Migration of Labor From Ten Asian Countries to Japan -- An Economic Analysis

Similar documents
Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth: The Asian Experience Peter Warr

Chapter 5: Internationalization & Industrialization

Chapter 10 Trade Policy in Developing Countries

Chapter Organization. Introduction. Introduction. Import-Substituting Industrialization. Import-Substituting Industrialization

POLICY OPTIONS AND CHALLENGES FOR DEVELOPING ASIA PERSPECTIVES FROM THE IMF AND ASIA APRIL 19-20, 2007 TOKYO

An Analysis of Rural to Urban Labour Migration in India with Special Reference to Scheduled Castes and Schedules Tribes

1. Introduction. The Stock Adjustment Model of Migration: The Scottish Experience

Trade led Growth in Times of Crisis Asia Pacific Trade Economists Conference 2 3 November 2009, Bangkok. Session 10

INDONESIA AND THE LEWIS TURNING POINT: EMPLOYMENT AND WAGE TRENDS

Managing Labor Migration: Asia and the GFMD

An Empirical Analysis of Pakistan s Bilateral Trade: A Gravity Model Approach

6. Policy Recommendations on How to Strengthen Financial Cooperation in Asia Wang Tongsan

Economic Growth and Poverty Reduction: Lessons from the Malaysian Experience

DETERMINANTS OF INTERNAL MIGRATION IN PAKISTAN

DETERMINANTS OF IMMIGRANTS EARNINGS IN THE ITALIAN LABOUR MARKET: THE ROLE OF HUMAN CAPITAL AND COUNTRY OF ORIGIN

Quantitative Analysis of Migration and Development in South Asia

Demographic Changes and Economic Growth: Empirical Evidence from Asia

Immigration and Unemployment of Skilled and Unskilled Labor

IMPACT OF IMMIGRATION AND OUTSOURCING ON THE LABOUR MARKET A Partial Equilibrium Analysis

GENDER EQUALITY IN THE LABOUR MARKET AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT

5. Destination Consumption

Illegal Immigration, Immigration Quotas, and Employer Sanctions. Akira Shimada Faculty of Economics, Nagasaki University

Immigrant-native wage gaps in time series: Complementarities or composition effects?

Expanding the Number of Semi-skilled and Skilled Emigrant Workers from Southeast Asia to East Asia

Executive summary. Strong records of economic growth in the Asia-Pacific region have benefited many workers.

The Gravity Model on EU Countries An Econometric Approach

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY. Shuji Uchikawa

Trade, informality and jobs. Kee Beom Kim ILO Regional Office for Asia and the Pacific

Working Paper Series

Race, Religion and Skilled Labour Immigration: The. Case of Malaysia

Migration and the European Job Market Rapporto Europa 2016

THAILAND SYSTEMATIC COUNTRY DIAGNOSTIC Public Engagement

Development, Politics, and Inequality in Latin America and East Asia

Migration and Education Decisions in a Dynamic General Equilibrium Framework

CHAPTER SEVEN. Conclusion and Recommendations

Determinants of Highly-Skilled Migration Taiwan s Experiences

Online Appendices for Moving to Opportunity

8 Is East Asia a natural trade bloc? The trade complementarity index, the intensity index, and the bias index

Trends in inequality worldwide (Gini coefficients)

World trade interdependencies: a New Zealand perspective

Made in China Matters: Integration of the Global Labor Market and Global Labor Share Decline

East Asian Currency Union

Trade, Employment and Inclusive Growth in Asia. Douglas H. Brooks Jakarta, Indonesia 10 December 2012

Labour Market Reform, Rural Migration and Income Inequality in China -- A Dynamic General Equilibrium Analysis

Exploring relations between Governance, Trust and Well-being

Rural-urban Migration and Urbanization in Gansu Province, China: Evidence from Time-series Analysis

Secondary Towns and Poverty Reduction: Refocusing the Urbanization Agenda

262 Index. D demand shocks, 146n demographic variables, 103tn

The Role of Internet Adoption on Trade within ASEAN Countries plus People s Republic of China

Revista Economica 65:6 (2015) ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT AS AN INTERRELATION BETWEEN WEALTH, COMPETITIVENESS, AND INTELLECTUAL CAPITAL EMPIRICAL EVIDENCES

