Does Elite Capture Matter? Local Elites and Targeted Welfare Programs in Indonesia

Similar documents
NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES DOES ELITE CAPTURE MATTER? LOCAL ELITES AND TARGETED WELFARE PROGRAMS IN INDONESIA

From Evaluation to Policy Impact: Improving Transparency and Take-up of Indonesia s Subsidized Rice Distribution Program

PANCHAYATI RAJ AND POVERTY ALLEVIATION IN WEST BENGAL: SUMMARY OF RESEARCH FINDINGS. Pranab Bardhan and Dilip Mookherjee.

Commuting and Minimum wages in Decentralized Era Case Study from Java Island. Raden M Purnagunawan

Publicizing malfeasance:

The interaction effect of economic freedom and democracy on corruption: A panel cross-country analysis

A Spatial Analysis of Foreign Aid and Civil Society

: Corruption Lecture 4

VULNERABILITY STUDY IN KAKUMA CAMP

2. Participation and Governance

Local Corruption and Popular Support for Fuel Subsidy Reform in Indonesia 1. Jordan Kyle, IFPRI

Direct Democracy and Local Public Goods Evidence from a Field Experiment in Indonesia

Are Caste Categories Misleading? The Relationship Between Gender and Jati in Three Indian States

Migration and Consumption Insurance in Bangladesh

Evaluating antipoverty transfer programmes in Latin America and sub- Saharan Africa: Better policies? Better politics?

Trends in Poverty and Inequality in Decentralising Indonesia

Governance, Politics, and Conditional Cash Transfer Programs

Kakuma Refugee Camp: Household Vulnerability Study

Efficiency Consequences of Affirmative Action in Politics Evidence from India

Chapter 2 Comparative Economic Development

THE EMPLOYABILITY AND WELFARE OF FEMALE LABOR MIGRANTS IN INDONESIAN CITIES

Direct Democracy and Local Public Goods: Evidence from a Field Experiment in Indonesia

Can information that raises voter expectations improve accountability?

Nepotism and Punishment: The (Mis-)Performance of Elected Local Officials in the Philippines

The Non-Democratic Roots of Elite Capture: Evidence from Soeharto Mayors in Indonesia

Unraveling the Welfare Effects of Administrative and Political Decentralization in Indonesia

Indonesia s Unified Database (UDB)

Evidence from Randomized Evaluations of Governance Programs. Cristobal Marshall

Research Report. How Does Trade Liberalization Affect Racial and Gender Identity in Employment? Evidence from PostApartheid South Africa

Comparative Economic Development

Presentation of Rise and Fall of Local Elections in China by Martinez-Bravo, Miguel, Qian and Yao

Does Participation Strengthen Civil Society?

Preliminary Effects of Oversampling on the National Crime Victimization Survey

The Impact of Licensing Decentralization on Firm Location Choice: the Case of Indonesia

The Impact of the Interaction between Economic Growth and Democracy on Human Development: Cross-National Analysis

A Global Economy-Climate Model with High Regional Resolution

Poverty and Inequality

Cash or Condition? Evidence from a Randomized Cash Transfer Program

Who is at the Wheel When Communities Drive Development? Evidence from the Philippines

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US

Reducing Poverty in the Arab World Successes and Limits of the Moroccan. Lahcen Achy. Beirut, Lebanon July 29, 2010

Poverty and Migration in the Digital Age: Experimental Evidence on Mobile Banking in Bangladesh

International Remittances and Brain Drain in Ghana

Remittances and the Brain Drain: Evidence from Microdata for Sub-Saharan Africa

Government Decentralization as a Commitment

Unequal Recovery, Labor Market Polarization, Race, and 2016 U.S. Presidential Election. Maoyong Fan and Anita Alves Pena 1

Full file at

Remittances and Poverty. in Guatemala* Richard H. Adams, Jr. Development Research Group (DECRG) MSN MC World Bank.

Governance and public service delivery in India

Table A.1: Experiment Sample Distribution and National Demographic Benchmarks Latino Decisions Sample, Study 1 (%)

Split Decisions: Household Finance when a Policy Discontinuity allocates Overseas Work

Development Economics: Microeconomic issues and Policy Models

Spatial Inequality in Cameroon during the Period

The Correlates of Wealth Disparity Between the Global North & the Global South. Noelle Enguidanos

Why Political Reservations?

Vote Buying and Clientelism

Social Dimension S o ci al D im en si o n 141

Economics 361. Political economy and economic development

How Important Are Labor Markets to the Welfare of Indonesia's Poor?

