Actors and regulatory roles in private and mixed forms of food regulation

Similar documents
-- CALL FOR PAPERS --

GLOBAL GOVERNANCE IN FOOD SAFETY: A COMPARATIVE STUDY ON PRIVATE FOOD STANDARD INITIATIVES

1 Hybridization of food governance: An analytical framework

PDF hosted at the Radboud Repository of the Radboud University Nijmegen

Seminar: Corporate Governance in a globalized economy Autumn Term 2012

Series Law of the Future Series No. 1 (2012)

NON-GOVERNMENTAL ORGANISATIONS IN INTERNATIONAL REGULATION: LESSONS FROM CERTIFICATION SCHEMES

PRIVATE STANDARDS AND THE WTO COMMITTEE ON SANITARY AND PHYTOSANITARY MEASURES

FOOD LAW ENFORCEMENT POLICY

Barbara Koremenos The continent of international law. Explaining agreement design. (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press)

Consultation draft 31 March, 2005

Transition document Transition document, Version: 4.1, October 2017

Import-dependent firms and their role in EU- Asia Trade Agreements

330 I CON 13 (2015),

THE INTERPLAY OF PUBLIC AND PRIVATE STANDARDS

GENERAL REPORT ON THE OUTCOME OF A SERIES OF MISSIONS CARRIED OUT IN ALL MEMBER STATES FROM JUNE 2004 TO OCTOBER 2005 TO EVALUATE

Private-regulation in global value chain a trade barrier or an opportunity for public-private co-operation?

Support for Farmers' Cooperatives Executive Summary

HOW TO MAKE TRADE BENEFIT WORKERS? Core Labour Standards Plus Linking trade and decent work in global supply chains

E15 Initiative on Regulatory Systems Coherence. Private standards Implications for trade, development and governance

Modern Politics in Animal Welfare: The Changing Character of Governance of Animal Welfare and the Role of Private Standards

THE CROATIAN PARLIAMENT

PERSPECTIVE LISTENING TO THE FOOD AND DRINK

Having regard to the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union, and in particular Article 43(2) and Article 168(4)(b) thereof,

1. Definitions of corporate involvement in global environmental governance

This document is meant purely as a documentation tool and the institutions do not assume any liability for its contents

Voluntary Initiatives and the World Trade Organisation

LAW ON PRODUCT SAFETY. (Directive 2001/95/EC)

EUI Working Papers. RSCAS 2010/53 ROBERT SCHUMAN CENTRE FOR ADVANCED STUDIES Private Regulation Series-04

Private Agri-food Standards: Supply Chains and the Governance of Standards

The Conflict-Free Gold Standard:

Feed Act (86/2008, amendments up to 565/2014 included)

2 Labor standards in international supply chains

Theories of Regulation (410115) 1

Competition and cooperation in the market of voluntary sustainability standards

#GoverningMPAs

Ronie Garcia-Johnson, Assistant Professor of Environmental Policy Nicholas School of the Environment Duke University

Guidance Notes on the Food Safety Act 1990 (Amendment) Regulations 2004 and the General Food Regulations 2004

Report of the second meeting of the Board on Trade and Sustainable Development to the Civil Society Dialogue Forum

LIST OF KEY MARKET ACCESS BARRIERS IN MEXICO UNDER THE MARKET ACCESS STRATEGY 22 September 2016 MAAC/

CAPTURING THE GAINS. Governance in a value chain world. Frederick Mayer and Anne Posthuma. e c o n o m i c a n d s o c i a l u p g r a d i n g

European Food Law Beginning and Development

For a Single Market with a purpose

REGULATIONS. (Text with EEA relevance)

English summary of book L OMS en péril» (WHO in peril) in French, by the author, Yves Beigbeder 1.

Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governance

I will be limiting my comments to the draft Guidance Note for Principle 7.

Guidelines on self-regulation measures concluded by industry under the Ecodesign Directive 2009/125/EC

Dr. John J. Hamre President and CEO Center for Strategic and International Studies Washington, D. C.

