Paternal Migration and Education Attainment in Rural Mexico (Job Market Paper)

Similar documents
International Migration and Gender Discrimination among Children Left Behind. Francisca M. Antman* University of Colorado at Boulder

Can migration reduce educational attainment? Evidence from Mexico *

THE EFFECTS OF PARENTAL MIGRATION ON CHILD EDUCATIONAL OUTCOMES IN INDONESIA

Can migration prospects reduce educational attainments? *

Can migration reduce educational attainment? Evidence from Mexico * and Stanford Center for International Development

Working Paper No Migration and education inequality in rural Mexico

THE DEMOGRAPHY OF MEXICO/U.S. MIGRATION

Independent and Third-Party Municipal Candidates. City Council Election Reform Task Force April 8, :00 p.m.

Overview of Boston s Population. Boston Redevelopment Authority Research Division Alvaro Lima, Director of Research September

Online Appendix for The Contribution of National Income Inequality to Regional Economic Divergence

Remittances and the Brain Drain: Evidence from Microdata for Sub-Saharan Africa

Brain drain and Human Capital Formation in Developing Countries. Are there Really Winners?

Is emigration of workers contributing to better schooling outcomes for children in Nepal?

Emigration and source countries; Brain drain and brain gain; Remittances.

Beyond Remittances: The Effects of Migration on Mexican Households

Brain Drain and Emigration: How Do They Affect Source Countries?

Migration, Remittances and Children s Schooling in Haiti

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach

The Impact of Migration and Remittances on Household Welfare: Evidence from Vietnam

English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap

Quantitative Analysis of Migration and Development in South Asia

Family Size, Sibling Rivalry and Migration

EXTENDED FAMILY INFLUENCE ON INDIVIDUAL MIGRATION DECISION IN RURAL CHINA

Gender preference and age at arrival among Asian immigrant women to the US

262 Index. D demand shocks, 146n demographic variables, 103tn

Evaluating Methods for Estimating Foreign-Born Immigration Using the American Community Survey

English Deficiency and the Native-Immigrant Wage Gap in the UK

Married men with children may stop working when their wives emigrate to work: Evidence from Sri Lanka

Roles of children and elderly in migration decision of adults: case from rural China

The impact of parents years since migration on children s academic achievement

Immigration and Internal Mobility in Canada Appendices A and B. Appendix A: Two-step Instrumentation strategy: Procedure and detailed results

Mineral Availability and Social License to Operate

The Impact of Migration on Family Left Behind

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION, SELF-SELECTION, AND THE DISTRIBUTION OF WAGES: EVIDENCE FROM MEXICO AND THE UNITED STATES

Silence of the Innocents: Illegal Immigrants Underreporting of Crime and their Victimization

Gender, Educational Attainment, and the Impact of Parental Migration on Children Left Behind

What happen to children s education when their parents emigrate? Evidence from Sri Lanka

Georgia s Immigrants: Past, Present, and Future

Illegal Immigration: How Should We Deal With It?

MIGRATION, REMITTANCES, AND LABOR SUPPLY IN ALBANIA

Parental Labor Migration and Left-Behind Children s Development in Rural China. Hou Yuna The Chinese University of Hong Kong

By 1970 immigrants from the Americas, Africa, and Asia far outnumbered those from Europe. CANADIAN UNITED STATES CUBAN MEXICAN

Migration, Remittances, and Labor Supply in Albania

The New Metropolitan Geography of U.S. Immigration

The Effects of Interprovincial Migration on Human Capital Formation in China 1

Where U.S. Immigrants Were Born 1960

Measuring International Skilled Migration: New Estimates Controlling for Age of Entry

What Do Networks Do? The Role of Networks on Migration and Coyote" Use

REMITTANCE TRANSFERS TO ARMENIA: PRELIMINARY SURVEY DATA ANALYSIS

The Determinants and the Selection. of Mexico-US Migrations

The Economics of Immigration

Rural and Urban Migrants in India:

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES MEXICAN ENTREPRENEURSHIP: A COMPARISON OF SELF-EMPLOYMENT IN MEXICO AND THE UNITED STATES

Immigrant Incorporation and Local Responses

The Brookings Institution

Selection and Assimilation of Mexican Migrants to the U.S.

