The new economics of the brain drain

Similar documents
WORLD ECONOMICS. The New Economics of the Brain Drain. Volume 6 Number 2 April - June By ODED STARK. Reprinted from

Notes on Policy Repercussions of The New Economics of the Brain Drain

Toil and Tolerance: A Tale of Illegal Migration

involving 58,000 foreig n students in the U.S. and 11,000 American students $1.0 billion. Third, the role of foreigners in the American economics

How Extensive Is the Brain Drain?

Some Observations on Net Fiscal Transfers to Recent Immigrants Resulting From Income Taxes and Government Transfer Programs

CEDI. Working Paper No CEDI DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES Revised May 2007

A social proximity explanation of the reluctance to assimilate

Social Capital as Patterns of Connections. A Review of Bankston s Immigrant Networks and Social Capital

MC/INF/267. Original: English 6 November 2003 EIGHTY-SIXTH SESSION WORKSHOPS FOR POLICY MAKERS: BACKGROUND DOCUMENT LABOUR MIGRATION

How are the Children of Visible Minority Immigrants Doing? An Update Based on the National Household Survey

Migration and Development

Rethinking the Brain Drain

Is there a New Mexico Brain Drain? Jim Peach and David Saucedo de la Fuente 1 Office of Policy Analysis, Arrowhead Center New Mexico State University

Trade and the distributional politics of international labour standards

SKILLED MIGRATION AND BRAIN DRAIN

Are Second-Best Tariffs Good Enough?

REVIEW OF INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS

International Migration and Development: Proposed Work Program. Development Economics. World Bank

Sixteenth Meeting of the IMF Committee on Balance of Payments Statistics Washington D.C., December 1 5, 2003

Riccardo Faini (Università di Roma Tor Vergata, IZA and CEPR)

Running head: BRAIN DRAIN 1

International Migration, Remittances and the Brain Drain: A Study of 24 Labor-Exporting Countries* Richard H. Adams, Jr. PRMPR.

The Many Guises of Immigration Reform

Migration and Development Policy coherence

A Political Economy to Examine Brexit

Volume Author/Editor: Jagdish N. Bhagwati, editor. Volume URL:

SMART STRATEGIES TO INCREASE PROSPERITY AND LIMIT BRAIN DRAIN IN CENTRAL EUROPE 1

The immigrant-native pay gap in Germany

Executive Summary. International mobility of human resources in science and technology is of growing importance

Brain drain and Human Capital Formation in Developing Countries. Are there Really Winners?

Socio-economic and Socio-political Effects of Emigration on the Sending Countries. Magdalena Bonev. Walltopia Austria GmbH, Vienna, Austria

Common Dreams, Different Circumstances: Lessons from Contemporary Development Economics

Engaging the Diaspora development the case of Albania

Do international migration and remittances reduce poverty in developing countries?

HP INC. BOARD OF DIRECTORS HR AND COMPENSATION COMMITTEE CHARTER

At a time when political philosophy seemed nearly stagnant, John Rawls

Preserving the future: engaging non governmental organisations and actors in sustainable environmental development

EFFICIENCY OF COMPARATIVE NEGLIGENCE : A GAME THEORETIC ANALYSIS

Between brain drain and brain gain post-2004 Polish migration experience

State Policies toward Migration and Development. Dilip Ratha

Demographic Evolutions, Migration and Remittances

Labour market trends and prospects for economic competitiveness of Lithuania

ISTANBUL MINISTERIAL DECLARATION on A Silk Routes Partnership for Migration

EcoTalent Mobility and International Development: Issues, Experience and Policies

A Stochastic Model of Migrant Rescue in the Mediterranean Sea

International Dialogue on Migration Inter-sessional Workshop on Developing Capacity to Manage Migration SEPTEMBER 2005

Population Dynamics and Long-Run Economic Growth

Losses and gains to developing countries from the migration of educated workers : an overview of recent research, and new reflections

Louise Arbour. Special Representative of the Secretary-General for International Migration

Explaining the two-way causality between inequality and democratization through corruption and concentration of power

THE BRAIN DRAIN + Frédéric Docquier a and Hillel Rapoport b. FNRS and IRES, Université Catholique de Louvain

What Should a Cautious Immigration Policy Look Like?