Feed Law Enforcement Guidance Document (Northern Ireland)

Labour Standards and Trade Policy

WTO and Multilateral Trading System: The Way Forward to Bali Ministerial

SADC TRADE RELATED FACILITY (TRF)

Corporate Accountability International s Response to the WHO s Public Web Consultation on Engagement with Non-State Actors 20 March 2013

First Nations Perspectives: Review of National Aquatic Animal Health Program

INTERNATIONAL FOOD STANDARDS AND WTO LAW

INSTITUTIONAL DYNAMICS IN ENVIRONMENTAL GOVERNANCE

Introduction. Walter Mattli and Ngaire Woods

WTO LAW IN THE LIGHT OF ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION

Article 1 General principles and objectives

Thailand Taking Action against Illegal, Unreported and Unregulated Fishing (IUU) (Continued)

Programme Specification

Scientific Coordinator: Petros C. Mavroidis European University Institute

***I DRAFT REPORT. EN United in diversity EN 2011/0288(COD)

What Makes A Regulator Excellent? A Risk Regulation Perspective

Answers by the Minister of Foreign Trade and Development Cooperation to:

Does the Agreement on Internal Trade Do Enough to Liberalize Canada s Domestic Trade in Agri-food Products?

for developing countries

Barriers to Fishery Exports from Developing Countries: The Impact of U.S. FDA Food Safety Regulation

A Policy Agenda for Diversity and Minority Integration

About the programme MA Comparative Public Governance

International social and environmental production standards: should corporate social responsibility get a slice of the WTO pie? Mathis, J.H.

INTERNATIONAL TRADE. To accompany the Georgia International Business Curriculum. CTAE Resource Network, Instructional Resources Office, 2010

Published in: African Journal of International and Comparative Law

Agri-Exports: What s holding Sri Lanka back? The impact of domestic barriers to trade

GEA and Trade Facilitation

Nesting, Overlap and Parallelism: Governance Schemes for International Production Standards

ITUC 1 Contribution to the pre-conference negotiating text for the UNCTAD XII Conference in Accra, April

Sanitary and Phytosanitary (SPS) Annex to the SADC Protocol on Trade:

September Press Release /SM/9256 SC/8059 Role of business in armed conflict can be crucial for good or ill

IBFAN-GIFA Briefing paper Comment on the draft 13 th General Programme of Work Presented at EBSS

The Effectiveness of Transnational Rule-Setting Organisations in Global Sustainability Politics:

The Beef Traceability Law. (The Law for Special Measures Concerning the Management and Relay of Information for Individual Identification of Cattle)

Freedom of Association and the Right to Bargain Collectively in Mexico

EU-Mexico Free Trade Agreement EU TEXTUAL PROPOSAL. Chapter on Sanitary and Phytosanitary Measures

ANTI HUMAN TRAFFICKING, ANTI IUU FISHING AND PROMOTING SUSTAINABLE FISHING

Global Health Governance: Institutional Changes in the Poverty- Oriented Fight of Diseases. A Short Introduction to a Research Project

Overview of the WTO TBT Agreement. Diane C. Thompson Principal Standards Advisor Standards Alliance. Lusaka, Zambia November 30, 2016

EUROPEAN COMMISSION HEALTH AND CONSUMERS DIRECTORATE-GENERAL

Food Information Regulation Improvement Notice Drafting. Andrew Gilden

Dr. C. (Cor) J. van Montfort

Beyond Policy Change: Convergence of Corporatist Patterns in the European Union?

REPORT OF THE FOURTEENTH MEETING OF THE FLEP-FORUM HELD IN SANTIAGO DE COMPOSTELLA ON 14 AND 15 JUNE 1999

A SHORT GUIDE TO CUSTOMS RISK

Anti Human Trafficking, Anti IUU Fishing and Promoting Sustainable Fishing

Technical Barriers to Trade (TBT) Annex to the SADC Protocol on Trade

How To Protect Workers in Global Supply Chain?

