Asymmetric Partisan Biases in Perceptions of Political Parties

Similar documents
Modeling Political Information Transmission as a Game of Telephone

Partisan Nation: The Rise of Affective Partisan Polarization in the American Electorate

Money or Loyalty? The Effect of Inconsistent Information Shortcuts on Voting Defection

Changing Parties or Changing Attitudes?: Uncovering the Partisan Change Process

AMERICAN JOURNAL OF UNDERGRADUATE RESEARCH VOL. 3 NO. 4 (2005)

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES PARTY AFFILIATION, PARTISANSHIP, AND POLITICAL BELIEFS: A FIELD EXPERIMENT

POLICY VOTING IN SENATE ELECTIONS: The Case of Abortion

A Distinction with a Difference? Investigating the Difference Between Liberals and Progressives

Source Cues, Partisan Identities, and Political Value Expression

The Ideological Foundations of Affective Polarization in the U.S. Electorate

Voting and Elections Preliminary Syllabus

It s Not Easy Being Green: Minor Party Labels as Heuristic Aids

Party identification represents the most stable and

Issue Importance and Performance Voting. *** Soumis à Political Behavior ***

The Declining Value of Moderation in US House Elections. Henry A. Kim University of California, Santa Barbara

Poli 123 Political Psychology

Vote Likelihood and Institutional Trait Questions in the 1997 NES Pilot Study

Party identification, electoral utilities, and voting choice

Change in the Components of the Electoral Decision. Herbert F. Weisberg The Ohio State University. May 2, 2008 version

Ohio State University

PSCI4120 Public Opinion and Participation

Issues, Ideology, and the Rise of Republican Identification Among Southern Whites,

Ai, C. and E. Norton Interaction Terms in Logit and Probit Models. Economic Letters

The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate

Polls and Elections. Presidential Reelectionpsq_

Concurrent Elections and Voter Attention: How voters search for political information in crowded campaign environments

Yea or Nay: Do Legislators Benefit by Voting Against their Party? Christopher P. Donnelly Department of Politics Drexel University

Supplementary Materials A: Figures for All 7 Surveys Figure S1-A: Distribution of Predicted Probabilities of Voting in Primary Elections

THE ELECTORATE'S PARTISAN EVALUATIONS: EVIDENCE OF A CONTINUING DEMOCRATIC EDGE JOHN G. GEER

A Report on the Social Network Battery in the 1998 American National Election Study Pilot Study. Robert Huckfeldt Ronald Lake Indiana University

POLI 300 Fall 2010 PROBLEM SET #5B: ANSWERS AND DISCUSSION

The Impact of Media Endorsements in Legislative Elections

A Tool for All People, but Not All Occasions: How Voting Heuristics Interact with Political Knowledge and Environment

Cross-Pressured Partisans: How Voters Make up Their Minds when Parties and Issues Diverge. 1

Pavel Yakovlev Duquesne University. Abstract

Should the Democrats move to the left on economic policy?

Each election cycle, candidates, political parties,

Party Polarization, Party Brands, and Responsible Party Government: The Increasing Role of Congressional Performance in American Politics

Voting and Elections Preliminary Syllabus

How Incivility in Partisan Media (De-)Polarizes. the Electorate

Political Science 820 Proseminar in American Politics. Spring 2002 Tuesday 12:40-3: North Kedzie Hall

SHOULD THE DEMOCRATS MOVE TO THE LEFT ON ECONOMIC POLICY? By Andrew Gelman and Cexun Jeffrey Cai Columbia University

How Political Signals Affect Public Support for Judicial Nominations: Evidence from a Conjoint Experiment

American Voters and Elections

Amy Tenhouse. Incumbency Surge: Examining the 1996 Margin of Victory for U.S. House Incumbents

Party Responsiveness and Mandate Balancing *

Keep it Clean? How Negative Campaigns Affect Voter Turnout

Coordination and Policy Moderation at Midterm

Retrospective Voting

Partisan Hearts, Minds, and Souls: Candidate Religion and Partisan Voting

Herbert F. Weisberg Steven P. Nawara

Social Networks as a Shortcut to Correct Voting

Persuasion in Politics

Does the Ideological Proximity Between Congressional Candidates and Voters Affect Voting Decisions in Recent U.S. House Elections?

Res Publica 29. Literature Review

Turnout and Strength of Habits

Party Hacks and True Believers: The Effect of Party Affiliation on Political Preferences

Party, Constituency, and Constituents in the Process of Representation

Practice Questions for Exam #2

THE IDEOLOGICAL GAP: BEHAVIORAL TRENDS OF THE POLITICALLY ACTIVE, A Thesis presented to. the Faculty of the Graduate School

Why Do We Pay Attention to Candidate Race, Gender, and Party? A Theory of the Development of Political Categorization Schemes

DATA ANALYSIS USING SETUPS AND SPSS: AMERICAN VOTING BEHAVIOR IN PRESIDENTIAL ELECTIONS

Author(s) Title Date Dataset(s) Abstract

Motivated Responses to Political Communications: Framing, Party Cues, and Science Information

PS 5030: Seminar in American Government & Politics Fall 2008 Thursdays 6:15pm-9:00pm Room 1132, Old Library Classroom

What Goes with Red and Blue? Assessing Partisan Cognition Through Conjoint Classification Experiments

Amanda Bittner, Memorial University Introduction

CALIFORNIA INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY

The Gender Gap, the Marriage Gap, and Their Interaction

I A I N S T I T U T E O F T E C H N O L O G Y C A LI F O R N

Who Votes Now? And Does It Matter?