THE EVOLUTION OF WORKER S REMITTANCES IN MEXICO IN RECENT YEARS

Network Effects on Migrants Remittances

Household Inequality and Remittances in Rural Thailand: A Lifecycle Perspective

Immigrant Employment and Earnings Growth in Canada and the U.S.: Evidence from Longitudinal data

Asian Development Bank Institute. ADBI Working Paper Series NO LONGER LEFT BEHIND: THE IMPACT OF RETURN MIGRANT PARENTS ON CHILDREN S PERFORMANCE

Immigrant-native wage gaps in time series: Complementarities or composition effects?

Epicenter Cities and International Education 17th AIEC Melbourne, Victoria Australia

Representational Bias in the 2012 Electorate

Brain Drain, Brain Gain, and Economic Growth in China

Rural and Urban Migrants in India:

Discussion Paper Series DP

Do Migrants Improve Governance at Home? Evidence from a Voting Experiment

International Migration, Self-Selection, and the Distribution of Wages: Evidence from Mexico and the United States. February 2002

The Great Mexican Emigration

The Pennsylvania State University. The Graduate School. College of Education MIGRATION, FAMILY TYPES, CHILDREN'S EDUCATION AND WORK

Moving Up the Ladder? The Impact of Migration Experience on Occupational Mobility in Albania

U.S. Immigration Policy

Parental Response to Changes in Return to Education for Children: The Case of Mexico. Kaveh Majlesi. October 2012 PRELIMINARY-DO NOT CITE

An Integrated Analysis of Migration and Remittances: Modeling Migration as a Mechanism for Selection 1

Explaining the Deteriorating Entry Earnings of Canada s Immigrant Cohorts:

Labour Migration and Network Effects in Moldova

A Story on the Economic Consequences of Repatriations

Determinants of Return Migration to Mexico Among Mexicans in the United States

Emigration, Remittances, and Labor Force Participation in Mexico

Supplementary information for the article:

Do Remittances Compensate for the Negative Impact of Migration on Children s Schooling?

WHO MIGRATES? SELECTIVITY IN MIGRATION

Gender Discrimination in the Allocation of Migrant Household Resources

Migration and families left behind

BENCHMARKING REPORT - VANCOUVER

Megapolitan America. Luck Stone Corporation

Extended Families across Mexico and the United States. Extended Abstract PAA 2013

Twenty-first Century Gateways: Immigrant Incorporation in Suburban America

The New U.S. Demographics

Webinar on Reducing Barriers to Citizenship: New Research and the Need for a Partial Fee Waiver. January 8, pm ET / 1pm PT

14 Pathways Summer 2014

Repeat Migration and Remittances as Mechanisms for Wealth Inequality in 119 Communities From the Mexican Migration Project Data

Racial and Ethnic Separation in the Neighborhoods: Progress at a Standstill

The New Geography of Immigration and Local Policy Responses

International Remittances and the Household: Analysis and Review of Global Evidence

Openness and Poverty Reduction in the Long and Short Run. Mark R. Rosenzweig. Harvard University. October 2003

Lured in and crowded out? Estimating the impact of immigration on natives education using early XXth century US immigration

Children of Immigrants

The Effect of Ethnic Residential Segregation on Wages of Migrant Workers in Australia

Transcription:

Paternal Migration and Education Attainment in Rural Mexico (Job Market Paper) Ao Li Boston University November 14, 2013 Abstract Migration from poor to rich regions has increased dramatically in recent years. The current study examines the impact of international migration on education attainment of migrants children in rural communities using data from Mexican Migration Project (MMP143), with historical migration pattern and unemployment in popular destination as instruments. We find that if the father in a household has been a migrant worker, schooling of his children will decrease by about 1.3 years, which is larger than that in the previous literature (about 1 year). This effect mainly comes from boys; the impact on young girls is not significant. Our results bring support to two of the possible channel mentioned in the literature: the brain-drain channel and the mother-empowerment channel. Contact: aoli@bu.edu, Department of Economics, Boston University, 270 Bay State Road, Boston MA 02215. I would like to thank Dilip Mookherjee, Kehinde F. Ajayi and Samuel Bazzi for their guidance and encouragement. I also benefitted immensely from conversations with Randall Ellis, Jawwad Noor, Julian Tszkin Chan, Mingli Chen, Wei Yu and Yanfei Wang. All errors are my own. 1