Making Global Trade Governance Work for Developing Countries

(Acts whose publication is obligatory) of 23 February 2005

The whistleblowing procedure is based on the following principles:

Transcription:

Actors and regulatory roles in private and mixed forms of food regulation Dr. ir. Tetty Havinga Institute for the Sociology of Law Radboud University Nijmegen PO Box 9049 6532 SB Nijmegen Netherlands T.Havinga@jur.ru.nl T +31-24-3615915 Paper for Regulation in the Age of Crisis Third Biennial Conference of the Standing Group on Regulatory Governance of the European Consortium for Political Research (ECPR) June 17-19 2010, Dublin VERY EARLY DRAFT. I AM STILL WORKING ON THIS PAPER. COMMENTS ARE WELCOME. Abstract In food regulation, as in other domains of regulation, the traditional command-and-control regulation by the state has been criticized for being ineffective, inflexible and neglecting the responsibilities of citizens and organizations. Transnational and national governments as well as the food industry, retailers and NGOs initiated new ways to deal with food regulation. Many of these new forms of regulation are characterised by a mix of public and private organisations involved in rule-making, implementation, monitoring compliance, and enforcement. In this paper I want to explore which actors are involved in private and mixed forms of food regulation. This question is important for problems of effectiveness, legitimacy and accountability of regulatory regimes. I argue that a dichotomous distinction between public (governmental) and private (non-governmental) regulation is not an adequate conceptualisation for analysing the reconfiguration of relationships between actors involved in food regulation. We need more sophisticated distinctions linking the type of actor to the role they play in the regulatory process. I unravel the regulatory process into multiple regulatory roles/actions to analyse complex patterns of actor involvement in a regulatory regime. 1

Actors and regulatory roles in private and mixed forms of food regulation Introduction The regulation and governance of food has changed dramatically in recent decades. National governmental bodies used to take the lead in rule-making and enforcing compliance. Several developments have transformed food regulation from traditional state regulation into private or mixed forms of regulation. Traditional command-and-control regulation by the state has been criticized for being ineffective, inflexible and neglecting the responsibilities of citizens and organizations. Food scares and crisis such as BSE (bovine spongiform encephalopathy), microbial contamination and tainted milk, make food risks more visible and recognised. Governments responded to the alleged decline in consumer confidence with stricter food safety regulations. Producers and suppliers became primarily responsible for food safety while national governments became responsible for controlling the adequacy of risk controlling mechanisms of companies in a food chain. Due to their legal responsibility and because of fear for potential reputation damage in case of unsafe food products, private actors developed initiatives for decreasing food safety risks and increasing consumer confidence in safe food. At the same time food chains became more internationalised. In response to consumer demand, improved techniques for transport and storage, and growing consumer incomes, European retailers increasingly obtain fresh products from all over the world enabling a year-round supply. Besides, claims are being made for responsibly produced food (sustainable food production, fair trade, animal welfare and labour rights) and healthy food (sugar, salt, fat, additives, low calorie). In the context of these developments new forms of food regulation emerged, including private food standards, corporate social responsibility initiatives, and codes of conduct. The transformation from traditional state regulation towards less state centred forms of regulation, involved a new relationship and a renewed allocation of responsibilities between government bodies on the one side and private actors on the other. These new forms are characterised by a less dominant role for the government and more responsibilities for private actors (Havinga 2006, Oosterveer 2005, Marsden c.s. 2010). New forms of food regulation include not only public actors, but also private actors such as firms, NGOs and other organisations both inside 2