Online Appendices for Moving to Opportunity

Do Migrants Improve Governance at Home? Evidence from a Voting Experiment

EVALUATION NOTE. Evaluating Trickle Up s Graduation Programs in India. Findings from a quasi-experimental evaluation in West Bengal and Jharkhand.

SIERRA LEONE 2012 ELECTIONS PROJECT PRE-ANALYSIS PLAN: POLLING CENTERCONSTITUENCY LEVEL INTERVENTIONS

Decentralization and Development: Dilemmas, Trade-offs and Safeguards. Pranab Bardhan and Dilip Mookherjee

Does Political Reservation for Minorities Affect Child Labor? Evidence from India. Elizabeth Kaletski University of Connecticut

Pathways to graduation: is graduation from social safety net support possible and why? Evidence from sub-saharan Africa

The University of Warwick. Local Governance and Contemporary Development in Indonesia: The Long Shadow of the Adat Law

Research Statement. Jeffrey J. Harden. 2 Dissertation Research: The Dimensions of Representation

Media and Political Persuasion: Evidence from Russia

5. Destination Consumption

SIERRA LEONE 2012 ELECTIONS PROJECT PRE-ANALYSIS PLAN: INDIVIDUAL LEVEL INTERVENTIONS

Natural resources, electoral behaviour and social spending in Latin America

Educational Qualifications of Village Leaders in North India: Implications for Public Service Delivery

Appendix for Citizen Preferences and Public Goods: Comparing. Preferences for Foreign Aid and Government Programs in Uganda

Self-Selection and the Earnings of Immigrants

Measuring Vote-Selling: Field Evidence from the Philippines

The Redistributive Effects of Political Reservation for Minorities: Evidence from India

Why hasn t decentralisation done more to improve the quality of life for Indonesian villagers?

Test Bank for Economic Development. 12th Edition by Todaro and Smith

Internal and international remittances in India: Implications for Household Expenditure and Poverty

The Economic Impact of International Remittances on Poverty and Household Consumption and Investment in Indonesia

SocialSecurityEligibilityandtheLaborSuplyofOlderImigrants. George J. Borjas Harvard University

List of Themes for Master Theses

WHY IS TORONTO DRAWING NEW WARD BOUNDARIES? Ward Population Background Brief. Revised, July 2015

Measuring Corruption: Myths and Realities

Poverty and Inequality

Political Reservation and Substantive Representation: Evidence from Indian Panchayats

Corruption and business procedures: an empirical investigation

Measuring and Reducing the Impact of Corruption in Infrastructure

Local Agency Costs of Political Centralization

Extended Families across Mexico and the United States. Extended Abstract PAA 2013

14.74 Foundations of Development Policy. Syllabus

Does poverty alleviation increase migration? evidence from Mexico

Poverty, Income Inequality, and Growth in Pakistan: A Pooled Regression Analysis

Yet the World Bank Enterprise Surveys suggest that there is much room for improvement in service quality and accountability

Household Inequality and Remittances in Rural Thailand: A Lifecycle Perspective

Governance and Resilience

There is a seemingly widespread view that inequality should not be a concern

Lahore University of Management Sciences. ECON 4410 Issues in Economic Policy

Globalization and Poverty Forthcoming, University of

Transcription:

Does Elite Capture Matter? Local Elites and Targeted Welfare Programs in Indonesia Rema Hanna, Harvard Kennedy School Joint with: Vivi Alatas, World Bank; Abhijit Banerjee, MIT ; Benjamin A. Olken, MIT ; Ririn Purnamasari, World Bank; Matthew Wai-Poi, World Bank

Motivation Series of projects designed to understand how to improve the targeting of social programs in developing countries Research conducted with the Indonesian Government to provide insights into PPLS 2011 (Indonesia s unified targeting database) Large concern over the role of local leaders in the process

Motivation Social scientists and policy practitioners weary of local elites (Wade, 1982; Dreze and Sen, 1989; Bardhan and Mookherjee, 2000; Acemoglu, 2006; Acemoglu, Reed, and Robinsion, 2012, etc.) Development policy often designed to marginalize local leaders, with potentially significant costs E.g. Targeting: better information and monitoring at local level (Alderman, 2002; Galasso and Ravallion, 2005; Alatas et al, 2012; Bardhan and Mookherjee, 2005) central governments are often reluctant to devolve decision making, preferring to allocate benefits based on less discretionary proxy-means test systems (Coady, Grosh, and Hoddinott, 2004).