The Challenge of Inclusive Growth: Making Growth Work for the Poor

WORLD ECONOMIC EXPANSION in the first half of the 1960's has

MACROECONOMICS. Key Concepts. The Importance of Economic Growth. The Wealth of Nations. GDP Growth. Elements of Growth. Total output Output per capita

THE EMPLOYABILITY AND WELFARE OF FEMALE LABOR MIGRANTS IN INDONESIAN CITIES

Assessing Barriers to Trade in Education Services in Developing ESCAP Countries: An Empirical Exercise WTO/ARTNeT Short-term Research Project

How migrants choose their destination country. The case of Sweden

Migration, Intermediate Inputs and Real Wages

Ethnic networks and trade: Intensive vs. extensive margins

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

ECONOMIC GROWTH* Chapt er. Key Concepts

Determinants of International Migration

Emigration and source countries; Brain drain and brain gain; Remittances.

Impact of Japan s ODA Loan on Asian Economic Developments

Migration and Tourism Flows to New Zealand

DRIVERS OF DEMOGRAPHIC CHANGE AND HOW THEY AFFECT THE PROVISION OF EDUCATION

BBVA EAGLEs. Emerging And Growth Leading Economies Economic Outlook. Annual Report 2014 Cross-Country Emerging Markets, BBVA Research March 2014

Citation 經營と經濟, vol.90(4), pp.1-25; Issue Date Right.

A Multivariate Analysis of the Factors that Correlate to the Unemployment Rate. Amit Naik, Tarah Reiter, Amanda Stype

Building Knowledge Economy (KE) Model for Arab Countries

Chapter 7. Urbanization and Rural-Urban Migration: Theory and Policy 7-1. Copyright 2012 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Aid for Trade in Asia and the Pacific: ADB's Perspective

The Determinants of Actual Migration and the Role of Wages and Unemployment in Albania: an Empirical Analysis

Growth and Poverty Reduction: An Empirical Analysis Nanak Kakwani

An Investigation of Brain Drain from Iran to OECD Countries Based on Gravity Model

European International Virtual Congress of Researchers. EIVCR May 2015

International Journal of Humanities & Applied Social Sciences (IJHASS)

Japanese External Policies and the Asian Economic Developments

Vietnam: The Political Economy of the Middle Income Trap

Guangxi Zhuang Autonomous Region 2013

Globalization and Income Inequality: Case of Iran

Chapter 17. Other source data Macroeconomic data. Betina Dimaranan

Rural and Urban Migrants in India:

The Location Decision of Foreign Direct Investment with a Special Reference to Ethnic Network

Market Openness & The Labor Market

Outline of Presentation

Differences in remittances from US and Spanish migrants in Colombia. Abstract

Determining factors of inbound travel to Japan A stronger yen matters more for the NIEs than China

ARTNeT Trade Economists Conference Trade in the Asian century - delivering on the promise of economic prosperity rd September 2014

The Wage Effects of Immigration and Emigration

Push and Pull Factors for Japanese Manufacturing Companies Moving Production Overseas

TitleMovement of People in East Asia and

Impact of Education, Economic and Social Policies on Jobs

Charting Cambodia s Economy

Rural and Urban Migrants in India:

MIGRATION, URBANIZATION, INDUSTRIALIZATION, EXPORT PROMOTION AND ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT

The Causes of Wage Differentials between Immigrant and Native Physicians

The Impact of Foreign Workers on Labour Productivity in Malaysian Manufacturing Sector

REGIONAL INTEGRATION AND TRADE IN AFRICA: AUGMENTED GRAVITY MODEL APPROACH

Guanghua Wan Principal Economist, Asian Development Bank. Toward Higher Quality Employment in Asia

Trade led Growth in Times of Crisis Asia Pacific Trade Economists Conference 2 3 November 2009, Bangkok

Transcription:

Utah State University DigitalCommons@USU Economic Research Institute Study Papers Economics 1994 Migration of Labor From Ten Asian Countries to Japan -- An Economic Analysis Ikuko Saito Utah State University Basudeb Biswas Utah State University L. Dwight Israelsen Utah State University Follow this and additional works at: http://digitalcommons.usu.edu/eri Recommended Citation Saito, Ikuko; Biswas, Basudeb; and Israelsen, L. Dwight, "Migration of Labor From Ten Asian Countries to Japan -- An Economic Analysis" (1994). Economic Research Institute Study Papers. Paper 40. http://digitalcommons.usu.edu/eri/40 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Economics at DigitalCommons@USU. It has been accepted for inclusion in Economic Research Institute Study Papers by an authorized administrator of DigitalCommons@USU. For more information, please contact dylan.burns@usu.edu.