1 Introduction Migration from poor to rich regions has increased dramatically in recent years. One of the biggest migration flows of workers happens between Mexico and the U.S. Currently, one in five households in rural Mexico has at least one member with international migration experience (McKenzie and Rapoport, 2011). Until recently, most research on migration focused on outcomes for the migrants themselves or the destination community (Blau and Kahn, 2012; Borjas, 1993; Card, 2001, 2009). Evidence now suggests that migration has important consequences for the families and communities at the origin as well (Antman, 2012c). The current study examines the impact of migration on education attainment of migrants children in rural Mexico. We follow McKenzie and Rapoport (2011) and Antman (2011a) in using historical migration rate and unemployment at popular destinations as instrumental variables to identify the general impact. We focus on the rural population (as opposed to both urban and rural data in Antman (2011a)), since whole-family migration is more prevalent in urban areas which leads to selection bias in the sample, and selection issues could be different between urban and rural areas. On the other hand, our main instrument of interest is unemployment rate at popular destinations, which varies at community level, comparing to historical migration rate which varies at state level. This allows us to capture the effect as the result of comparing migration communities with non-migration communities, while McKenzie and Rapoport (2011) only captures this effect as the result of state-level variation. Then, we speculate the more probable channels of this effect by analyzing regression results. The rest of this paper is organized as follows: Section 2 describes the different channels through which migration can affect education attainment and related literature; Section 3 describes the econometric model and instruments used; Section 4 provides basic information of the data; Section 5 presents the OLS and IV regression results; Section 6 concludes the paper. 2 Migration and Education: the Channels There are many channels through which parent s migration can affect children s education. In theory, the signs of these impacts are different, so estimating the general effect empirically is not trivial. Most of the literature has been focusing on this general effect without 2

discerning the possible channels. de Brauw and Giles (2008) exploits the exogenous national ID card distribution in rural China and find negative relationship between internal migration and high school enrollment. Meyerhoefer and Chen (2011) uses historical migration pattern in northeastern China to show negative effect on girls education attainment. Hanson and Woodruff (2003) and McKenzie and Rapoport (2011) both use historical pattern in Mexico-US migration as instrument. The former finds a positive relationship for younger children; the latter finds a negative one for all children in rural areas. Antman (2011b) uses employment statistics at destination as an IV and manage to find negative effect on time spent in studying for children aged 12-15 in an urban Mexican data set. In another paper, Antman (2012b) studies both urban and rural sample in Mexican Migration Project; she identifies the time of migration in order to set up a DID regression, with family fixed effects. The results suggests that father s U.S. migration during children s school years has a positive effect on younger girls. On the other hand, some recent works actively identify the possible routes separately. The following is a list of possible routes suggested in the literature. First, remittances relax resource constraints within household, enabling more investment in education. If this is the main source, we expect to see positive impact on children s education attainment, more so if the working period is longer. Yang (2008) relies on variation in exchange rate to estimate the effect of remittances in the Philippines. He shows that larger amounts of remittances do result in an increase in child schooling. Second, the migration of parent(s) leads to family disruption which could have negative consequences for children. This effect is likely to be larger as time with parental absence increases. Also studying the case in the Philippines, Cortés (2013) uses families with migrant fathers as control to show that mother s absence has a more detrimental effect on children s education. Third, possibility of working abroad can either encourage or discourage education, depending on the relative return of education (Beine et al., 2008, 2010; Mountford, 1997; Docquier and Rapoport, 2012). Previous studies, Chiquiar and Hanson (2005) for example, have shown that the return to Mexican education is lower in Mexico then in the U.S., so in our case a brain-drain like effect is more likely. Presumably migrant workers and their family members back home will gain more information about return to education in the U.S. over time, so the brain-drain effect is likely to be larger if the migrants spend more time in the U.S. Finally, with father being abroad, mother assumes more power in family decision making, including but not limit to resource allocation. There has been literature (Duflo, 2003; 3