and outside the production chain. Recent trends are the emergence of retailer-led food governance and of global coalitions for setting standards, an increased use of global business to business standards and of third party certification (Fulponi 2006, Harrison 1997, Hatanaki & Busch 2008, Havinga 2006, Marsden et al 2000, 2010), and a move from a prescriptive towards an enforced self-regulating approach (Martinez et. al. 2007). Marsden et al (2010) talk about the Public-Private Model of Food Regulation. Henson & Caswell (1999) distinguish between direct and indirect regulation of food safety (see figure 1). Direct regulation entails prescriptions and requirements for the production and handling of food to assure the production of safe food. Even though indirect regulation does not provide prescriptions for the production and product, it is nevertheless expected to act as an incentive to implement food safety controls. Most research on food safety has focussed on direct forms of food safety regulation. Figure 1: Types of regulation of food safety Source of Character of the rules the rules Direct Dutch Commodities Act Public (Warenwet) 1 UK 1990 Food Safety Act EU General Food Law 2 Indirect Product liability law 3 TBT-GATT agreement 4 Publicprivate Industrial code of hygienic practice Insurance policy Private Private food safety certification scheme (GlobalGap, MSC) Consumer complaint proceedings Recently, not only public regulatory arrangements but also private forms of direct food safety regulation received attention (Fulponi 2006, Havinga 2006, Henson & Reardon 1 Dutch Law of 19 September 1919 (Stb. 581, latest change Stb. 2001, 601). 2 Regulation EC no. 178/2002 of 28 January 2002 laying down the General Principles and Requirements of Food Law, Establishing the European Food Safety Authority and Laying down procedures in matters of food safety. Official Journal of the European Communities 2002 L31/1-24. 3 Art. 185-193 bk 6 BW. 4 GATT Agreement on Technical Barriers to Trade (TBT). 3

2005, Marsden et al 2000, 2010, Martinez et al 2007, Rothstein 2005, Van Waarden 2006). Public and private actors in regulatory arrangements Some authors just distinguish between public and private actors (e.g. Spruyt 2001; Josling, Roberts & Orden 2004: 156), state and non-state actors or governmental and non-governmental actors. Daniel Stewart (2010) implicitly distinguishes state actors from non-state actors in his analysis of the availability of judicial review to actions of non-state actors. Bingen & Busch (2006: 246) observe a constantly evolving and changing global network of relationships among public and private, mandatory, voluntary, and national and international standards bodies instead of neatly delineated public and private responsibilities (p 246). The social fields around food safety regulation include three important institutional actors: state (governmental agencies), industry (food industry and farmers) and third parties 5 (private auditing and certification organizations, retailers and consumer organizations) (Havinga 2006). Several authors on regulation replace this public private dichotomy by a threefold classification: state, market and civil society (in particular authors on environmental regulation or sustainability). In their analysis of non-state market driven governance systems (NSMD) Bernstein & Cashore (2007: 356) distinguish two forms of non-state actors: firms and NGOs. Abbott and Snidal (2009) provide a systematic depiction of the variety of regulatory standardsetting (RSS) in their Governance Triangle. Abbott and Snidal consider RSS rules to be a form of regulation, even though the are voluntary. They distinguish three groups of actors directly involved in RSS: states, firms and NGOs. 5 This concept of third party differs from the concept of Levi-Faur, see later. 4

From Kenneth W. Abbott & Duncan Snidal (2009) The Governance Triangle: Regulatory Standards Institutions in the Shadow of the State, in Walter Mattli & Ngaire Woods eds The politics of global regulation 2009, (Princeton University Press) p.50. The seven zones in the triangle indicate the three forms of single-actor standards, three forms of dual-actor standards and one form involving direct participation of all three groups of actors. Abbott and Snidal have included only four regulatory food standards in their governance triangle 6, in another publication they include another two food standards in zone 2 7. Other food standards could easily be included. This illustrates a disadvantage of making types. GlobalGap will be classified as a single-actor standard (Zone 2). However, GlobalGap is not a single-actor standard, but a standard set by actors from a single category. In GlobalGap are multiple actors involved with very different positions and interests! Abbott and Snidal show the evolution of the governance triangle (see figure). In the pre-1985 period there are only a few RSS schemes, mostly in Zone 1 (state). The 1985-94 decade shows an emergence of RSS schemes particularly firm-schemes, but also the first multi-stakeholder schemes en NGO schemes. The post-1994 period shows a continued proliferation of firm schemes and an increased number of NGO schemes and the emergence of collaborative schemes (NGOs and firms or tripartite, zone 6 and 7). 6 Marine Stewardship Council 1997, Max Havelaar 1988 (fair trade coffee) and International Federation of Organic Agriculture Movements 1972 (organic food), all three in zone 6 (dual-actor standards with involvement of firms & NGOs) and WHO Code of Marketing for Breast-milk Substitutes 1981 in zone 1 (state standard). 7 GlobalGap 1997 en SQF 1994 (SafeQualityFood), Abbott & Snidal 2009 p 513 (Abbott, Kenneth W. -& Duncan Snidal (2009) Strenghtening International Regulation Through Transnational New Governance: Overcoming the Orchestration Deficit, Van der Bilt Journal of Transnational Law vol 42, p 501-578) 5