June 1994 ERI Study Paper #94-10 MIGRATION OF LABOR FROM TEN ASIAN COUNTRIES TO JAPAN -- AN ECONOMIC ANALYSIS By Ikuko Saito Basudeb Biswas L. Dwight Israelsen

MIGRATION OF LABOR FROM TEN ASIAN COUNTRIES TO JAPAN -- AN ECONOMIC ANALYSIS By Ikuko Saito Basudeb Biswas L. Dwight Israelsen Department of Economics Utah State University Logan, Utah 84322-3530 Telephone Number: (801) 797-2304 (All correspondence should be addressed to Basudeb Biswas.)

MIGRATION OF LABOR FROM TEN ASIAN COUNTRIES TO JAPAN -- AN ECONOMIC ANALYSIS 1. Introduction The Middle Eastern countries were a very attractive destination for migrant workers from Asian countries in the 1970s. However, the Middle East closed the door for foreign labor because of stagnant economy in the 1980s. The major new destination for people in Asia may be Japan in the 1990s. Japan faced an unprecedented influx of foreign labor from neighboring Asian countries in the 1980s. Ten major migrantsending -countries are NIES (Hong Kong, Singapore, Taiwan, and Korea), ASEAN (Malaysia, Thailand, Philippines, Indonesia), China and India. In general, poverty and a stagnant economy at a home country are considered main push factors to cause external migration to foreign countries, and prosperity and high growth rates of economy in a destination country are considered importpnt pull factors to induce people migrate from abroad into the country. However, the immigration to Japan reveals a pattern that can not be explained by those conventional classic variables. Why did the immigration take place in the 1980s when the major immigrant sending countries had higher growth rates than Japan who was in a recession because of sudden Japanese yen appreciation, resulting in decrease in

2 volume of exports and higher unemployment rates? Conventional variables for migration can hardly. provide rational explanations for the migration between Japan and ten Asian countries in the 1980s. The answer will be found in the Todaro (1969) model providing a rational explanation for accelerating rural-urban labor migration despite the existence of positive marginal products in agriculture and significant levels of urban unemployment. It is the purpose of this study to test validity of Todaro model for international labor migration. This model is generally used to explain increasing rural-urban migration within a country in spite of significant levels of urban unemployment. Section 2 briefly review the Todaro model. Section 3 of this paper reports the results of the test. Finally, Section 4 summarizes the test results and gives the concluding remarks. 2. Brief Review of Todaro Model The basic push-pull factors model is based on the traditional neoclassical theory that individuals maximize their utilities: individuals move from one country to another for better economic opportunities: they move from areas with low wages to areas with relatively high wages. According to Hicks (1932), "differences in net economic advantages chiefly

3 differences in wages, are the main causes of migration. II While there is no doubt that substantial re~l wage differences are the important factor (even though they are not the most important) to cause international labor migration, this wage disparity doesn't give a complete explanation for it. Even though there are large disparities in real income between countries, international labor migration does not necessarily happen. Wage differentials are not necessary and sufficient condi tions to cause migration. Obviously, the migrant's decision-making process is influenced by additional motives. However, the model ignores some influential determinants for the migrant's decision-making such as costs (monetary and psychic) to migrate to other countries, expected return in the future, and possibility of being unemployed abroad. The human capital approach has been developed to overcome some shortcomings of the push-pull factors model. The human capital model attributes labor migration to the differences in the present value of all the future net gains from migrating or frdm staying at home. The model is useful in explaining the direction and the stages of migration from farm to village, from village to town, from town to city, and the microeconomic of migration: who migrates. However, the model does not give a convincing explanation for persisting migration to urban areas with r ising unemployment. A special type of a human capital approach is the Todaro

4 model. Todaro (1969), and Harris and Todaro (1970) modified and extended the human capital model to 9vercome the above mentioned shortcoming: accelerating migration to urban areas with high unemployment rates. Harris and Todaro (1970) pointed out a curious economic phenomenon: despite the existence of positive marginal products in agriculture and significant levels of urban unemployment, rural-urban labor migration not only continues to exist, but indeed, appears to be accelerating. The Todaro model includes for a migrant the probability of being unemployed at the destination place. This new explanatory variable is contrary to the pure neoclassical world where wages and prices are flexible, the labor market is always in equilibrium, and therefore there is no unemployment. We briefly explain their basic idea, referring to Yotopoulos and Nugent (1976). The urban- rural differential, a, is a crucial determinant of the labor supply to the urban sector and a function of the pool of urban une mployment in the migration mode l. a can be written as, a =II W- R ( 1 ) where W a n d R are the urban and the rural wage r a te