Decentralization Done in a way that minimizes role of local elites community driven development : allow communities to choose/implement infrastructure projects Designed to devolve decision making and project implementation to citizens (Casey, Glennerster, and Miguel forthcoming, Mansuri and Rao, 2012). Citizens ability and skills to do so may be weaker than local leaders (Khwaja, forthcoming) Possible long run effects: the incentive of local leaders to acquire skills and demonstrate performance is reduced (see, e.g., Myerson 2009).

This paper Estimate the extent of local elite capture in targeted welfare programs, and compare the loss from capture against other forms of targeting error Utilize both cross-sectional data on several targeted transfer programs and a high-stakes field experiment that we conducted in Indonesia, which ranked 118 out of 176 countries on the 2012 Transparency International s Corruption Perception Index

Household Survey Data Dec 2010 to Mar 2011: 3,998 households in 400 villages chosen from 2500 PKH expansion villages (another 200 in self-targeting) 3 provinces: Lampung, South Sumatera, and Central Java (30% urban/70% rural) Collected data on: Household Per Capita Consumption Detailed networks data: Asked villagers to name formal and informal leaders and then all of their relatives in the hamlet (2 votes) Access to targeted transfer programs

Methods Estimated the following specification: Received ivs =β 0 +β 1 ln(pce) ivs+ β 2 Elite ivs + δ s +ε ivs Elite: Leaders + Relatives Robust to different definitions of relatives Separate by type of elite (formal/informal) Include strata FE (δ s ), cluster at village level Compare capture across: With more and less slots relative to poverty line With elected versus appointed leaders

Programs Targeted Transfer Programs (Survey Data): BLT (2005/2008): UCT: $10 a month to about 19.2 million poor households PPLS 2008 and PSE 2005 Jamkesmas: Health Insurance Health Insurance for up to 76 million people District quota from PPLS/PSE; to populate quota, PPLS/PSE or recommendations from National Family Planning Board (in reality, could also join with other methods) Raskin: Subsidized rice program Village quotas, community meetings to populate list (most often, when actually held, just elites attend meeting) Matched survey data to PPLS 2008

Experimental Variation Aspects of the programs may have already been designed or implemented in a way to reduce elite capture in parts of programs/areas where central government is worried it would be a problem In 400 villages, we experimentally vary the ability of elites to control targeting process in Indonesia s real conditional cash transfer program (PKH), which gives $150 per year for up to 6 years per beneficiary

Experimental Design 400 villages randomized to one of three treatments: PPLS method: status quo procedure Community Input Full: Full community invited to update the list; shown 75 percent of the subvillage s beneficiary quota; depending on subtreatment, add or add/replace individuals Community Input Elite: 5-8 local leaders, both formal and informal, to the updating meetings

Data for Experimental Results Survey data where we collected baseline data on consumption and networks Matched to administrative data on targeting outcomes Endline survey data on who received PKH

Outline of Results Existing Social Programs Experimental Results Formal versus informal leaders Slots relative to poverty line Democracy Other forms of patronage Benchmarking loss from capture against other targeting losses

Do not observe evidence of capture in unconditional cash programs or rice program Conditional on LPCE, elites are 2.9 percentage points (6.8 percent) more likely to receive health insurance program (Jamkesmas) Robust to different definition of elite, robust to only leaders (not relatives), robust to control for whether one belongs to similar social groups as elite, etc

2008 PPLS survey (targeting lists) 1- Near Poor (36 Percent), 2-Poor (26 percent), 3- very poor (~10 percent) No evidence that elites are more likely to be on the list, and if anything less likely to be on bottom of the lists (conditional on consumption)

Experimental Results (PKH) No evidence that elites are more likely to get PKH Difference between PMT/community not significant No difference between meetings with full community or elite only meetings

Equivalent to 2008 PPLS very poor Similar results to 2008 list: no evidence of that elite and relatives less more likely to be on the list (in fact, less likely) No difference between full and elite meetings

Results Not much evidence of elite capture thus far Results similar to experiment (Alatas, et al 2012) where we compare different forms of community targeting with PMT with lower stakes (one time payment of $3) Next question: are all elites the same? Formal Elites: hold formal roles (hamlet head, member of the legislative council) Informal Elites: Tokoh Masyarakat : teachers, religious leaders, rich people

Formal Informal Formal elites more likely, informal elites less likely No difference on the targeting outcomes (PPLS), suggesting that adjustments happen when programs actually implemented (and not during targeting stage)

Formal Informal Neither formal or informal elites more likely to receive PKH (no difference between full community and elite only meetings) Targeting results: less effect of elite