From Kenneth W. Abbott & Duncan Snidal (2009) The Governance Triangle: Regulatory Standards Institutions in the Shadow of the State, in Walter Mattli & Ngaire Woods eds The politics of global regulation 2009, (Princeton University Press) p.53. Levi-Faur (2010) distinguishes between three similar groups of actors: civil, market, state actors. For Levi-Faur a non governmental organization can be controlled by civil society actors (CiNGO), controlled by market actors (MaNGO), or controlled by state actors (GoNGO). This distinction between different types of NGOs which act as regulators will allow us to develop a clearer understanding of hybrid designs of regulatory institutions. Because of the ambivalent definition of NGO I would prefer to speak from civil actors (next to governmental or state actors and firms or market actors). Authors on food regulation tend to focus less on NGOs or civil society, probably because these actors do not play a significant role in many food regulatory arrangements. Food regulatory schemes are dominated by state regulation and by firm schemes. But it is possible that in the future civil actors become more important in food regulation. Already, we can observe an increase of these actors in the regulatory domain striving for social interests (e.g. fair trade movement), environmental interests (e.g. organic food movement) or animal welfare (e.g. animal rights movement). In another stream of literature authors on food regulation do particularly analyse the networks or production chains connected to a regulatory regime. Marsden c.s. (2010: 120) distinguish between three types of interest in the new hybrid food policy-formation network: 6

1. policy & regulatory interests, 2. private interests, and 3. consumer & social interests. These types correspond with the three actor categories in the regulatory triangle of Abbott and Snidal (state, firms, NGOs). Marsden et al 2010 argue that it is the interactions between public and private actors that are essential to a fuller understanding of the food system (p 283, italics in original) and the boundaries between public, private and civil society interests are less clear with time (p 290). 8 In their analysis of the new regulation and governance of food Marsden c.s. pay attention to several actors such as UK and EU governmental bodies, corporate retailers, farmers, producers, manufacturers, global standard-setting organisations, private certification bodies, logistic firms, environmental and social NGOs. They paint a picture of various complex networks involving many organisations and regulations (see for example the figure below). 8 Other authors also observe the blurring of the public/private distinction and the rise of hybrid organizations and networks combining governmental and non-governmental actors (e.g. Bingen & Busch 2006, Black 2002, Havinga 2006, Levi-Faur 2010). 7

From T. Marsden, A. Flynn & M. Harrison, The New Regulation and Governance of Food. Beyond the Food Crisis? New York/London: Routledge 2010, p. 280. Bush & Oosterveer (2007) describe export firms as key actors in the shrimp trade linking local producers in Thailand and Vietnam with global trade networks. They conclude that certification bodies are unable to audit the chain below the level of exporters, where capital and information flows through informal, diffuse trade networks (p. 391). A governance arrangement involves a complex mix of state and non-state actors: bureaucrats, retailers, wholesalers, importers and exporters, local trade network, producers, NGOs, processing companies and consumers. In a study of FSC and MSC Van Waarden (2009/2010) points to the involvement of a wide range of actors from all phases in the value chain with different interests as one of the factors contributing to the success of these schemes: small scale and large fisheries, fishery associations and cooperations, suppliers, manufacturers, distribution, retailers, scientists, indigenous peoples organisations, fishery communities, and environmental groups. 8