5 reppectively, and n is the probability of obtaining a job in the urban sector in anyone period. The' probability for a worker to find a job is defined as, n= yn S-N (2 ) By substitution, we obtain, a= WyN_ R S-N (3 ) The supply of migrant labor to the urban sector, S, a function of the rural-urban differential is, as >0 aa (4 ) On the other hand, the rate of urban job creation can be expressed as a function of the wage rate and a parameter, k, where ) k is the difference between the rage _ of industrial output growth and the rate of industrial labor productivity growth. In symbols, ay <0' aw I ay>o ak (5) We can now determine the increase In the urban labor supply

6 resulting from an increase in the labor demand conditions as represented by k, that is, the increase in industrial output net of labor productivity changes, as _ as aa. ay ak - aa. ay ak ( 6 ) By substitution, (7 ) Urban unemployment increases if the increase in urban labor supply exceed? the increase in the jobs created, that is, if or Finally, we can express the wage differential, a. explicitly in terms of the probability of finding a job, and we write, as ~) (1t W-R) 2 (S - N) aa. W S a ( 9 ) The elasticity can be viewed as the "migration

7 response function / " that is I the elasticity of rural labor supply to the urban sector with respect ~o the urban-rural wage differential, properly discounted by the probability of finding a job. As long as the "migration response function" exceeds the urban-rural differential l weighted as above I the migration into the urban sector increases In spite of increasing unemployment rates in the urban. Todaro (1969) clearly concluded about accelerating rural-urban migration in spite of significant levels of urban unemployment that "as long as the urban-rural real income differential continues to rise sufficiently fast to offset any sustained increase in the rate of job creation l then even in spite of the long-run stabilizing effect of a lower probability of successfully finding modern sector employment I the lure of relatively higher permanent incomes will continue to attract a steady stream of rural migrants into the ever more congested urban slums." Later l Todaro (1986a, 1986b) expanded his original model focusing on international labor migrati9n from developing countries to developed countries. The idea behind the various Todaro models is that the decision to migrate depends on the expected relative income differential between the place of origin and the foreign destination. The expected income diff erential, in turn, depends on actual income differentials I the cost of migration and the probability of employment. In

his decision-making process, a migrant chooses the destination 8 that maximizes the discounted present val~e of the expected net gains of his labor. Formulated in mathematical terms Todaro's basic idea can be written as: n V f (0) = f P f ( t) Y f ( t) e-rtdt-c m (10) t=o. n V h ( 0) = f Ph ( t) Y h ( t) e -r t d t (11 ) t=o where V f and V h are discounted present values in the destination country and at home, respectively, P f and Ph are for a migrant the probabilities of having a job in the destination country and at home, respectively, Y f and Y h are actual (or average) income in the destination country and at home, respectively, r is the rate of time preference, and em is th~ cost of migration. Then the discounted present value of the net gain from moving abroad is expressed as: ex. (0) = V f (0) - V h (0) at t =0 (12) If ex. (0) ) 0, the economically rational potential migrant will decide to move abroad. Assuming a one-period time horizon,

9 then, the migration function can be expressed as: M = <1> (a) = <1> (Vt-V h ) =<1> [P f (U t ) Yt-C m - Ph (U h ) 'Y ll ] (13) where <1>(0) o, U t and U h are the unemployment rates in the destination country and at home, respectively. Here, we assume that the probabilities of having a job in the destination country and at home are functions of the unemployment rates in the destination country (U t ) and at home (U h ) I respectively. The Todaro model for international labor migration can be interpreted as stating that the level of migration is a function of both the wage differential between countries and the probability for a migrant to get a job in a destination country. Lundborg (1991) examined the labor flows of Nordic immigrants to Sweden during the period 1968 to 1985, and found that the differences in the level of real wages, unemployment rates between the destination and the origin are important, and that unemployment rate at destination stands out as an essential determinant for all groups of migrants. Heijke (1987) also confirmed the importance of income disparities, job opportunities in the receiving country in the study of the migration flows between the Mediterranean area