Skilled Worker Migration and Trade: Inequality and Welfare

Brain Drain, Brain Gain, and Economic Growth in China

Remittances by Country and by Type of Worker -

DEMOGRAPHIC SHOCKS: THE VIEW FROM HISTORY. DISCUSSION

Studying abroad: encouraging students to return to Kyrgyzstan

Systematic Policy and Forward Guidance

Research Paper: Migration of international students and mobilizing skills in the MENA Region (Tunis, May 13, 2013)

Circular migration as an employment strategy for MENA countries

Is inequality an unavoidable by-product of skill-biased technical change? No, not necessarily!

SKILLED MIGRATION: WHEN SHOULD A GOVERNMENT RESTRICT MIGRATION OF SKILLED WORKERS?* Gabriel Romero

European Integration Consortium. IAB, CMR, frdb, GEP, WIFO, wiiw. Labour mobility within the EU in the context of enlargement and the functioning

Losses and Gains to Developing Countries from the Migration of Educated Workers

Economics of Migration. Basic Neoclassical Model. Prof. J.R.Walker Page 1. Economics 623 Spring 2012

1.2 Efficiency and Social Justice

Public Education in an Integrated Europe: Studying to Migrate and Teaching to Stay?

The best practices on managing circular and return migration in countries of origin, transit and destination

How Should Immigration Affect the Economy? A D A M M. Z A R E T S K Y

Mitigating the Consequences of Brain Drain in Developing Countries

The European refugee crisis and the natural rate of output

Revista Economică 67:Supplement (2015) BRAIN DRAIN MIGRATION TYPE. WHAT CAUSES BRAIN DRAIN PHENOMENON?

INTERNATIONAL MOVEMENT OF RESOURCES ECO 41 UDAYAN ROY

Chapter Ten Growth, Immigration, and Multinationals

INTRODUCTION. Franck Duvell (COMPAS) Yuriy Bilan (CSR) Iryna Lapshyna (LAC) Yulia Borshchevska (CSR) January Research objectives

Policy Coherence for Migration and Development

Public Perceptions of Immigration in European Union: A Survey Analysis of Eurobarometer 83.3 and 85.2

This is the Test of English for Educational Purposes, Practice Test 3, Part 4, Listening.

MC/INF/293. Return Migration: Challenges and Opportunities. Original: English 10 November 2008 NINETY-SIXTH SESSION

When users of congested roads may view tolls as unjust

ECON 1000 Contemporary Economic Issues (Spring 2018) Economic Growth

Lecture 23: The Political Economy of International Migration (1) Benjamin Graham

Chapter VI. Labor Migration

This book has a simple and straightforward message. The

The Brain Drain: Curse or Boon?

Commentary on Session IV

An Investigation of Brain Drain from Iran to OECD Countries Based on Gravity Model

Brain Drain and Development Support Policy Coherence

The Public Policy Process WEEK 10: DECISION MAKING, POLICY DESIGN AND POLICY TOOLS

Foreign Labor. Page 1. D. Foreign Labor

Bela Hovy Chief, Migration Section Population Division, Department of Economic and Social Affairs (UN DESA)

Lesson 10 What Is Economic Justice?

Internationalism in Higher Education: A Review

A Theoretical Approach: Examining the Educated Unemployment Rate and International Skilled Migration of Developing Countries.

Influencing Expectations in the Conduct of Monetary Policy

Migration. Why do people move and what are the consequences of that move?