Antman, 2012b) suggesting that investment on children s - especially girls - education increases when women has more power in distribution household income. 3 Econometric Model We are interested in the effect β of living in a migrant household on education attainment: Schooling i = βmigrant i + γx i + ε i where Schooling i is education attainment for a child measured in years of schooling completed, Migrant i is a dummy variable signifying whether the father in a household has ever been a migrant, and X i is a set of controls regarding personal, family, and community characteristics. Even if father last migrated before the child starts schooling or before the child is born, Migrant i could still affect education attainment through different channels, including remittance and brain-drain. Migrant i is also likely to be endogenous: the same (unobserved) characteristics could have effects on both migration status and education attainment. One possible way to address this problem is to use an instrumental variable for migrant status. The errors ε i could be correlated within communities so standard errors clustered at community level are reported in the regression results. A possible candidate for migrant status is historical migration rate. Existing migration network lowers the cost for future migrants, so they are more likely to move to places where many local predecessors have gone (Hanson and Woodruff, 2003). However, historical migration rates are partly determined by factors like historical inequality and development level, which probably still influence current economic and education outcomes (McKenzie and Rapoport, 2011). If we control for some more historical variables and/or interact historical rates with current characteristics, they could still be useful. For this study we collected Mexican migration population in the U.S. in 1924 at the state level, taken from Foerster (1925). To address the endogeneity problem of this instrument, we control for proportion of rural households owning land by state in 1910, a measure of inequality and economic development taken from Mcbride (1923). On the other hand, we can map Mexican communities into U.S. destinations by observing the current migration pattern, then use the employment situation at the destination as an instrument (Antman, 2012a). As a feature on the demand side of migration, it is likely to have influence on the decision of potential migrant workers; since this is a U.S.-based variable, 4

it is relatively unlikely to correlated with unobserved characteristics in Mexico households. We use MMP143 to identify the U.S. city to which the migrants from a Mexican community were most likely to be their most recent migration destination; for a summary of this connection see Table 1. Then we link observations with unemployment data of the year the community is surveyed from the Bureau of Labor Statistics according to the said correspondence. This is a relevant variable, at least for non-migration, since when the unemployment rate in the destination is high fathers who have never been to the U.S. is unlikely to go now. 4 Data The Mexican Migration Project (MMP), available at mmp.opr.princeton.edu, is a collaborative research project by Princeton University and the University of Guadalajara. It started collecting migration-related data in a few communities in 1982 and continues to do so every year since 1987. As of the last update (MMP143 in 2013), it has data for 143 communities. Massey and Zenteno (2000) argues that a reasonably accurate profile of rural Mexican migrants to the United States; in recent years it covers more and more urban communities as well. Since primary education coverage is almost universal in Mexico (Santibañez et al., 2005), our sample includes all children aged 11-19 living in a rural (defined as a community with a population of less than 50000 people) area post-1997 1. These children are likely to have finished or about to finish primary school but not all of them are in the job market. We focus on international migrations and define the father in a household as a migrant if he has reported migrant trips to U.S. and Canada in or before the survey year. Table 2 shows the basic descriptive statistics for the sample. Children with migrant fathers on average are younger, have slightly lower education attainment (but comparable to the age difference), live in slightly smaller households, and more likely to be girls. None of these difference is statistically significant. From Figure 1 we notice that the distributions of education attainment among children do not differ much between migrants children and non-migrants children. Their fathers usually have finished fewer years of education, but because of working abroad they have a higher income. The migrant ratio is exceptionally large (about one-third) in the sample, given that migrant and non-migrant households have roughly the same number of children. 1 The measurement of household income in MMP143 is different pre- and post- 1997. 5

5 Results We first examine the impact of father being a migrant on children s years of education completed. The control variables include age, age squared, gender and birth order of the child; father s and mother s education attainment; family size and income; and number of secondary schools per 1000 residents in the Municipio. Table 3 shows the results from OLS regression and IV regression, each reporting standard errors clustered at the community level under two specifications. OLS regressions show little and insignificant consequences from father being a migrant. Most other controls, including parents education and number of children in the household, have expected effects. Interestingly, girls finish more years of education than boys, holding everything else constant. To remove the endogenous effect in migrant status, we use historical migration and destination unemployment as instruments. Table 3 shows the first-stage results using these instruments. For the main IV regression, we employ two-step GMM IV regression 2 in Stata 11. We reject the null of weak instruments in Stock and Yogo (2002) test and fail to reject the null in over-identification tests for all IV specifications on our full sample. The result, shown in table 4, suggests that living in a household with a migrant father can reduce children s education attainment by more than one year, and the results are significant at 5% level. Given that the average years of education completed for the sample is less than 8 years, paternal migration seems to have a large negative impact. Comparing to the OLS results, this also suggests that the migrant community is likely to be positively selected. However, since the instruments are all on community level and above, this may reflect more about the local custom than the act of migration itself: people in communities with long migration tradition and/or good current migration prospect are less likely to invest a lot in education; they may want their children to end schooling early and test their earning potential in the U.S. This is most akin to the brain-drain channel mentioned above: the next generation is expected to work in the U.S. where return to Mexican schooling is lower, so education investment is not a big concern for families in these communities. In table 5, we divide our sample into four gender-age groups and see how this effect varies among different types of children. Most children do not go to school any more around age 16, as manifested by the insignificant effect of age in children older than 16. The negative effect of paternal migration is significant for boys and older girls, and is larger for older children who presumably follow their father s footstep and start working. The effect 2 Applying ivreg2 package by Baum et al. (2010) 6