10 and North-west Europe. 3. Empirical Testing On a macroeconomic level, the magnitude of international labor migration depends on mainly wage differentials and labor market conditions in a country of origin and destination. We use GNP per capita of each country as a proxy for wage of each country. By formulating the migration equation based on the neoclassical push-pull factors approach, (18) or LMi t = a. i + P 1 + P 2 YD kit + P 3 UDk it + i t (19) where LM it the logarithm of magnitude of gross migration from country i to Japan, in year t, YJ i t YH it UJ it UH it the per capita income of Japan In year t, the per capita income of country i in year t, the unemployment rate of Japan, in year t, the unemployment rate of country i, in year t, YD1 it YJ it - YH it = standardized difference in the income per capita of Japan (YJ it ) and of o r lgln countries (YH it ),

11 YD2 it YJ it / YH it = standardized ratio in the income per capital of Japan (YJ it) and of the origin countries (YH it) I UD1 it UJ it - UH it = difference in the unemployment rate of Japan (UJ it) and of the origin countries (UH it) I UD2 it UJ it / UH it = standardized ratio in the unemployment rate of Japan (UJ it ) and of the origin countries (UH it ), dummy variable for cross-sectional unit k 1 or 2. i I, 2... 10, t I, 2... 15. This is a push-pull approach including only the very basic, but the most important motives of individual migration derived from a microeconomic view as explanatory variables. The other possible non-economic variables are excluded in this model such as distance, language, religion, etc. We test the validity of these macroeconomic model specifications empirically by ordinary least squares method, using panel data for ten Asian-Pacific countries over the period 1976 to 1990. Assuming that differences across countries can be captured in differences in the constant term, this model is referred as the least squares dummy variable

12 (LSDV) model. We measure the empirical relevance <:>f these push-pull factors by looking at the statistical - significance of independent variables. We expect that gross migration level is directly related to the unemployment rate in the origin countries, the income per capita in Japan, and the difference or ratio in the income per capita of Japan and origin countries, and inversely related to the unemployment rate in Japan, the income per capita in the origin countries, and the difference or ratio in the unemployment rate between Japan and origin countries. Straubhaar (1988). incorporated Todaro's basic microeconomic idea into a simple aggregated form, arguing that if people move to maximize their expected gains from migration or stay, where the expected gains are measured by the ratio between real income abroad and at home weighted by the probability of a new migrant obtaining a higher paid job, the aggregated Todaro migration equation should be written as, where YJ TOD = (l-uj. ) *~ ll I t YH. It (21 )

We calculate two TODs different from the above, and regress 13 three TODs separately on LM, using LSDV model. The other TODs are as follows. 1 YJ TOD2 =--*~ It UJ it YH it (22) (23) We would expect that the migration is directly related to the Todaro indexes (TOD, TOD2, TOD3). In this simplified form the Todaro.model differs from a basic push-pull approach only by combining the independent variables, analyzed separately in the push-pull approach, into a single composite index. Results The empirical results of regressing the migration flows (LM) on the independent variables show the following signs for the estimated coefficients (see Table 1). By looking at the single explanatory variables, we can see that the unemployment rates at home and in Japan show unexpected signs. Neither the "push" nor "pull" effects of changing unemployment rates at home and Japan were useful in explaining changes in the migration flows. For the "push" effect of the changes in the GNP per capita at home and the

14 "pull" effect of the changes in the GNP per capita in Japan show the expected signs. However, the former is not statistically significant at 10 % level, while the latter is statistically significant at 1% level. The income gap characterizing variable (YD1 and YD2) shows that expected sign at 1% level of significance in any models. The variable characterizing the unemployment rate difference (UD1 and UD2) shows that expected signs, but none of them are statistically significant.

Table 1. Empirical Significance for the Model-Characterizing Variables (Period: 1976-1990, estimation technique: OLS, indicated are the T-values only, model: one-way LSDV model) ============================================================ Dependent variable: LM Independent variable YJ YH UJ UH Expected sign + 8.238-0.811 7.261 + -0.667 *** *** (R 2 =0.911) 15 Independent variable YD1 UD1 / YD1 UD2 Expected sign + + 9.608-0.440 10.214-1.075 *** *** (R 2 =0. 864) (R 2 =0.865) Independent variable YD2 UD1 / YD2 UD2 Expected sign + + 4.306-0.776 5.002-0.538 *** *** (R 2 =0.796) (R 2 =0.796) Independent variable TOD / TOD2 / TOD3 Expected sign + + + 5.027 3.314 10.198 *** *** *** (R 2 =0.795) (R 2 =0.758) (R 2 =0. 755) ------------------------------------------------------------- ) *** = significant at the 1% level Note) When a coeffeicnet has an unexpected sigh, a two-tail test of the null hypothesis is applied and we will use a one-tail test otherwise. ============================================================ The push-pull factors approach does well in explaining migration flows from Asian countries to Japan. By looking at the sign of the coefficient for the Todaro-