The Persuasion Effects of Political Endorsements

Author(s) Title Date Dataset(s) Abstract

The Case of the Disappearing Bias: A 2014 Update to the Gerrymandering or Geography Debate

Battleground 2016: new game. June 30, 2016

Measuring the Political Sophistication of Voters in the Netherlands and the United States

THE WORKMEN S CIRCLE SURVEY OF AMERICAN JEWS. Jews, Economic Justice & the Vote in Steven M. Cohen and Samuel Abrams

Information, visibility and elections: Why electoral outcomes differ when voters are better informed

Measuring the Political Sophistication of Voters in the Netherlands and the United States

FOR RELEASE APRIL 26, 2018

Supplementary Materials for Strategic Abstention in Proportional Representation Systems (Evidence from Multiple Countries)

Chapter Four: Chamber Competitiveness, Political Polarization, and Political Parties

IDEOLOGY, THE AFFORDABLE CARE ACT RULING, AND SUPREME COURT LEGITIMACY

The Behavioral Foundations of the Midterm Effect

1. The Relationship Between Party Control, Latino CVAP and the Passage of Bills Benefitting Immigrants

USING MULTI-MEMBER-DISTRICT ELECTIONS TO ESTIMATE THE SOURCES OF THE INCUMBENCY ADVANTAGE 1

Understanding Taiwan Independence and Its Policy Implications

Biased but moderate voters

Cross-District Variation in Split-Ticket Voting

Constituents Policy Perceptions and Approval of their Members of Congress *

What s So Amazing about Really Deep Thoughts? Cognitive Style and Political Misperceptions

IDEOLOGY AND VOTE CHOICE IN THE 2004 ELECTION

Online Appendix 1: Treatment Stimuli

CONGRESSIONAL CAMPAIGN EFFECTS ON CANDIDATE RECOGNITION AND EVALUATION

Proposal for the 2016 ANES Time Series. Quantitative Predictions of State and National Election Outcomes

CREST CENTRE FOR RESEARCH INTO ELECTIONS AND SOCIAL TRENDS

CHAPTER II THE CONCEPT OF POLITICAL SOPHISTICATION

VOTER BEHAVIOR IN ELECTIONS WITHOUT PARTY LABELS. John P. Lappie

PERCEIVED ACCURACY AND BIAS IN THE NEWS MEDIA A GALLUP/KNIGHT FOUNDATION SURVEY

Elite Polarization and Mass Political Engagement: Information, Alienation, and Mobilization

Transcription:

Asymmetric Partisan Biases in Perceptions of Political Parties Jonathan Woon Carnegie Mellon University April 6, 2007 Abstract This paper investigates whether there is partisan bias in the way that individuals see the parties positions on issues and whether that bias can be accounted for by differences in information or the way in which citizens deal with information shortfalls. Using data from the 2004 NES survey, I find that there are significant differences in perception between different groups of partisan identifiers and that while much of the bias can be accounted for, some remains. The remaining biases also reveal interesting asymmetries between Democratic and Republican partisans and across issues. Prepared for the 65 th Annual National Conference of the Midwest Political Science Association, Chicago, Illinois.

The two major parties are among the most permanent objects in the American political system, and such longevity implies that citizens are exposed to a steady stream of information about them. Given the wealth of information about parties, citizens should more or less agree about what each party stands for, even if they disagree about the relative merits of those policies. 1 But do they? An alternative perspective, grounded in the view that attitudes or party loyalties shape perceptions (Berelson et al 1954; Campbell et al 1960; Bartels 2002), suggests that citizens will selectively perceive the political environment and that individuals who differ in their evaluations of the parties will also perceive them differently. Understanding individual-level differences in how the parties are perceived is important for several reasons. Much of the previous research on political perception, which focuses on candidates, emphasizes the important role that party cues and stereotypes play in shaping citizens voting decisions when information about candidates is ambiguous or costly to acquire (Conover and Feldman 1989, Feldman and Conover 1983, Rahn 1993, Koch 2001). If there are biases in perceptions of the parties, then those biases will also lead to biased perceptions of candidates. Consistent with the behavioral research, rational choice theorizing emphasizes the electoral incentives that political leaders have to shape the public s perceptions of their parties that is, their brand names or reputations (Aldrich 1995; Downs 1957; Snyder and Ting 2002). The existence of partisan bias implies that shaping and altering party images is much more constrained than it would otherwise be. If partisan bias is too 1 This assumes that individuals are Bayesian learners or unbiased information processors (Gerber and Green 1998, 1999), which is discussed below. 1

severe then the costs of party leadership may be high, the benefits of maintaining the brand name too small, and decentralized parties would result. 2 In this paper, I first investigate whether there is partisan bias in the way that individuals see the parties positions. After showing that such biases exist and describing their patterns across parties and issues, I then develop three possible explanations. Information is the common thread between these explanations. Biases might result from differences in information, from biases in the way that the same information is processed, or from differences in the way that citizens make up for their lack of information through shortcuts and heuristics. The empirical analysis suggests that some amount of bias is due to both differences in information and heuristic reasoning but that some bias remains, which is possibly due to biased information processing. The remaining biases are smaller and confined to a few issues, and are also interestingly asymmetric across parties and issues. In the conclusion I discuss implications of my findings for party competition. Perceptions of Party Positions in 2004 To what extent are there partisan differences in what people think the parties stand for? Figure 1 shows the average perceived positions of the parties on seven issue scales for each category of partisan identifiers from the 2004 National Election Studies (NES) survey. 3 Each scale is adjusted so that -3 is the liberal position and 3 is the conservative position. The horizontal lines in Figure 1 depict the extent of partisan bias for each group that is, the difference between a partisan group s perceptions and pure independents perceptions (who are a neutral baseline and therefore by definition 2 By decentralized I mean that party leaders ability to control and discipline the party is weak (both in terms of candidate selection and influencing elected members behavior). 3 The endpoints of each issue scale are defined in the Appendix. 2

unbiased). 4 Looking across the several issues, there appears to be a great deal of partisan bias. For strong partisan identifiers of both parties, this bias is sometimes as much as an entire scale point on a seven point scale. [Figure 1 about here.] In terms of the parties general liberal-conservative positions, there is a striking asymmetry between what Democratic and Republican identifiers perceive. Republican identifiers (including independent leaners) perceive the Democratic Party as much more liberal, and the Republican Party as somewhat more conservative, than pure independents do. In contrast, regardless of the strength of identification, the perceptions of Democratic partisans do not differ much from those of pure independents. This asymmetry is quantified more precisely in Table 1, which shows results from regressions of party perceptions on dummy variables for partisan identification. The excluded category is pure independents so the estimated constant is their average perception. The other coefficients are equivalent to differences in mean perceptions between the partisan groups and independents, which is an estimate of partisan bias. Consistent with the visual analysis, the partisan bias for each Republican-identifying group is statistically significant in terms of perceptions for both parties, while partisan bias for Democratic-identifying group is not statistically significant in all but one case. Interestingly, the exception is that independent Democratic leaners perceive Republicans as slightly more conservative than pure independents and other Democratic identifiers, but no differently than independent Republican leaners. [Table 1 about here.] 4 This is different from claiming that pure independents are the most accurate, only that they cannot be biased partisans because by definition they are not partisan. 3