Where along distribution does manipulation occur? PKH is ~10 percent of the population, while 36% UCT, 42% Health insurance, 75% rice subsidy We find less capture by elites for targeting outcomes on of the very poor on the 2008 targeting survey Natural variation in number of slots a village receives relative to its poverty line (over or under quota)

Elite more likely to get benefits when more slots available Formal elites only steal when there is left over after taking care of the very poor, or harder for elite to pretend to be poor when there are fewer slots? May explain less capture in PKH than other programs

Democracy as Constraint on Capture? Urban villages generally have appointed village heads; rural villages generally have elected ones Response to demographic shifts slow variation in democracy (Martinez-Bravo, 2012)

Democracy does not appear to be a constraint We find no effect of the village leader being elected on whether elites are more likely to be on the 2008 targeting lists or BLT If anything, in elected areas: formal elites are differentially more likely to be in the PKH targeting list, get PKH, and receive health insurance or rice

Other forms of patronage So far, we have focus on capture of the form of putting themselves or their relatives on the list May provide patronage to certain individuals or groups other than those related to them. Hard to observe since we do not know who these individuals are But, we can test whether the observed characteristics of individuals chosen by elites versus non-elites matters (conditional on LPCE)

Other forms of patronage We explore 22 characteristics including household size, share of children, debt, alcohol spending, friendliness, hardworkingness, minority status, contributions to village level public goods First test whether leaders and non-leaders have same preferences/information on who is poor Baseline survey: individual rankings of poverty Regress rankings on characteristics No difference: coefficients looks similar for leaders versus non-leaders

Experimental Results Compare characteristic for those chosen in elite only meeting versus full community (both actual outcomes and targeting outcomes) Coefficients tend to look very similar in terms of sign, magnitude and significance levels Receives PKH: p-value of joint test=0.17 Targeting list PKH: p-value of joint test=0.77

Benchmarking Capture to Targeting Error We find that formal elites are more likely to receive transfers, conditional on their consumption level, during the implementation of certain targeted transfer programs We next want to ask: is this loss economically significant and how does it compare to other forms of targeting error? Back of envelope calculation Formal analysis

Back of the Envelope Calculation Some facts: Formal elites are 9 percent richer than non-elites At most 8 percentage points more likely to receive benefits than non-elites (health insurance) Represent at most 15 percent of the population Average consumption level of beneficiaries would be three tenths of a percentage point higher with formal elite capture than without it 0.15 (share of elites in population) (0.08 / 0.42) (relative increase in elite s probability of receiving the program) 0.09 (elite consumption relative to non-elite consumption)

Formal Analysis Assume a CRRA utility function with ρ=3; calculate utility for all households in our sample without the program. Calculate expected utility from each social program, both with and without elite capture. For each household: calculate their predicted probability of receiving benefits from a program, and the predicted probability of receiving benefits from the same model setting the ELITE variable equal to 0 (without an elite premium). Keep the #of beneficiaries the same with/without capture, but just change the probability of a household receiving benefits Assign each household the benefits from a program based on their predicted probability, and then calculate the total utility under the program with and without capture using the two different predicted probabilities

Two additional benchmarks 1. Utility from the program under perfect targeting (rank households by baseline consumption) 2. High quality PMT using data from our baseline survey rather than the government survey for the entire population (not just pre-identified) Share of the possible utility gain each scenario obtains, where 0 is the utility without the program and 100% is the maximum utility with the program under perfect consumption targeting.

PKH Exp BLT05 BLT08 Jamkesmas Raskin With Elite on 26.58% 57.37% 60.20% 61.75% 88.33% With Elite off 26.35% 57.98% 60.98% 62.93% 88.79% Under perfect PMT-targeting 41.37% 75.73% 77.26% 78.38% 94.89% Differences between elite and non-elite are small: eliminating formal elite capture entirely would improve welfare by about 0.54 percentage points In contrast, gain in utility from better implementing PMT is quantitatively large Largely due to data quality: implemented PMT using our high quality survey data (rather than government data) over the government s pre-identified household list results in a 36.99 percent welfare gain for PKH

Conclusion Despite the perceived high level of corruption in targeted programs, we find very little evidence of elite capture formal elites are more likely to capture programs than informal local leaders The manipulation of the system occurs during program implementation, and not during the targeting surveys

Conclusions Relatively larger gains from focusing on methods to improve our ability to predict consumption and data quality Currently conducting research to understand if we can improve on existing targeting formulas Costs of elite capture may not be that large relative to the benefits of engaging local leaders in the process and providing additional training and support