16 model-characterizing variables TOD, TOD2, TOD3, we can see that the all of them have the expected s~gh at 1% level of significance, and TOD3 has the highest t-value. Interpretation of Results All variables characterizing unemployment have the unexpected signs or insignificant coefficients. These unexpected signs or insignificant coefficients on an unemployment rate variable in explaining migration confirms the findings of several empirical studies on internal labor migration. Some possible causes for this finding can be attributed to the use of total migration as a proxy for labor force migration or the ignorance of individual characteristics of the migrants like age or education. In this study on international migration, we focus on migrants as an economic institution, not on individual migrants. Therefore, the economic characteristics of them are expressed by aggrega~es. As a result, the quality of the empirical results depends on the extent to which simplifying assumptions correspond to reality. Many studies have demonstrated that the disaggregation of migrants by types (age, sex, race and marital status) lead to significantly different conclusions. It is also possible to find the answer to this unexpected phenomenon in the Todaro (1969) 's explanation for continuous and accelerating migration flows from rural to urban despite

17 high unemployment in urban areas. The results show that the Todaro's model is applicable to internation~l labor migration, too. In fact, Japan's higher unemployment rates in the late of 1980s did not affect negatively migration flows from Asian countries. The results show that the income in Japan and the income differences are very important factors to explain migration as expected by theory. Among TOD variables, TOD3 is statistically significant with highest t-value. The result suggests that migration change is attributed to the expected net gains in year t from migration to Japan, calculated by [the probability of. obtaining a higher paid job (measured by (l-uj t ), the employment rate in Japan in year t), times the income per capita in Japan] [the probability of obtaining a job (measured by (l-uh t ), times the income per capita at home]. 4. Conclusion This paper investigated the effectiveness of the Todaro model for international labor migration. The paper used the LSDV (least square dummy variables) model, utilizing panel data for ten major migrant - sending countries over the period, 1976 to 1990. The results found in the push-pull factors model that income gaps be tween countries were essential factors to cause migration, but unemployment rates were not.

18 This study proved the validity of the Todaro model for international labor migration: as lon~ as the income differential between countries continues to-rise sufficiently fast to offset any sustained increase in the rate of job creation, then even in spite of the relatively high unemployment rates at a destination, the lure of relatively higher incomes will continue to attract a steady stream of migrants from Asian countries. The Following suggestions are made to extend the present study. In this paper, wage rates and unemployment rates were treated as exogenous variables. But thos~ variables are also affected by international migration. Hence it would be appropriate to develop a model based on simultaneous equations model including equations for labor mobility, income and unemployment rates.

19 REFERENCES Gordon, Ian and Thirlwall, A. P., ets., European Factor Mobility: Trends and Consequences, New York: St. Martin's Press, 1989. Harris, John R. and Todaro, Michael P., IIMigration, Unemployment and Development: A Two-Sector Analysis, II American Economic Review, 60, 126-142, 1970. Lundborg, Per, "Determinants of Migration in the Nordic Labor Market," Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 93(3}, 363-375, 1991. OECD, The Future of Migration, Paris: OECD, 1987. Sapir, Andre, "Economic Reform and Migration in Yugoslavia, II Journal of Development Economics, 9, 149-181, 1981. Straubhaar, Thomas, On the Economics of International Labor Migration, West Germany: Verlag Paul Haupt Bern und Stuttgart, 1988. Todaro, M. P., "A Model of Labor Migration and Urban Unemployment in Less Developed Countries, II American Economic Review, 59, 138-148, 1969, Todaro, M. P., "International Migration Domestic Unemployment, and Urbanization: A Three-Sector Model," Population Council, Center for Policy Studies. Working Paper; 124. New York: The Population Council, 1986a. Todaro, M. P., "A Theory of Illegal International Migration from Developing Countries," Population Council, Center for Policy Studies. Workind Paper; 126. New York: The Populat ion Council, 1986b.