The asymmetric pattern that appears for the liberal-conservative scale does not, as a whole, appear for the other issue scales. Only Republican identifiers perceptions of the Democratic Party on the defense spending and abortion scales are similar. Reversing the asymmetry, Democratic identifiers perceive the Republican Party to be more conservative on the services and spending, guaranteed jobs, and aid to blacks scales than others do. With the exception of strong Democrats, perceptions of the Republican Party s position on abortion are remarkably consistent across partisan categories. All but one of the remaining perceptions display a partisan extremism effect where the degree of partisan bias increases with the strength of partisan identification but the direction of bias is the same for both Democratic and Republican identifiers. Perceptions of the Democratic Party s position on the spending and services, guaranteed jobs, aid to blacks, and women s equality issues and the Republican Party s position on defense spending all appear to follow this pattern. For two of the perceptual items (guaranteed jobs and aid to blacks) there is also an asymmetry: strong Republican identifiers perceive the Democratic Party as more liberal than strong Democratic identifiers do. Perceptions of the Republican Party s stance on the role of women in society display quite a different pattern. While Democratic leaning and identifying individuals see the Republican Party as slightly more conservative than pure independents do, Republican identifiers see the party as more liberal on this issue. The initial analysis of 2004 NES data clearly shows that different groups of partisan identifiers perceive the parties ideological and issue positions differently. It is important to note that while a regression of perceived positions on a single seven point 4

party identification variable, such as in Bartels (2002) analysis, would uncover some of the partisan bias uncovered here, doing so would mask the two main patterns in the data. One is an asymmetric pattern of partisan bias where individuals identifying with one party perceive positions to be more extreme than pure independents and individuals identifying with the other party while latter partisan groups perceive positions similarly. The other is a partisan extremism effect where stronger partisan identifiers see the parties positions as more extreme than pure independents and weak identifiers. Explaining Perceptions and Partisan Bias What explains partisan biases in perceptions? Having information is critical to forming beliefs about others, and the literature on public opinion and political psychology suggests three potential sources of differences in political perceptions related to how information is acquired or used. There may be differences in information processing, differences in the information observed, or differences related to the way in which people make up for the lack of information. Below, I develop testable hypotheses regarding differences in information and the use of political heuristics. Information and Information Processing A classic explanation for perceptual bias in the voting literature (Campbell et al 1960) posits that partisanship raises a perceptual screen that biases the assimilation of information (accepting favorable information and rejecting unfavorable information) or its construal (interpreting the same information differently). Recently, Bartels (2002) argues that it is exactly this filtering through the lens of partisanship that explains 5

differences in political perceptions. His analysis shows that partisan differences remain after accounting for prior beliefs, measurement error, and uniform changes in opinion. Although he documents partisan bias, he does not provide any evidence that it can be explained by biased information processing. In contrast, Taber and Lodge (2006) show in a controlled laboratory setting that motivated reasoning does cause bias in information processing, but their experiment pertains to arguments for and against particular policies rather than perceptions of candidate or party positions, leaving open the question of whether the latter may also be affected by motivated political reasoning. The polar opposite of biased information processing is that individuals are rational and unbiased, i.e. Bayesian, learners (Gerber and Green 1998, 1999). If individuals interpret and process information in the same way, then differences in perceptions must arise from differences in information that they encounter. This might arise from the use of alternative media sources for political information, different social networks (Beck 2002; Huckfeldt and Sprague 1995), or from selective exposure to political information. Moreover, partisans might have more (and more accurate) information about their own party than about the opposing party. Note, however, that differences in levels of information will lead to observed biases in perceptions only if the information itself is different. The Bayesian learning perspective suggests that there will be fewer differences in perceptions between individuals with high levels of information. The reasoning is as follows. If we increase the total amount of information that each of two individuals have, then we are likely to increase the amount of information that they have in common. The more their sets of information overlap, the closer their perceptions should be. Therefore, 6

I hypothesize that partisan differences should be smaller among individuals with high levels of information. The hypothesis cannot be strengthened since we cannot actually measure absolute levels of information, nor can we measure whether people observe the same things. Note also that evidence in favor of the hypothesis would also cast doubt that biased information processing is at work in shaping perceptions of parties. Heuristic Political Reasoning The biased and unbiased information processing perspectives both assume that beliefs about others are based on information received and that those beliefs are accurately reported in surveys. Much of the public opinion literature, however, emphasizes the paucity of citizens knowledge of public affairs, which suggests that rather than reporting attitudes and beliefs, individuals often make up their answers as they go along (Zaller 1992). This does not necessarily mean that people guess haphazardly. Research on low information rationality (Popkin 1991; Lupia and McCubbins 1998) instead suggests that uninformed individuals use simple rules of thumb or heuristics to estimate the politically relevant information they do not actually have (or may have forgotten). One such heuristic is projection, in which individuals assume that others hold the same positions that they themselves do (Page and Brody 1972). 5 The projection hypothesis rarely takes this pure form, and instead typically involves the interaction of candidate evaluation with one s own positions. That is, favored candidates are perceived 5 This heuristic is actually rational when the only information a person has is knowledge of him or herself in other words, the sample size is N = 1 (Dawes and Mulford 1996). But this is rather extreme, since it also means that an individual has no additional information with which to determine whether he or she is like or unlike the object being perceived. 7