1100 Ethics July 2016

The brain drain: how to reverse the trend

James M. Buchanan The Limits of Market Efficiency

Transcription:

MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive The new economics of the brain drain Oded Stark 2005 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/30939/ MPRA Paper No. 30939, posted 17. May 2011 12:57 UTC

The New Economics of the Brain Drain by Oded Stark Universities of Bonn, Klagenfurt, and Vienna; Warsaw University; ESCE Economic and Social Research Center, Cologne and Eisenstadt Mailing Address: Oded Stark April 2005 ZEF, University of Bonn Walter-Flex-Strasse 3 D-53113 Bonn Germany E-Mail Address: ostark@uni-bonn.de Details of the new research reported in this article were presented in the Tjalling Koopmans Distiguished Lecture delivered by the author at the International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis (IIASA). The text of the Koopmans Lecture was published in 2004 in World Development (Volume 32).

Abstract For nearly four decades now, the conventional wisdom has been that the migration of human capital (skilled workers) from a developing country to a developed country is detrimental to the developing country. However, this perception need not hold. A well designed migration policy can result in a brain gain to the developing country rather than in just a brain drain from it, as well as in a welfare increase for all of its workers - migrants and non-migrants alike - as new research suggests. Key words: migration, human capital formation, externalities, social welfare JEL classification: F22; H23; I30; J24; J61

A detailed reasoning When we refer to human capital, we have in mind the productive attributes of individuals that are acquired or formed either formally (for example, by attending a college) or informally (for example, by on-the-job training as a by-product of regular work). Just as physical capital is an asset that yields a flow of output, human capital is an asset, embodied in human beings, that yields a flow of income. We can reasonably assume that individuals are naturally endowed with some ability (say physical strength) that enables them to produce, hence earn. But typically, individuals enhance or supplement their natural endowment by investing time and resources in the acquisition of skills, technical knowledge, and professional qualifications. Since undertaking such an investment today yields (expected) returns tomorrow, we have a resemblance with the formation of physical capital. Hence, we resort to the expression human capital formation. While not all the human capital that an individual has is the outcome of decisions made by the individual, in the new research reported in this article we study investment behavior under the assumption that the individual is decisionally responsible for the acquisition of the productive assets that are embodied in him. Much of the human capital in a country is a result of decisions made by individuals. However, individual choices seldom add up to the social optimum. In particular, individuals do not consider the positive externalities that human capital confers in production. The result is that they acquire less human capital than is socially desirable. If individuals could be persuaded to form more human capital, the human capital in an economy could rise to the socially optimal level. What makes an unfortunate state of affairs worse is that whatever quantities of human capital are formed, some - and often more than a mere some - are lost through the migration leakage. Therefore, the main concern up until now has been to contain the leakage. In the words of a World Development Report: Can something be done to stop the exodus of trained workers from poorer countries? (World Bank 1995, p.64). This concern is in congruence with the large brain drain literature (for a 1

systematic review see Bhagwati and Wilson 1989), and is regularly echoed by the informed press. For example, in its May 31, 2001 lead article, while advocating the entry of migrants into Europe, The Economist hastens to add: There is a risk, especially when immigration policies target only the highly skilled, that the best talent will be drained from poor countries to rich ones. Although expressed more cautiously, the viewpoint of Carrington and Detragiache (1999) presented in a bulletin of the International Monetary Fund is quite similar: Another important issue is the extent to which the benefits of education acquired by citizens of developing countries are externalities that individuals cannot be expected to take into account when making their private decisions. If such externalities are substantial, as is emphasized by the new growth theory, then policies to curb the brain drain may be warranted. New research turns this concern on its head. At the heart of this research is the idea that the prospect of migration can induce individuals to form a socially desirable level of human capital. The point is that compared to a closed economy, an economy open to migration differs not only in the opportunities that workers face, but also in the structure of the incentives that they confront: higher prospective returns to human capital in a foreign country impinge on human capital formation decisions at home. The research considers a setting in which an individual s productivity is fostered by his own human capital as well as by the economy-wide average level of human capital. It examines the relationship between the actual formation of human capital in an economy and the socially optimal formation of human capital in the economy. It identifies conditions under which, from a social point of view, too little human capital formation takes place in the economy. It then examines the relationship between the actual formation of human capital and the socially optimal formation of human capital in the presence of a possibility of migration. The research provides conditions under which per capita output and the level of welfare of all workers are higher with migration than in its absence, and it shows that a restrictive migration policy can enhance 2