on younger girls is insignificant. These results support the decision-making channel, where mothers have more say in resource allocation so the negative effect for girls is compensated but not for the boys, similar to the case in Antman (2012b). The results are robust to restricting sample to children aged 12-18 and 13-17. If we defined rural communities as one with a population with less than 10000 residents, then the sign and magnitude of the results still hold, but the exact effect cannot be identified accurately, due partly to the smaller sample size (about one-third of the observations are in communities with 10000-50000 residents). 6 Conclusion Equipped with MMP143 data set and two instruments, we find that in rural Mexico, if the father in a household has been a international migrant worker, schooling of his children will decrease by about 1.3 years, and the effect is larger for boys than for girls. The results are larger than that in the previous literature (about 1 year in general, 1.3 year for boys and less for girls, in McKenzie and Rapoport (2011)). The discrepancy could be a result from the different instruments used. Because of the limitation of the instruments, this is more likely a result of local custom instead of personal act. To describe the impact for having a migrant parent in the household, we need an instrument that varies at the household level, or use a panel data and exploit the family fixed effect. The gender-age group results suggests that the effect mainly comes from boys in the sample. This fit in the story suggested by Antman (2012b) among others, but the total effect is different; while Antman (2012b) finds positive impact for girls, our data show no significant effects for younger girls and negative effect for older girls. This is due to the difference in the sample: while Antman (2012b) uses the full MMP sample with both urban and rural children, we focus on rural data, since the mechanism of migration could be different between urban and rural people. In general, our results bring support to two of the possible channel mentioned in the literature: the brain-drain channel and the mother-empowerment channel. In unreported results, we find that father s length of U.S. migration experience has a negative but insignificant impact on children s education attainment. If this effect can be identified as negative, then it would further add support to the two aforementioned channels, while weaken the evidence for the remittance channel. 7

References Antman, F. M. (2011a). International Migration and Gender Discrimination among Children Left Behind. The American Economic Review, 101(3):645 649. Antman, F. M. (2011b). The Intergenerational Effects of Paternal Migration on Schooling and Work: What Can We Learn from Children s Time Allocations? Journal of Development Economics, 96(2):200 208. Antman, F. M. (2012a). Elderly Care and Intrafamily Resource Allocation when Children Migrate. The Journal of Human Resources, 47(2):331 363. Antman, F. M. (2012b). Gender, Educational Attainment, and the Impact of Parental Migration on Children Left Behind. Journal of Population Economics, 25(4):1187-1214. Antman, F. M. (2012c). The Impact of Migration on Family Left Behind. IZA Discussion Paper No. 6374. Baum, C. F., Schaffer, M. E., and Stillman, S. (2010). ivreg2: Stata Module for Extended Instrumental variables/2sls, GMM and AC/HAC, LIML and k-class Regression. Beine, M., Docquier, F., and Rapoport, H. (2008). Brain Drain and Human Capital Formation in Developing Countries: Winners and Losers. The Economic Journal, 118(April):631 652. Beine, M., Docquier, F., and Rapoport, H. (2010). On the Robustness of Brain Gain Estimates. Annals of Economics and Statistics / Annales d Économie et de Statistique, 97-98:143 165. Blau, F. D. and Kahn, L. M. (2012). Immigration and the Distribution of Incomes. NBER Working Paper 18515. Borjas, G. J. (1993). The Intergenerational Mobility of Immigrants. Journal of Labor Economics, 11(1):113 135. Card, D. (2001). Immigrant Inflows, Native Outflows, and the Local Labor Market Impacts of Higher Immigration. Journal of Labor Economics, 19(1):22 64. Card, D. (2009). Immigration and Inequality. The American Economic Review, 99(2):1 21. Chiquiar, D. and Hanson, G. H. (2005). International Migration, Self-Selection, and the Distribution of Wages: Evidence from Mexico and the United States. Journal of Political Economy, 113(2):239 281. 8