to be close to one s own position while disfavored candidates are perceived to be farther away. 6 Projection is essentially an anchoring and adjustment process (Tversky and Kahneman 1974). The initial guess, or anchor, is the individual s own position, and this guess is then adjusted according to the evaluation of the political object. According to Brady and Sniderman (1985), the adjustment mechanism is explicitly affective and relies on an individual s feelings towards the group whose position is being estimated. What they call the likeability heuristic therefore provides way to compensate for information that is forgotten or lost when only summary party and candidate evaluations are retained in online processing (Lodge, McGraw, and Stroh 1989). Projection can also be thought of as a special case of inference (Feldman and Conover 1983). In general, individuals can use inference processes to estimate unknown information about political objects from what they know about similar objects (e.g. party cues and stereotypes) or from related characteristics of the same object (e.g. using ideology to guess stances on specific issues). In fact, Feldman and Conover find that perceptions of candidate positions depend more on processes of inference from ideology and party cues than on the process of projection. Drawing from this existing research, I hypothesize that perceptions of party positions are formed through anchoring and adjustment. In particular, when estimating a position on a specific issue, I expect that the anchor is a combination of an individual s own position and beliefs about the party s ideology, and the adjustment is based on the individual s feelings for the party. More specifically, if those who take a liberal position on an issue view the liberal position as good or desirable, then the more positively they 6 Of course, this is exactly the relationship we should observe from issue voting, with the direction of causality reversed. 8

feel about a party, the more they will adjust their estimate in the liberal direction. Likewise, conservatives on an issue will adjust their estimates in a conservative direction the more positively they feel about the party. For moderates, positive feelings should lead to more moderate estimates of a party s position, although the actual direction depends on where the initial guess is. If anchoring and adjustment is the dominant process by which individuals estimate party positions, then partisan differences might arise because the adjustment process is insufficient or inaccurate. For instance, the adjustment process might be too conservative in the sense that guesses are too close to the anchors even after adjustment (as in the classic projection hypothesis). Alternatively, feelings may differ. Suppose that a Democratic identifier and a Republican identifier hold the same position on an issue. If the Democrat likes the Democratic Party and the Republican dislikes it, then if they both anchor on their own position, they will make different adjustments and end up with different estimates of the party s position. If partisan biases are primarily the byproduct of heuristic political reasoning, then differences between partisan identifiers should disappear once the anchoring and adjustment are accounted for. Data and Methods I use additional data from the 2004 NES survey to assess whether accounting for information and heuristic reasoning reduces the partisan bias shown in Figure 1 (and Table 1). 7 In order to determine which individuals might be highly informed (at least 7 Since this study relies on only cross-sectional data, it cannot directly address whether there is reverse or simultaneous causality. In particular, the literature argues that there is often a persuasion effect whereby citizens do not actually have their own preferences or positions on issues but instead are persuaded to adopt the positions of the parties. Carsey and Layman (2006) provide evidence that this effect depends on awareness and attitude importance. Even if there is persuasion, however, it does not directly affect the 9

relative to others), I create and combine two measures that, while imperfect, I expect to be correlated with information. First, I create a six point political knowledge index from four office recognition items (Cheney, Hastert, Rehnquist, Blair) and the items regarding control of each chamber of Congress. Each correct answer contributes one point on the scale. 8 I also create a media attention index from items concerning interest in the campaigns, attention to campaign news, number of days the respondent watched national TV news, and number of days the respondent read the newspaper. 9 The political knowledge index therefore provides a rough measure of the retention of information while the second captures exposure to information. I then define a high information respondent as one who scores highly on both indices: four points or higher on the knowledge index and above the median on the attention index. This results in about 25 percent (N = 305) of the NES survey respondents being classified as high information. I then estimate a regression of perceived positions on dummy variables for partisan identification (as in Table 1) using only the sample of high information respondents. 10 In order to analyze whether heuristic reasoning accounts for partisan bias, I extend the simple dummy variable regression of perception on party identification. To account for anchoring, I include the respondent s own position on the issue (projection) and, when the dependent variable is a specific issue, the perception of the party s position analysis, as it does not matter where citizens positions come from, only that they have them. Furthermore, the persuasion hypothesis assumes that citizens perceive the parties prior to forming their own attitudes. If initial perceptions are unbiased then they should remain unbiased even after citizens are persuaded to adopt them. 8 For similar knowledge indices see Zaller (1992) and Delli Carpini and Keeter (1993). 9 Because it is unclear how to combine the variables measured in days of attention with dichotomous attention variables, I performed a factor analysis of the six items and used the first factor as the media attention index score. The Appendix provides details. 10 I also performed an alternative analysis for each issue that restricts the sample to respondents for whom the issue is highly salient (i.e. who rate the issue as extremely important ) under the theory that individuals will be more knowledgeable about and pay more attention to issues that are important to them, but the results are inconclusive. 10

on the general liberal-conservative ideology scale (inference). Note that the constant term also represents a common anchoring point for all individuals, which can be interpreted as common knowledge or information. To capture the adjustment effect, I include a set of interactions between the respondent s positions and the feeling thermometer rating for the party. (Feeling thermometers are rescaled to range from -1 to 1.) Instead of including interactions for every possible position on an issue, I create three issue-specific indicator variables: liberal (positions less than 0), moderate (position equals 0) and conservative (positions greater than 0). The following equation describing the perceived party position is estimated separately for each issue i and party j: PartyPosition ij = α + δ StrongD + δ WeakD + δ LeansD + + δ LeansR + δ WeakR + δ StrongR 4 + β RespPosition 1 + β Lib Feelings 3 + β Con 5 1 i i 5 Feelings i 2 + β PartyIdeology j + β Mod Feelings j 2 4 + ε ij 6 3 i j j If the issue is the general liberal-conservative ideology scale, then the PartyIdeology variable is omitted as an independent variable (since it is the dependent variable). Findings Estimated partisan differences between high information individuals are presented in Table 2. There are fewer partisan differences than in Table 1, but some amount of partisan bias remains. (In Table 1, 48 coefficients are statistically significant while in Table 2 there are 23 significant coefficients.) In particular, for all but one issue, there remains a consistent bias among strong Republican identifiers to view the Democratic Party as much more liberal (on average, an entire scale point more liberal) than other groups of partisan identifiers do. For weak 11

