (analysis of analyses) serves to purge the results from abnormal or contextual influence 4. Bias-corrected overcharge estimates are obtained by taking out the statistically significant effects of the two bias-capturing or abnormally influent Z variables

5. The significant heterogeneity in the data requires that sophisticated econometric techniques be applied: Outliers (0% and 50%) must be excluded for two reasons: (1) their inclusion creates biases see subsection 5.1 of the BK paper - and distorts the relevancy of the results (our subsample: 786 cartels or 70% of cartels in the database); (b) they may not be fully credible or reasonable based on economic theory. Cohen and Scheffman: Price increases of 10% or more are beyond belief and "the Justice Department's assertion that price-fixing conspiracies would typically result in a mark-up over competitive level of ten percent [ ] is not supported by the available evidence. [ ] This conclusion has important implications because of the potential inefficiencies that may arise from overdeterrence But this may create a loss of information problem (a sample selection bias). We use Heckman methodology to deal with this sample selection problem, an advanced but well documented method in statistical fields/applications. It is widely used in many statistical fields, including economics, medicine, labor studies, psychology, social studies, and others (J. Heckman, 2000 Nobel prize) Four homogenous clusters (groups of cartels) are constructed to account for the remaining heterogeneity in the data. The purpose is to allow the bias in overcharge estimates to vary across the different clusters. It does. We use linear and log-linear specifications to ensure a better control of the heterogeneity and a better fit

Main Econometric Results (BK paper) 1. Our results show that the bias captured by variables Z (estimation method and publication source) is substantial and economically significant. 2. The bias-corrected mean and median estimates obtained by neutralizing the effects of those bias-capturing variables suggest that the mean bias-corrected overcharge estimate for cartels with raw positive overcharge estimates under 50% (the bulk of cartel cases) is approximately 13.6% with a median of 13.6%, while the mean for all cartels of all types is 17.5% with a median of 14.1%. These values must be considered as upper bounds (given our conservative assumptions). 3. In the present context, the median values are more informative and reliable as representative characteristics of cartel behavior. 4. The bias-corrected overcharge estimates reveal a more homogenous behaviour of cartels across different types, geographical locations and periods than suggested by the raw overcharge estimates: a cartel is a cartel is a cartel.

Assessing Excess Cartel Profits (Buccirossi & Spagnolo 2007, as used in Combe and Monnier 2010) 1. Buccirossi and Spagnolo (2007) old-method : Δπ is a function of the cartel overcharge k, the competitive mark-up m and the elasticity of demand (and sales) e Δπ / S = k[(1 + m)(1 - ek) em] / [(1 + m)(1 + k)(1 ek)] 2. Potential pitfall: Yardstick methods (if different MC or elasticities) 3. Potential pitfall: Lerner index m m p c p c p p : vs m m p p p 4. Potential pitfall: Dynamic (repeated) interactions underlying m: likely to be larger if small number of firms, repeated interactions, demand is volatile but growing fast, cost of capital is low, investments are significantly irreversible (sunk). Moreover, BLM (2011) show that along an industry development path, episodes of tacit collusion may be followed by episodes of intense competition and vice-versa. 5. Potential pitfall: Even if a cartel is shown to be present, its effects may be small as k may be small while m Is large (Important: k, m, e are not independent: effect of e).

Illustrations Applying Buccirossi and Spagnolo with k + m = 40% Cartel overcharge k = 30% k = 13% k = 10% Competitive mark-up m = 10% m = 27% m = 30% Demand elasticity e = 2 Cartel excess profit as a % of S 12.6% 4.9% 3.8% Dissuasive fine Restitutive fine

There are two approaches to obtain the dissuasive fine The static multi-period one, implicitly used by Combe and Monnier but with the wrong α 1 α π m c nc cartel no cartel c nc π α π m -fs α π π m S f Prob of detection but-for profit cartel profit cartel sales Fine as a % of S F=fS Fine in m m EΠ along c = (1 απ ) + απ ( F); EΠ along nc = π F is dissuasive IFF it is larger than Δπ / α, or nδπ / αn (not nδπ / α) n with α = 1 (1 a) n

There are two approaches to obtain the dissuasive fine The dynamic one, which should be preferred from an economic point of view A. Cartels are dynamic organizations B. Participants reassess their strategies (participation vs. defection) on a regular basis C. Current and future costs (including potential fines) and benefits are changing and uncertain D. Firms evaluate their options and discount the future at their cost of capital

c cartel 1 α π m defect α move out Prob of detection c defect α π m -H π π π m Π δ δ but-for profit cartel profit profit of defect Discount factor π d π Η Fine in M δ π + α( H + π) EΠ along c = = 1 δ ; 1 δ(1 α) D δ EΠ along defect = π + π 1 δ H is dissuasive IF (sufficiency) it is larger than (1- α ) Δπ / α