The broad threefold categorisation of actors involved in regulation: state actors, firms and civil society, is useful in analysing the balance between these three actor types in comparative perspective, historical as Abbot and Snidal do or comparing between countries, industries or types of regulation. However, for analyzing the involvement of actors in private and hybrid systems of food regulation a more sophisticated categorisation of firms is needed. Consider three private food regulatory regimes GlobalGap, BRC, and a Dutch Halal certification. All three will be classified as firm scheme in zone 2 from Abbott and Snidal. Yet the three are only similar in some ways. For analysing the effectiveness and legitimacy of a regulatory regime it is important to distinguish between private actors which are regulated (regulatees), private actors which are part of the production chain but are not regulated themselves by the regulation at hand (such as suppliers and retailers), and private actors providing services to the regulated industry (such as certification and auditing organisations). The increasing role of transnational and international governmental bodies in food regulation makes it inevitable to distinguish between different levels of state actors. Following Marsden c.s. (2010) civil society interests can broken down into social interests (e.g. child labor, fair trade, occupational health), environmental interests (e.g. biodiversity, sustainability, insecticides) and consumer interests (e.g. safety, food security, choice and price). Position in Actor regulation/supply chain State - transnational level - (federal) level - State level - local level Non- Market/firms Inside supply - regulatee state/private chain - not subject of regulation at hand (farming, agricultural logistics, manufacturing, 9

Civil society (NGOs) Outside supply chain food logistics, retail/catering) Providing services (e.g. auditing, certification) - Social interests - Environmental interests - Consumer interests Regulatory roles Traditional Command-and-Control regulation is conceptualised as state legislation. However, a regulatory regime comprises not only legislation and other rules. Picciotto (2002) conceptualised regulation as consisting of three elements: rule-making, monitoring compliance, and enforcement (Scott 2002, Havinga 2006, Levi-Faur 2010). Besides Levi-Faur (2010) distinguishes between three roles: regulator, regulatee, third party 9. Combining these three roles with three actor types he distinguishes 27 types of third party regulatory designs (see figure below). 9 Levi-Faur 2010 distinguishes three main strategies in regulation: 1. first party regulation: Regulator=regulatee (self-regulation), 2. second party regulation: regulator independent from regulatee (e.g. state regulation of business, or retailer imposing regulation on suppliers), 3. third party regulation relationship between regulator and regulatee is mediated by a third party as independent auditor (eg EurepGAP). The meaning of the concepts first party, second party and third party is not consistently used in the literature. E.g. Bingen & Busch (2006) : 1 party = supplier, 2 party = buyer, 3 party = independent third assessing compliance, 4 part = staat/regulatory agency. Havinga (2006) categorized retailers setting food safety standards for their suppliers as third party regulation. 10

From Levi-Faur, David (2010) Regulation & Regulatory Governance, Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governance 1 (regulation.huji.ac.il) Mattli & Woods (2009) include implementation in their definition of regulation: the organisation and control of economic, political, and social activities by means of making, implementing, monitoring, and enforcing of rules. Including implementation means considering the regulatees as part of the regulatory regime. For Abbott & Snidal (2009: 63) the regulatory process comprises five main stages (or five tasks): 1 Agenda-setting (placing an issue on the regulatory agenda) 2 Negotiation (negotiating, drafting and promulgating of standards) 3 Implementation (implementing standards within the operations of targets of regulation such as firms) 4 Monitoring compliance 5 Enforcement (promoting compliance and responding to non-compliance) Agenda-setting is added to rule-making. Abbott & Snidal use the abbreviation ANIME to refer to these five stages. Studying private forms of food regulation such as GlobalGap and BRC, I miss one important phase in ANIME. In traditional command and control regulation after making the rules the next phase is implementing the rules. However, rules from for instance GlobalGap or BRC are not just being implemented in farms or food industry. It 11