Republican identifiers, there also appears to be little difference in the magnitudes of partisan biases in Table 1 and Table 2 although fewer coefficients are statistically significant in the high information condition. For Republican leaners, there does appear to be reduction in bias, although the biases in perceptions of general ideology and for the aid to blacks scale remain large and statistically significant. Most of the partisan differences in perceptions of the Republican Party disappear when the sample is restricted to high information types. Most interestingly, systematic differences in perceptions of the GOP on the liberal-conservative ideology scale disappear altogether. A few scattering partisan differences remain for independent leaners, strong Democrats, and strong Republicans on various issues. Also interesting is that on the abortion scale, however, strong Republicans and Republican leaners view the party as more liberal than others do. Another pattern from Table 1 that disappears when we look only at the most informed individuals is the extremism effect, where strong partisans view the parties as more extreme than independents do. Looking at the estimated constant term, which is the mean perception of pure independents, suggests why. Almost all of the estimated constants in Table 2 are larger in absolute value than in Table 1. In other words, highly informed pure independents see the parties as more extreme than less informed independents. This is consistent with previous research that finds that extremists are better informed than moderates (Palfrey and Poole 1987) many of the latter being moderate by virtue of not being informed. The results therefore suggest that the extent of partisan bias in perceptions depends on how informed people are. Among more informed partisans, there are fewer 12

differences in perceptions between them than there are between partisans in general. This suggests some support for the Bayesian learning perspective. Nevertheless, bias remains, so unbiased learning cannot be the entire story. What if it is not the information people have but the lack of information and the ways in which citizens compensate that leads to biased perceptions? Tables 3 and 4 present ordinary least squares estimates that generally support the anchoring and adjustment model. In terms of anchoring, the coefficient for party ideology is positive and statistically significant for all specific issues and for both parties, but the effect of a respondent s own position is only significant and positive for three cases. Note that the estimated effect of a respondent s own liberal-conservative position on perceived party liberal-conservative position is negative for both parties. While this is inconsistent with projection, it might be consistent with some other judgmental bias such as the uniqueness bias. Thus, the analysis suggests that inference plays a much more important role than projection in making initial guesses about party positions, which is consistent with previous work by Feldman and Conover (1983). [Table 3 about here.] [Table 4 about here.] The empirical results also provide strong support for an affective adjustment process. For all but one regression in Tables 3 and 4, the liberal-feeling interaction is negative and significant. This means that the more positively those who hold a liberal position on an issue feel about a party, the more liberal they perceive the party to be (for both parties). For all but two regressions, the more positively those who hold a conservative position feel, the more they adjust the estimate of the party position in a 13

conservative direction. Moderates make similar adjustments in a moderate direction from an extreme baseline, but on a less extensive and less consistent basis. Overall, these results support the adjustment part of Brady and Sniderman s (1985) likeability heuristic. Once anchoring and adjustment have been controlled for, what remains of partisan bias? Tables 3 and 4 show that a few biases remain but that much of the bias disappears when heuristic reasoning is taken into account. There are 16 significant differences, compared to 23 in Table 2 and 48 in Table 1. A casual assessment of the magnitudes of these differences also suggests a substantial reduction. Among the remain partisan differences, strong Republican identifiers continue to exhibit biased perceptions of the Democratic Party on several issues, viewing it as more liberal than others perceive it to be. In these cases, however, the magnitude of bias is approximately half of what it originally was in Table 1, implying that anchoring and adjustment accounts for much but not all of the initial bias. Weak Republicans and Republican leaners also see the Democratic Party as more liberal than others do, but only in terms of general ideology. Strong and weak Republicans also continue to perceive the Republican Party as more conservative than others perceive it to be. For Democratic leaning or identifying groups, the only remaining differences are that they perceive Republicans as more conservative on the services and spending scale and the defense spending scale than others partisan groups do. Conclusion Overall, the findings provide a modest amount of support for the role of information implied by the Bayesian learning perspective but more support for the use of 14

political heuristics. Perhaps this is not too surprising given what little people know about politics. After all, even the most highly informed citizens are not perfectly informed. This lack of information is made up through short cuts, and the analysis shows that a synthesis of previously documented political heuristics is at work. More specifically, the data support the hypothesized combination of ideological inference and an affective adjustment process. Nevertheless, neither increasing information nor accounting for heuristics completely explains the data. This leaves remaining differences in partisan perceptions which might be attributed to selective perception or other biases in information processing. These biases, however, are not as extensive as they first seem, and the analysis also reveals interesting asymmetries. Strong Republicans tend to believe that the Democratic Party takes a position that is more liberal on almost every issue than any other partisan group believes it does. If this were the only kind of bias, then the consequences for party competition would be minimal since strong partisans are the least likely to change party affiliations, but it is not the only remaining bias. All Republican identifiers, including independent leaners, tend to perceive that both parties are more extreme in terms of general ideology than Democrats or independents do. (Bias among Democratic identifiers, however, is limited to perceptions of the Republican Party on spending issues.) This bias in perceptions of general ideology also leads to biases in estimates of positions on specific issues because citizens because of the reliance on ideological inference. In addition, the bias in perceived Democratic Party position is greater than the bias in perceived Republican Party position. This implies an advantage for the Republican Party in terms of Downsian spatial positioning. 15

Given that current ideological positions of the parties diverge, the Republican Party would not have to moderate its position towards the median voter as much as the Democratic Party would in order to gain the same number of additional votes. Finally, the sizeable effects of the affective adjustment process suggest that parties need not compete directly on the issues to affect issue-based voting. Instead, they might wage emotion-laden campaigns that seek to increase the public s negative feelings towards their opponents and positive feelings toward themselves. This would produce an equilibrium of constantly negative politics, though in the long run, citizens would simply adjust the adjustment process itself and come to rely less on their feelings to estimate what they don t know about politics. 16

Appendix: Data Definitions Issue Scales Liberal-Conservative (7 point) -3 = liberal 3 = conservative Spending and Services (7 point) -3 = government should provide many more services even if it means an increase in spending 3 = government should provide fewer services even in areas such as health and education in order to reduce spending Defense Spending (7 points) -3 = spend less money for defense 3 = defense spending should be greatly increased Guaranteed Jobs (7 point) -3 = government in Washington should see to it that every person has a job and a good standard of living 3 = government should just let each person get ahead on their own Aid to Blacks Scale (7 point) -3 = government in Washington should make every effort to improve the social and economic position of blacks 3 = government should not make any special effort to help blacks because they should help themselves Women s Role Scale (7 point) -3 = women should have an equal role with men in running business, industry, and government 3 = a woman's place is in the home 17