Comparing the benchmarks as a function of cartel duration with a similar Δπ, a probability of detection α = 15%, and normalizing F3 at 1 (Note that F3 is NOT a function of n) Relative positioning of the various benchmarks as a function of cartel duration label Definition 14 F1 nδπ 12 F2 nδπ/α 10 8 6 F1 restitution benchmark F2 Combe and Monier Dissuasive benchmark F3 dynamic dissuasive benchmark F3 F4 (1 - α) Δπ/α nδπ/α n 4 F4 Overall n-year dissuasive benchmark F1/F3 nα /(1-α) 2 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 F2/F3 F4/F3 n/(1-α) nα /(1-α)α n

Parameters With Combe and Monnier cartel overcharge With Boyer and Kotchoni cartel overcharge (1) (3) cartel overcharge k 30% 13% competitive markup m 10% 27% A factor of 2.6 Excess profit as a percentage of sales (B&S 2006) 12.6% 4.9% Annual probability of detection 15% 15% Fines as a % of affected one year sales cartel duration (years) 6 6 Restitution F1 75.5% 29.4% C&M dissuasive F2 503.5% 195.8% Our dynamic dissuasive F3 71.3% 27.7% Dissuasive F4 121.3% 47.1% A factor of 18

Parameters With Combe and Monnier cartel overcharge With Boyer and Kotchoni cartel overcharge (1) (3) cartel overcharge k 20% 13% competitive markup m 10% 17% A factor of 1.7 16 Excess profit as a percentage of sales (B&S 2006) 11.6% 7.0% Annual probability of detection 15% 15% Fines as a % of affected one year sales cartel duration (years) 6 6 Restitution F1 69.7% 42.0% C&M dissuasive F2 464.6% 279.5% Our dynamic dissuasive F3 65.8% 39.6% Dissuasive F4 111.9% 65.8% A factor of 11.7

64 European cartels We obtain that 65% paid more than the restitution fine, Assuming a factor 1/2 instead of 50% in Combe and Monnier 64 European cartels We obtain that 56% paid more than the dissuasive fine, Assuming a factor 1/10 instead of 1.5% in Combe and Monnier 17

Cento Veljanovski, Deterrence, Recividism and European Cartel Fines (Case Associates, July 2011): Others have argued that this way of calculating the deterrence multiplier is too simplistic. [Allain, Boyer, Kotchoni and Ponssard] suggest that the Commission s fines result in both a reasonable approximation of the losses inflicted by cartels and deterrence for the majority of firms. Based on much a lower average overcharge of 13% estimated by Boyer and Kotchoni, [they] show that the fines as a percentage of annual sales needed to deter firms from entering into a cartel is massively lower. They find that 56% of the fines in their sample (of 64 firms for the period 1975 to 2009) are above the deterrent benchmark. Applying this to the sample above suggests that fining under the 2006 Penalty Guidelines would adequately deter many firms from participating in cartels, at least going forward. If [Allain, Boyer, Kotchoni and Ponssard] work is confirmed by other scholars then it has significant policy implications.

Recommendations on Setting Fines 1. Cartel fines should be set at the dynamic dissuasive fine level F3. Alternatively, the rule could be max{f3, F1} if it is considered important that the fine be at least restitutive when F3< F1. 2. Define major offenses through a threshold such as an annual turnover on the relevant market is above 1 billion Euros a fine estimated to be above 100 million Euros a fine estimated to be above 50% of affected sales For major offenses, fines should be based on an explicit evaluation of the effects of the cartel a proper representation of the but-for environment a proper estimation of the economic damages For all other offenses, fines should be based on a simplified economic analysis including a standard cartel overcharge (over a range of 5%, 10% to 15%) estimates of demand elasticity (over a range of 0, 1, 2) Estimates of competitive mark-up (depending on the industry standards).

The Next Steps I. Review recent decisions on cartel in order to assess more thoroughly the above assertions on recent fine levels (slide 27) II. Develop the working tools (cookbook) to characterize relevant but-for environments in 2 above (slide 29) III. Analyze in depth some representative recent cases IV. Develop enhanced Guidelines for efficient and incentive-based programs of compliance toward competition rules and regulations III. Develop enhanced Guidelines for proper cooperation between competitors to favor investments and employment in industries that are volatile and quasi natural monopolies (large fixed and sunk costs, with low variable costs), while deterring the formation and/or sustainability of cartels in such industries

The Determination of Optimal Fines in Cartel Cases: The Myth of Underdeterrence Marie-Laure Allain, École Polytechnique (Paris) Marcel Boyer, Université de Montréal, École Polytechnique (Paris) and CIRANO Rachidi Kotchoni, Université Laval and University of Alberta Jean-Pierre Ponssard, École Polytechnique (Paris) and CIRANO 1. «The determination of optimal fines in cartel cases: Theory and practice» Concurrences 4-2011 (Allain, Boyer, Ponssard) 2. http://www.cirano.qc.ca/pdf/publication/2011s-35.pdf (Boyer, Kotchoni) 3. http://www.cirano.qc.ca/pdf/publication/2011s-34.pdf (Allain, Boyer, Kotchoni, Ponssard) Conference in honor of Michel Moreaux, Toulouse, November 18, 2011.