seems to be crucial that the rules are promoted and eventually made mandatory by dominant market parties such as big supermarket chains first. Regulatees have to adopt a regulation. By and large, this may be because the regulation is legal obligatory, or because adoption is an obligation by a dominant actor in the market (retailers) or because the regulatee considers adoption beneficial for some reason (improving reputation, market share, price). Van Waarden (2009/2010) distinguishes three main functions for a certification standard organization such as FSC and MSC: standard setting, accreditation, and trademark assurance. Conclusion When I planned to write this paper some months ago, I had in mind just to add some distinctions of actors to the three main actor types (state, form, NGO) and to include some regulatory activities to the three elements of regulation (rulemaking, monitoring and enforcement). Working on the paper and reading and rereading literature made be change my mind. It will not work that way. It is too complex and many distinctions are only important in particular regulatory arrangements. Besides, it often is more important to know whether the different tasks ( e.g. drafting of the rules, implementing of the rules and enforcing compliance) are carried out by the same organization or by three or more different organizations than that they are carried out all by market actors (making this a single-actor regulation). Black (2008) observes accountability problems because regulatory roles and responsibilities are spread over several actors (deciding on goals, drafting standard, monitoring, enforcement). It is impossible to call a standard-setter to account for enforcement of the rules or to call the enforcer to account for rules he did not make. Black (2008) asks How to call to account a constellation of regulators? To make it even more complex: the involvement of actors and the roles they perform develop in course of time. Bernstein and Cashore (2007) showed for non-state market driven governance systems that political legitimacy is constructed in a three-phaseprocess with different relationships between the actors and participation of different actors. Bernstein and Cashore distinguish between the initiation phase, the phase of widespread support and the phase of political legitimacy. A picture of the actors and roles involved in Eurepgap in 1997 differs from actors and roles in GlobalGap in 2010 12

(Van der Kloet & Havinga 2008). The picture will be different at another moment in time. For these reasons I simply end with a catalogue of regulatory activities connected to three main phases that apply to every regulatory arrangement: 1. Rule making 2. Implementation 3. Monitoring and enforcement Actions Sideline actions I. Rule making 1. first step (initiator) agenda setting 2. determine goals of regulation 3. negotiation about the rules - Lobbying - Mobilizing resistance or support - adapting the rules (to new situations and acquired experience) 4. drafting the rules 5. lay down the rules (decide on and promulgating the rules) 6. further regulations and implementing orders II. Implementation 7. adopting the rules 8. imposing the rules on suppliers - promoting and supporting the rules or other actors in the supply - Education & coaching chain (make the rules compulsory for other actors) 9. implementing rules within firms (or other targets of regulation/regulatees) - facilitating III. Monitoring and enforcement 10. testing 11. inspection - accreditation certification bodies 12. audit, verification - trademark assurance 13. certification - developing instruments and 13