Abortion (4 point) -3 = By law, abortion should never be permitted. -1.5 = The law should permit abortion only in case of rape, incest, or when the woman's life is in danger 1.5 = The law should permit abortion for reasons other than rape, incest, or danger to the woman's life, but only after the need for the abortion has been clearly established. 3 = By law, a woman should always be able to obtain an abortion as a matter of personal choice. Media Attention Items Campaign interest 1 = very much interested 0.5 = somewhat interested 0 = not much interested Read about campaign in newspaper 0 = no 1 = yes Attention to newspaper campaign articles 0 = none 0.25= very little 0.5 = some 0.75= quite a bit 1 = a great deal Days watched national TV news 0-7 days Days read daily newspaper 0-7 days 18

Days read online newspaper 0-7 days Factor analysis for Media Attention Index Item Factor Loading Uniqueness Scoring Coefficient Campaign interest 0.45 0.80 0.08 Read about campaign in newspaper 0.90 0.19 0.41 Attention to newspaper campaign articles 0.91 0.17 0.47 Days watched national TV news 0.29 0.91 0.08 Days read daily newspaper 0.57 0.67 0.07 Days read online newspaper 0.26 0.93 0.01 N = 1,212; largest eigenvalue = 2.32; proportion of variance = 0.97 19

References Aldrich, John H. 1995. Why Parties? The Origins and Transformation of Political Parties in America. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Bartels, Larry M. 2002. Beyond the Running Tally: Partisan Bias in Political Perceptions. Political Behavior 24:117-150. Beck, Paul A. 2002. Encouraging Political Defection: The Role of Personal Discussion Networks in Partisan Desertions to the Opposition Party and Perot Votes in 1992. Political Behavior 24:309-337. Berelson, Bernard R., Paul F. Lazarsfeld, and William N. McPhee. 1954. Voting: A Study of Opinion Formation in a Presidential Campaign. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Brady, Henry E. and Paul M. Sniderman 1985. Attitude Attribution: A Group Basis for Political Reasoning. American Political Science Review 79:1061-1078. Campbell, Angus, Philip E. Converse, Warren E. Miller, and Donald E. Stokes. 1960. The American Voter. New York: Wiley. Carsey, Thomas M. and Geoffrey C. Layman. 2006. Changing Sides or Changing Minds? Party Identification and Policy Preferences in the American Electorate. American Journal of Political Science 50:464-477. Conover, Pamela J. and Stanley Feldman. 1989. Candidate Perceptions in an Ambiguous World: Campaigns, Cues, and Inference Processes. American Journal of Political Science 33:917-940. Dawes, Robyn M. and Matthew Mulford. 1996. The False Consensus Effect and Overconfidence: Flaws in Judgment or Flaws in How We Study Judgment? Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 65:201-211. Delli Carpini, Michael X. and Scott Keeter. Measuring Political Knowledge: Putting First Things First. American Journal of Political Science 37: 1179-1206. Downs, Anthony. 1957. An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York: Harper and Row. Feldman, Stanley and Pamela J. Conover. 1983. Candidates, Issues and Voters: The Role of Inference in Political Perception. Journal of Politics 45:810-839. Gerber, Alan and Donald P. Green. 1998. Rational Learning and Partisan Attitudes. American Journal of Political Science 42:794-818. 20

Gerber, Alan and Donald P. Green. 1999. Misperceptions About Perceptual Bias. Annual Review of Political Science 2:189-210. Huckfeldt, Robert R. and John Sprague. 1995. Citizens, Politics, and Social Communication: Information and Influence in an Election Campaign. New York: Cambridge University Press. Koch, Jeffrey W. 2001. When Parties and Candidates Collide: Citizen Perceptions of House Candidates Positions on Abortion. Public Opinion Quarterly 65:1-21. Lupia, Arthur and Mathew McCubbins. 1998. The Democratic Dilemma: Can Citizens Learn What They Need to Know? Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Lodge, Milton, Kathleen M. McGraw, and Patrick Stroh. 1989. An Impression-Driven Model of Candidate Evaluation. American Political Science Review 83:399-419. Page, Benjamin I. and Richard A. Brody. 1972. Policy Voting and the Electoral Process: The Vietnam War Issue. American Political Science Review 66:979-995. Palfrey, Thomas R. and Keith T. Poole. 1987. The Relationship Between Information, Ideology, and Voting Behavior. American Journal of Political Science 31:511-530. Popkin, Samuel. 1991. The Reasoning Voter: Communication and Persuasion in Presidential Campaigns. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Rahn, Wendy M. 1993. The Role of Partisan Stereotypes in Information Processing About Political Candidates. American Journal of Political Science 37:472-496. Snyder, James M., Jr. and Michael M. Ting. 2002. An Informational Rationale for Political Parties. American Journal of Political Science 46:90-110. Taber, Charles S. and Milton Lodge. 2006. Motivated Skepticism in the Evaluation of Political Beliefs. American Journal of Political Science 50:755-769. Tversky, Amos and Daniel Kahneman. 1974. Judgment under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases. Science 185: 1124-1131. Zaller, John R. 1992. The Nature and Origins of Mass Opinion. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 21

Figure 1. Average perceptions of parties issue positions by party identification a. Liberal-Conservative Strong Rep b. Spending-Services Strong Rep p Weak Rep Weak Rep Leans Rep Leans Rep Independent Independent Leans Dem Leans Dem Weak Dem Weak Dem Strong Dem -3-2 -1 0 1 2 3 Strong Dem -3-2 -1 0 1 2 3 c. Defense Spending p d. Jobs j Strong Rep Strong Rep Weak Rep Weak Rep Leans Rep Leans Rep Independent Independent Leans Dem Leans Dem Weak Dem Weak Dem Strong Dem -3-2 -1 0 1 2 3 Strong Dem -3-2 -1 0 1 2 3 Democratic Party Republican Party Lines indicate difference between the average perception of independents and the average perception of the partisan group.