Cortés, P. (2013). The feminization of international migration and its effects on the children left behind: Evidence from the Philippines. mimeo. de Brauw, A. and Giles, J. (2008). Migrant opportunity and the educational attainment of youth in rural China. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 4526. Docquier, F. and Rapoport, H. (2012). Globalization, brain drain, and development. Journal of Economic Literature, 50(3):681 730. Duflo, E. (2003). Grandmothers and Granddaughters: Old Age Pensions and Intrahousehold Allocation in South Africa. The World Bank Economic Review, 17(1):1 25. Foerster, R. F. (1925). The racial problems involved in immigration from Latin America and the West Indies to the United States. U.S. Department of Labor, Washington, DC. Hanson, G. H. and Woodruff, C. (2003). Emigration and educational attainment in Mexico. mimeo. Massey, D. S. and Zenteno, R. (2000). A validation of the ethnosurvey: The case of Mexico-US migration. International Migration Review, 34(3):766 793. Mcbride, G. M. (1923). The Land Systems of Mexico. Condé Nast Press, Greenwish, CO. McKenzie, D. and Rapoport, H. (2011). Can migration reduce educational attainment? evidence from Mexico. Journal of Population Economics, 24(4):1311 1358. Meyerhoefer, C. D. and Chen, C. J. (2011). The effect of parental labor migration on children s educational progress in rural China. Review of Economics of the Household, 9(3):379 396. Mountford, A. (1997). Can a Brain Drain be Good for Growth in the Source Economy? Journal of Development Economics, 53(2):287 303. Santibañez, L., Vernez, G., and Razquin, P. (2005). Education in Mexico: Challenges and Opportunities. Technical report, RAND Corporation. Stock, J. H. and Yogo, M. (2002). Testing for weak instruments in linear IV regression. Technical Working Paper 284. Yang, D. (2008). International Migration, Remittances and Household Investment: Evidence from Philippine Migrants Exchange Rate Shocks. The Economic Journal, 118(528):591 630. 9

Table 1: Popular Destinations by Community Destination No. of Communities Associated Austin-San Marcos, TX 1 Charlotte-Gastonia-Rockhill, NC-SC 2 Chicago, IL 11 Dallas, TX 3 Denver, CO 3 Houston, TX 1 Las Vegas, NV-AZ 1 Los Angeles-Long Beach, CA 17 Louisville, KY-IN 1 Minneapolis-St. Paul, MN-WI 2 New York, NY 3 Oakland, CA 1 Orange County (sic), CA 1 Philadelphia, PA-NJ 2 Phoenix-Mesa, AZ 1 Portland-Vancouver, OR-WA 2 Reading, PA 1 San Diego, CA 1 San Francisco, CA 1 San Jose, CA 4 Stockton-Lodi, CA 1 Tulsa, OK 1 Total 61 10

Table 2: Descriptive Statistics for Rural Children 11-19 Years old Full Sample w/ Migrant Father w/o Migrant Father Difference Father s education 6.420 5.612 6.842-1.230 (4.330) (3.633) (4.596) Mother s education 6.171 5.833 6.348-0.515 (3.811) (3.447) (3.977) Child s age 15.080 14.925 15.161-0.236 (2.574) (2.592) (2.561) Child s education 7.747 7.524 7.863-0.339 (2.707) (2.675) (2.717) Number of children 3.706 3.858 3.627 0.231 in the household (1.849) (1.977) (1.774) HH income 28270.54 29052.21 27931.63 1120.58 (1997 Peso) (43027.4) (61579.9) (31788.3) Child is female 50.12% 51.28% 49.53% Obs. 7064 2420 4644 % in sample 100% 34.26% 65.74% 11