14. documentation 15. tracing non-compliant and undesirable behaviour 16. sanctioning non-compliance [Legal enforcement / withdrawal certificate] strategy in response to non compliance - evaluation and adaptation of monitoring and enforcement strategy/rules We need to analyse particular regulatory regimes and establish which actors are involved, how they are interrelated and what role they play. I intend to work on this in the coming months based on cases from your papers and other available case studies. Literature Kenneth W. Abbott & Duncan Snidal (2009) Strengthening International Regulation Through Transnational New Governance: Overcoming the Orchestration Deficit, Van der Bilt Journal of Transnational Law vol 42, p 501-578 Kenneth W. Abbott & Duncan Snidal (2009) The Governance Triangle: Regulatory Standards Institutions in the Shadow of the State, in Walter Mattli & Ngaire Woods eds The politics of global regulation (Princeton University Press) Bernstein, S. & B. Cashore (2007) Can non-state global governance be legitimate? An analytical framework. Regulation and Governance 1, 1-25. Bingen, Jim & Lawrence Busch (eds) (2006) Agricultural Standards. The Shape of the Global Food and Fiber System (Springer Netherlands) Black, Julia. 2002. Critical reflections on regulation. London: CARR Discussion Paper Series Black, Julia (2008) Constructing and contesting legitimacy and accountability in polycentric regulatory regimes, Regulation & governance 2008 (doi:10.1111/j.1748-5991.2008.00034.x) Bush, Simon R. & Peter Oosterveer (2007) The Missing Link: Intersecting Governance and Trade in de Space of Place and the Space of Flows. Sociologica Ruralis 47/4 p 384-399 Doris Fuchs, Agni Kalfagianni and Tetty Havinga, Actors in Private Food Governance: The Legitimacy of Retail Standards and Multistakeholder Initiatives with Civil Society Participation., Agriculture and Human Values 2010 (Online from August 2009: Agric Hum Values DOI 10.1007/s10460-009-9236-3) Fulponi, Linda. 2006. Private voluntary standards in the food system: The perspective of major food retailers in OECD countries. Food Policy 31: 1-13.Harrison 1997, Havinga, Tetty. 2006. Private regulation of food safety by Supermarkets. Law and policy 28(4): 515-533. Henson,S. and Julie Caswell, Food safety regulation: an overview of contemporary issues, Food policy Volume 24, Issue 6, (December 1999), Pages 589-603 Henson, Spencer and Thoms Reardon (2005) Private Agri-food Standards: Implications for Food Policy and Agri-food Systems, Food policy Volume 30, Issue 3, Pages 241-253 Josling, Tim, Donna Roberts & David Orden (2004) Food Regulation and Trade. Towards a Safe and Open Global System. Washington DC: Institute for International Economics 14

Levi-Faur, David (2010) Regulation & Regulatory Governance, Jerusalem Papers in Regulation & Governance 1 (regulation.huji.ac.il) Marsden, Terry, Andrew Flynn & Michelle Harrison (2000) Consuming Interests. The Social Provision of Foods. London: UCL Press. Marsden, T., A. Flynn & M. Harrison (2010) The New Regulation and Governance of Food. Beyond the Food Crisis? New York/London: Routledge. Marian Garcia Martinez, Andrew Fearne, Julie A. Caswell, Spencer Henson (2007), Coregulation as a possible model for food safety governance: Opportunities for public-private partnerships. Food Policy 32 (2007) 299-314 Walter Mattli & Ngaire Woods (2009) eds The politics of global regulation (Princeton University Press) Oosterveer, Peter. 2005. Global Food Governance. Wageningen: Wageningen University. Picciotto, S., Introduction: Reconceptualizing regulation in the era of globalization, Journal of Law and Society 29 (2002) 1, 1-11. ROTHSTEIN, HENRY (2005) Escaping the Regulatory Net: Why Regulatory Reform Can Fail Consumers. Law & Policy Volume 27, Issue 4, Page 520-548 Scott, C., 2002 Private Regulation of the Public Sector: A neglected facet of contemporary governance, in: Journal of Law and Society 29 (2002) 1, 56-76. Spruyt, Hendrik (2001) The supply and demand of governance in standard-setting: insights from the past, Journal of European Public Policy 8 (2001) 3, 371-391. Stewart, Daniel (2010) paper dublin Van der Kloet, Jaap & Tetty Havinga, Private regulation of food safety from a regulatee s perspective, Paper for the International Workshop on Globalization, Global Governance and Private Standards, 4-5 November 2008, Leuven, Belgium Van Waarden, Frans (2006) Taste, tradition, transactions, and Trust: The public and private regulation of food, In: Ansell, Christopher & David Vogel (eds), What's the beef? The contested governance of European Food Safety, Cambridge MA: MIT Press, 2006. p.35-59. Van Waarden, Frans (2010) Governing global commons: Public-private-protection of fish and forests. J. Swinnen, J. Wouters, M. Maertens en A. Marx (eds) Private standards and global governance. Legal and economic perspectives. Cheltenham: Edgar Elgar 2010 15