Figure 1 (continued). Average perceptions of parties issue positions by party identification e. Aid to Blacks Strong Rep f. Women s Equality Strong Rep Weak Rep Weak Rep Leans Rep Leans Rep Independent Independent Leans Dem Leans Dem Weak Dem Weak Dem Strong Dem -3-2 -1 0 1 2 3 Strong Dem -3-2 -1 0 1 2 3 g. Abortion Strong Rep Weak Rep Leans Rep Independent Leans Dem Weak Dem Strong Dem -3-2 -1 0 1 2 3 Democratic Party Republican Party Lines indicate difference between the average perception of independents and the average perception of the partisan group.

Table 1. Partisan differences in perceptions of party issue positions Perceptions of Democratic Party Perceptions of Republican Party Lib-Con Serv. + Spend. Def. Spend. Guar. Jobs Aid to Blacks Women Equal Abortion Lib-Con Serv. + Spend. Def. Spend. Guar. Jobs Aid to Blacks Women Equal Abortion Strong D 0.00-0.55** 0.33* -0.77*** -0.62** -1.07*** -0.23 0.34 1.12*** 0.65*** 0.85*** 0.78*** 0.47* 0.52* (0.18) (0.19) (0.17) (0.18) (0.20) (0.18) (0.27) (0.20) (0.19) (0.16) (0.19) (0.18) (0.21) (0.26) Weak D 0.11-0.33 0.09-0.38* -0.12-0.35 0.26 0.14 0.49* 0.46** 0.24 0.43* 0.42 0.31 (0.19) (0.19) (0.17) (0.19) (0.20) (0.19) (0.29) (0.21) (0.19) (0.17) (0.19) (0.19) (0.22) (0.27) Lean D -0.27-0.31 0.17-0.28-0.22-0.58** -0.25 0.43* 0.48* 0.54*** 0.48** 0.54** 0.33 0.39 (0.18) (0.19) (0.16) (0.18) (0.20) (0.18) (0.28) (0.20) (0.19) (0.16) (0.18) (0.18) (0.21) (0.26) Lean R -0.94*** -0.26-0.64*** -0.62** -0.70** -0.43* -0.50 0.47* -0.06 0.35* -0.27-0.20-0.56* -0.16 (0.19) (0.20) (0.18) (0.20) (0.21) (0.19) (0.29) (0.22) (0.20) (0.17) (0.20) (0.20) (0.22) (0.27) Weak R -0.92*** -0.45* -0.62*** -0.65*** -0.53** -0.58** -0.61* 0.68** 0.12 0.36* -0.16-0.01-0.41 0.02 (0.19) (0.20) (0.17) (0.19) (0.21) (0.19) (0.28) (0.21) (0.20) (0.17) (0.19) (0.19) (0.22) (0.27) Strong R -1.33*** -0.73*** -1.29*** -1.15*** -1.07*** -0.81*** -1.04*** 0.77*** -0.01 0.78*** 0.30 0.28-0.95*** 0.02 (0.18) (0.19) (0.17) (0.19) (0.20) (0.19) (0.28) (0.20) (0.19) (0.16) (0.19) (0.19) (0.21) (0.26) Constant -0.47** -0.66*** -0.11-0.24-0.31-0.74*** -1.07*** 0.73*** 0.29 0.93*** 0.88*** 0.73*** -0.17 0.87*** (0.15) (0.16) (0.14) (0.15) (0.17) (0.15) (0.23) (0.17) (0.16) (0.13) (0.15) (0.15) (0.18) (0.22) R sq. 0.14 0.02 0.17 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.02 0.07 0.03 0.06 0.06 0.11 0.02 RMSE 1.35 1.44 1.28 1.39 1.43 1.33 1.82 1.52 1.45 1.25 1.39 1.33 1.54 1.69 N 1086 1094 1103 1072 1014 1025 895 1080 1100 1114 1073 1009 1029 891 Ordinary least squares estimates. * p <.05, ** p <.01, *** p <.001

Table 2. Partisan differences in perceptions of party issue positions among high attention respondents Perceptions of Democratic Party Perceptions of Republican Party Lib-Con Serv. + Spend. Def. Spend. Guar. Jobs Aid to Blacks Women Equal Abortion Lib-Con Serv. + Spend. Def. Spend. Guar. Jobs Aid to Blacks Women Equal Abortion Strong D 0.01-0.13 0.75* -0.4-0.65-0.65* -0.58 0.21 1.11** 0.56* 0.62 0.62 0.84* 0.12 (0.29) (0.30) (0.29) (0.32) (0.36) (0.32) (0.40) (0.30) (0.36) (0.24) (0.32) (0.32) (0.42) (0.36) Weak D 0.17-0.2 0.36-0.29-0.14-0.30-0.05-0.19 0.03 0.39 0.28 0.25 0.49 0.26 (0.32) (0.34) (0.33) (0.36) (0.39) (0.36) (0.45) (0.34) (0.40) (0.27) (0.36) (0.35) (0.48) (0.41) Lean D -0.12-0.10 0.44-0.35-0.5-0.36-0.34 0.10 0.82* 0.56* 0.70* 0.52 0.64-0.12 (0.30) (0.32) (0.31) (0.34) (0.37) (0.34) (0.42) (0.32) (0.38) (0.26) (0.34) (0.34) (0.45) (0.38) Lean R -0.70* -0.44-0.34-0.57-0.85* -0.06-0.28-0.21-0.15 0.07-0.49-0.73* -0.61-0.91* (0.31) (0.33) (0.32) (0.35) (0.39) (0.35) (0.43) (0.33) (0.39) (0.26) (0.35) (0.35) (0.46) (0.39) Weak R -0.96** -0.51-0.75* -0.92* -0.64-0.21-0.59 0.19 0.34 0.23 0.18-0.12-0.22-0.63 (0.31) (0.33) (0.32) (0.36) (0.39) (0.35) (0.44) (0.33) (0.39) (0.27) (0.36) (0.35) (0.47) (0.39) Strong R -1.08*** -0.85** -0.99*** -1.11*** -1.22*** -0.42-0.91* -0.17-0.09 0.30-0.03-0.35-1.31** -0.90* (0.28) (0.30) (0.29) (0.32) (0.35) (0.32) (0.40) (0.30) (0.36) (0.24) (0.32) (0.32) (0.42) (0.36) Constant -0.95*** -1.22*** -0.56* -0.65* -0.6-1.41*** -1.53*** 1.72*** 0.72* 1.44*** 1.35*** 1.33*** -0.06 1.63*** (0.25) (0.27) (0.26) (0.29) (0.32) (0.28) (0.35) (0.27) (0.32) (0.22) (0.29) (0.29) (0.38) (0.31) R sq. 0.17 0.07 0.28 0.08 0.08 0.03 0.04 0.02 0.12 0.04 0.1 0.15 0.23 0.11 RMSE 1.1 1.14 1.11 1.19 1.24 1.17 1.52 1.14 1.35 0.92 1.19 1.13 1.56 1.37 N 300 298 298 294 283 287 291 297 300 299 293 284 289 289 Ordinary least squares estimates. * p <.05, ** p <.01, *** p <.001