Figure 1: Histogram of Years of Education, by Father s Migrant Status 12

Table 3: First-stage Results Dependent variable Father has been a migrant Unemployment rate -0.0244** -0.0283*** at destination (0.00958) (0.00888) Migration population 0.0000751** 0.0000739** in 1925 (0.0000353) (0.0000360) Age of child -0.0225-0.0376 (0.0304) (0.0274) Age of child squared 0.000357 0.000847 (0.00105) (0.000946) Child is female 0.0113 0.00901 (0.00981) (0.00908) Father s education -0.0147*** -0.0148*** (0.00341) (0.00275) Mother s education 0.00462 0.00471 (0.00455) (0.00357) No. of children 0.00816 0.00153 in household (0.00835) (0.00660) Household income 2.99e-07 (2.40e-07) No. of secondary schools 0.0191 0.0105 in Municipio per 1000 resident (0.0943) (0.0888) Birth order 0.0140 0.0171* (0.0121) (0.00960) Home ownership rate -0.0135-0.0130 in 1910 (0.0129) (0.0115) Obs. 4381 7064 F-statistic 8.36 9.76 Prob. > F 0.0006 0.0002 R-squared 0.0625 0.0551 *: significant at 10% level **: significant at 5% level ***: significant at 1% level 13

Table 4: Effect of Migration Status on Years of Education Completed OLS 1 IV 1 OLS 2 IV 2 Father has been 0.025-1.39** 0.0374-1.28** a migrant (0.112) (0.680) (0.079) (0.648) Age of child 2.21*** 2.15*** 2.21*** 2.17*** (0.153) (0.162) (0.123) (0.125) Age of child squared -0.0518*** -0.0506*** -0.0519*** -0.0512*** (0.00553) (0.00580) (0.00447) (0.00442) Child is female 0.220*** 0.262*** 0.250*** 0.269*** (0.0538) (0.0503) (0.0475) (0.0475) Father s education 0.106*** 0.085*** 0.114*** 0.0925*** (0.0121) (0.0183) (0.0107) (0.0154) Mother s education 0.119*** 0.120*** 0.116*** 0.121*** (0.0113) (0.0114) (0.0105) (0.0110) No. of children -0.0618** -0.0438-0.0394-0.0318 in household (0.0298) (0.0292) (0.0262) (0.0247) No. of secondary schools 0.0827 0.0922 0.0943 0.102 in Municipio per 1000 resident (0.197) (0.215) (0.240) (0.260) Birth order -0.230*** -0.207*** -0.251*** -0.234*** (0.0647) (0.0649) (0.0516) (0.0507) Household income -7.67e-07-2.07e-07 (5.34e-07) (6.36e-07) Home ownership rate 0.0322 0.00490 0.0619 0.0553 in 1910 (0.0388) (0.0386) (0.0381) (0.0359) Obs. 4381 4381 7064 7064 R-squared 0.4457 0.3875 0.4365 0.3847 *: significant at 10% level **: significant at 5% level ***: significant at 1% level 14

Table 6: Effect of Migration Status on Years of Education Completed: Age-Gender Groups Female 11-15 Female 16-19 Male 11-15 Male 16-19 Father has been -0.550-2.14* -0.947* -1.89** a migrant (0.708) (1.23) (0.561) (1.01) Age of child 2.24*** 3.38 2.04*** -1.46 (0.495) (2.50) (0.513) (2.22) Age of child squared -0.0567*** -0.0873-0.0485** 0.0497 (0.0193) (0.0719) (0.0198) (0.0638) Father s education 0.0373* 0.132*** 0.0441*** 0.161*** (0.0200) (0.0309) (0.0169) (0.0254) Mother s education 0.0824*** 0.188*** 0.0643*** 0.163*** (0.0133) (0.0255) (0.0130) (0.0247) No. of children -0.0299-0.0942** -0.0538-0.0960* in household (0.0310) (0.0478) (0.0328) (0.0532) No. of secondary schools 0.113 0.149 0.0617 0.113 in Municipio per 1000 resident (0.240) (0.388) (0.250) (0.430) Birth order -0.0470-0.173* -0.0876-0.131* (0.0799) (0.098903) (0.0950) (0.0790) Home ownership rate 0.131*** 0.0647 0.0913** -0.0581 in 1910 (0.0421) (0.0551) (0.0413) (0.0559) Obs. 1907 1634 1925 1598 R-squared 0.3550 0.1190 0.3084 0.1543 *: significant at 10% level **: significant at 5% level ***: significant at 1% level 15