welfare and nudge the economy toward the social optimum. It derives this result first, when all workers are alike and are equally capable of responding to the migration prospect, and second, when workers differ both in their skills and in their ability to respond. The research demonstrates that migration is conducive to the formation of human capital and thus casts migration as a harbinger of human capital gain rather as the culprit of human capital drain. An interesting implication is that the gains from migration to the home country accrue neither from the remittances that migrants send nor from migrants return home with amplified skills acquired abroad. Summing up In summary, the research shows that when the productivity of an individual in a closed economy or in a small open economy without migration is fostered not only by his own human capital but also by the average level of human capital, the individual who optimally chooses how much to invest in costly human capital formation will, from a social point of view, under-invest. Consequently, social welfare is affected adversely. The research then shows that somewhat surprisingly, the facility of migration can mitigate this undesirable outcome. In fact, a well-specified migration policy can ameliorate the tendency to under-invest in human capital and permit the formation of a socially desirable level of human capital. The favorable effect of migration and the associated welfare gain apply not only when all individuals can respond to the migration prospect but also when only a subset of individuals is affected. In the latter case, even those who cannot gain from migration by participating in it stand to gain from the response of others. The propensity to acquire skills is not invariant to the possibility that the skills will be highly rewarded. This consideration appears to have escaped the attention of scholars of migration for many years. The pioneering work of Grubel and Scott (1966) provides a careful account of why a 3

country need not lose by the emigration of highly skilled individuals. According to Grubel and Scott (1966, p. 270): [E]migration should be welcomed whenever two conditions are met. These are, first, that the emigrant improves his own income and, second, that the migrant s departure does not reduce the income of those remaining behind. Neither Grubel and Scott nor those who followed in their footsteps have mentioned that the prospect of migration modifies the human capital formation calculus, thereby entailing a welfare gain for the non-migrants (rather than being inconsistent with a welfare loss). The new research draws attention to this possible relationship and shows that the behavioral response to the prospect of migration nourishes both a brain drain and a brain gain, and that a skilfully executed migration policy can confine and utilize the response to secure a welfare gain for all workers. Beyond countries Are there any lessons that entities other than countries, for example, companies and corporations, can draw from the New Economics of the Brain Drain? Consider a world that consists of one country. There are two big orchestras in the country: a good orchestra, GO, and an excellent orchestra, EO. The pay of the EO players is higher than the pay of the GO players. Because of concerns that losing better GO players to the EO will hurt the quality of the GO performances, the GO management insists that the GO players commit not to leave for the EO. (Alternatively, the management of the GO could have made it known that a departure for the EO will be associated with a severe financial penalty - for example, the forfeiting of pension rights.) This management practice may not be wise. Suppose instead that the GO managers permit the EO musical directors to hire randomly a small number, say two, of the finest GO players. This policy change is public knowledge. As a consequence, the GO players will practice harder, prepare more for rehearsals, and excel in their playing. This incentive would not have been present without the 4

possibility of being hired by the EO. When all the GO players are equally eligible for hire by the EO (even though only two will actually be hired), the quality of playing of the GO can very well become higher even after the departure of the two players. When fine-tuned, the probability of departure could be turned into a management policy tool aimed at enhancing the quality of the GO musical output. 5

References Bhagwati, Jagdish and Wilson, John D. 1989. Income Taxation and International Mobility. Cambridge, MA.: MIT Press. Carrington, William J. and Detragiache, Enrica. 1999. How Extensive Is the Brain Drain? Finance and Development 36: 46-49. Grubel, Herbert B. and Scott, Anthony D. 1966. The international flow of human capital. American Economic Review 56: 268-274. World Bank. 1995. World Development Report 1995. New York: Oxford University Press. 6