Table 3. Estimated effects of partisanship, anchoring, and adjustment on perceptions of Democratic Party positions Lib-Con Serv. and Spending Defense Spending Guarant. Jobs Aid to Blacks Women Equal Role Abortion Strong Dem 0.11-0.23 0.33-0.30-0.30-0.73*** -0.38 (0.21) (0.19) (0.18) (0.20) (0.20) (0.19) (0.28) Weak Dem 0.05-0.23 0.09-0.17-0.04-0.12 0.03 (0.20) (0.19) (0.18) (0.19) (0.20) (0.19) (0.28) Leans Dem -0.16-0.27 0.26-0.08-0.17-0.32-0.04 (0.19) (0.18) (0.17) (0.18) (0.19) (0.18) (0.27) Leans Rep -0.71*** -0.06-0.29-0.24-0.40-0.10 0.02 (0.20) (0.20) (0.18) (0.20) (0.20) (0.20) (0.28) Weak Rep -0.53** -0.27-0.30-0.35-0.26-0.29-0.03 (0.19) (0.19) (0.18) (0.19) (0.20) (0.19) (0.27) Strong Rep -0.62** -0.29-0.67*** -0.53** -0.55** -0.50* -0.13 (0.20) (0.19) (0.18) (0.20) (0.20) (0.20) (0.28) Party Ideology 0.15*** 0.20*** 0.19*** 0.23*** 0.14*** 0.30*** (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.04) Respondent Position -0.11** -0.16*** 0.05-0.04 0.05 0.14*** 0.09*** (0.04) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) Liberal Position -1.17*** -1.51*** -0.62** -1.41*** -1.14*** -0.37** -0.22 x Feelings (0.23) (0.15) (0.22) (0.18) (0.21) (0.13) (0.24) Moderate Position 0.46* 0.27 0.11-0.04-0.37* 0.27 1.22*** x Feelings (0.18) (0.18) (0.15) (0.19) (0.18) (0.22) (0.21) Conservative Position 1.28*** 1.41*** 0.96*** 0.91*** 1.08*** 1.52*** 1.57*** x Feelings (0.14) (0.19) (0.13) (0.15) (0.15) (0.28) (0.30) Constant -0.67*** -0.58*** -0.16-0.25-0.25-0.56*** -1.10*** (0.16) (0.16) (0.14) (0.16) (0.16) (0.17) (0.23) R squared 0.25 0.21 0.28 0.19 0.22 0.15 0.21 rmse 1.19 1.3 1.2 1.29 1.28 1.25 1.61 N 882 1032 1039 1014 961 977 832 Ordinary least squares estimates. * p <.05, ** p <.01, *** p <.001

Table 4. Estimated effects of partisanship, anchoring, and adjustment on perceptions of Republican Party positions Lib-Con Serv. and Spending Defense Spending Guarant. Jobs Aid to Blacks Women Equal Role Abortion Strong Dem -0.31 0.77*** 0.52** 0.41* 0.25 0.07 0.09 (0.23) (0.19) (0.17) (0.19) (0.19) (0.22) (0.28) Weak Dem -0.25 0.44* 0.31 0.05 0.18 0.32 0.18 (0.22) (0.19) (0.17) (0.19) (0.19) (0.22) (0.28) Leans Dem -0.17 0.37* 0.43** 0.29 0.23 0.20 0.16 (0.22) (0.19) (0.17) (0.18) (0.18) (0.21) (0.27) Leans Rep 0.32-0.03 0.08-0.31-0.33-0.30-0.15 (0.23) (0.20) (0.18) (0.20) (0.20) (0.22) (0.28) Weak Rep 0.46* 0.22 0.06-0.31-0.17-0.10 0.00 (0.22) (0.20) (0.18) (0.20) (0.19) (0.22) (0.28) Strong Rep 0.49* -0.08 0.26-0.04 0.10-0.46* 0.07 (0.24) (0.20) (0.18) (0.20) (0.20) (0.23) (0.28) Party Ideology 0.14*** 0.13*** 0.20*** 0.16*** 0.08** 0.18*** (0.03) (0.02) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.04) Respondent Position -0.20*** 0.02 0.00 0.03-0.03 0.10** 0.04 (0.04) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) Liberal Position -1.43*** -1.15*** -0.68*** -1.11*** -1.07*** -1.19*** -0.97*** x Feelings (0.20) (0.14) (0.18) (0.15) (0.16) (0.13) (0.19) Moderate Position -0.77*** -0.53** -0.23-0.82*** -0.73*** 0.18-0.34 x Feelings (0.19) (0.16) (0.14) (0.17) (0.16) (0.28) (0.21) Conservative Position 0.78*** 1.03*** 0.61*** 0.47** 0.17 0.11 0.68* x Feelings (0.20) (0.20) (0.13) (0.15) (0.15) (0.34) (0.34) Constant 1.06*** 0.15 0.94*** 0.78*** 0.79*** -0.09 0.72** (0.18) (0.16) (0.14) (0.16) (0.16) (0.19) (0.23) R squared 0.15 0.22 0.1 0.21 0.17 0.22 0.09 rmse 1.36 1.34 1.17 1.28 1.23 1.44 1.63 N 880 1032 1041 1006 948 972 825 Ordinary least squares estimates. * p <.05, ** p <.01, *** p <.001