Special Interests and the Trade Policy in the BRICs *

Similar documents
An Empirical Investigation into the Determinants of Trade Policy Bias

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES LOBBYING COMPETITION OVER TRADE POLICY. Kishore Gawande Pravin Krishna Marcelo Olarreaga

New Year, New President, New Trade Agenda? John Murphy U.S. Chamber of Commerce

International Trade Lecture 25: Trade Policy Empirics (I)

Oral History Program Series: Civil Service Interview no.: O5

Preview. Chapter 9. The Cases for Free Trade. The Cases for Free Trade (cont.) The Political Economy of Trade Policy

The Political Economy of Trade Policy

The Political Economy of Trade Policy. Empirical Approaches

Andrew L. Stoler 1 Executive Director Institute for International Business, Economics and Law // //

CHINA IN THE WORLD PODCAST. Host: Paul Haenle Guest: Claire Reade

Love of Variety and Immigration

International Trade Revised: November 8, 2012 Latest version available at

Arndt-Corden Department of Economics Public Lecture. Australian National University, Canberra, 23 May 2017

AP GOPO CHAPTER 9 READING GUIDE

APPRAISAL OF THE FAR EAST AND LATIN AMERICAN TEAM REPORTS IN THE WORLD FOREIGN TRADE SETTING

Lecture 7: Domestic Politics of Trade. Benjamin Graham

Prospects and Challenges for the Doha Round

Union of Concerned of Concerned Scientists Press Conference on the North Korean Missile Crisis. April 20, 2017

International Business 7e

Trump and the Xenophobic Populist Parties: Cultural Backlash in Artificial Intelligence Society

Each Senate District is made up of three Assembly (Representatives) Districts.

Exam 1, Section 1 EC 302 Intermediate Macroeconomics Prof. Michael McElroy Spring 2018

Corruption and Political Competition

Political Economics II Spring Lectures 4-5 Part II Partisan Politics and Political Agency. Torsten Persson, IIES

PREPARED REMARKS FOR COMMERCE SECRETARY GARY LOCKE Asia Society and Woodrow Wilson Center event on Chinese FDI Washington, DC Wednesday, May 4, 2011

Marc Lee Economist Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives -- BC Office CANADA-U.S. CUSTOMS UNION: A CRITICAL ASSESSMENT

A General Overview of the Political Economy of Trade

Corruption : The Main Problem in the Administration of India

Book Discussion: Worlds Apart

Resistance to Women s Political Leadership: Problems and Advocated Solutions

PS 124A Midterm, Fall 2013

Challenges to Global Governance Joel Hellman Global Futures Lecture, Gaston Hall, September 9, 2015

Final exam: Political Economy of Development. Question 2:

What are term limits and why were they started?

EXPERT INTERVIEW Issue #2

Capture and Governance at Local and National Levels

Introduction to the declination function for gerrymanders

ECONOMICS U$A PROGRAM #27 INTERNATIONAL TRADE: FOR WHOSE BENEFIT?

India: Gains of Economic Reforms

Common Good: An interview with Lord Stephen Green, UK Minister for Trade and Investment. Complimentary article reprint.

Is China a Currency Manipulator?

INTERNATIONAL ANNUAL CONFERENCE ON INTEGRITY - CAII 2018

The Gravity Model on EU Countries An Econometric Approach

Indonesia: Middle Income Country in Transition

PLS 103 Lecture 3 1. Today we talk about the Missouri legislature. What we re doing in this section we

Container Cast 44, Creating Border Environment 2014

Terence Wood

BBC Learning English Talk about English First Sight, Second Thoughts Part 5 'Working Life'

From The Collected Works of Milton Friedman, compiled and edited by Robert Leeson and Charles G. Palm.

Congressional Forecast. Brian Clifton, Michael Milazzo. The problem we are addressing is how the American public is not properly informed about

My company was founded by Paul Revere in We believe we are the oldest basic manufacturing company in the USA. Today, we ship copper and brass

2018 State Legislative Elections: Will History Prevail? Sept. 27, 2018 OAS Episode 44

THE ANDREW MARR SHOW INTERVIEW: NICOLA STURGEON, MSP FIRST MINISTER, SCOTLAND JANUARY 25 th 2015

SHANKER SINGHAM, DIRECTOR OF INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND COMPETITION, IEA

EFFECTIVELY RECOVERING ATTORNEY S FEES

THE WOODROW WILSON SCHOOL OF PUBLIC AND INTERNATIONAL AFFAIRS AND THE BOBST CENTER FOR PEACE AND JUSTICE

What has changed about the global economic structure

Political Economy. Pierre Boyer and Alessandro Riboni. École Polytechnique - CREST

DR LIAM FOX ANDREW MARR SHOW 18 TH DECEMBER, 2016

Speech by President Barroso: "A new era of good feelings"

Chapter Six. The Political Economy of International Trade. Opening Case. Opening Case

Putting development back in the WTO

In this unit we are going to speak about globalization.

CHINA IN THE WORLD PODCAST. Host: Paul Haenle Guest: Erik Brattberg. March 13, 2018

The End of Textiles Quotas: A case study of the impact on Bangladesh

Welcome to the dark side of rationality.

PS 0500: Leader(s) Matter(s) William Spaniel

The State of Central Asia

University of Miami Law Review

State Policies toward Migration and Development. Dilip Ratha

REMARKS BY AMBASSADOR SUSAN SCHWAB THE UNITED STATES TRADE REPRESENTATIVE

Benefits and costs of free trade for less developed countries

In Defense of Majoritarianism

How Dictators Forestall Democratization Using International Trade Policy 1

INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS, FINANCE AND TRADE Vol. II - Strategic Interaction, Trade Policy, and National Welfare - Bharati Basu

Competitiveness: A Blessing or a Curse for Gender Equality? Yana van der Muelen Rodgers

CHRISTIAN POLITICAL ORGANIZATIONS

NEW PERSPECTIVES ON THE LAW & ECONOMICS OF ELECTIONS

CARLETON ECONOMIC PAPERS

3. Which region had not yet industrialized in any significant way by the end of the nineteenth century? a. b) Japan Incorrect. The answer is c. By c.

Econ 554: Political Economy, Institutions and Business: Solution to Final Exam

Globalization and Industry Support for Immigration

ANDREW MARR SHOW 4 TH MARCH 2018 SIMON COVENEY

Interview with Philippe Kirsch, President of the International Criminal Court *

COMMUNICATIONS H TOOLKIT H NATIONAL VOTER REGISTRATION DAY. A Partner Communications Toolkit for Traditional and Social Media

USAPC Washington Report Interview with Ambassador Carla Hills May 2007

Californians. healthy communities. ppic statewide survey FEBRUARY in collaboration with The California Endowment CONTENTS

ALTERNATIVES TO ADJUDICATION. Toby Randle. 9 May 2005 THE SAVOY HOTEL, LONDON

THE COFFEES OF THE SECRETARY-GENERAL JAMES K. GALBRAITH

COMMERCIAL INTERESTS, POLITICAL INFLUENCE, AND THE ARMS TRADE

PODCAST: Politically Powerless, Economically Powerful: A Contradiction?: A Conversation with the Saudi Businesswoman Rasha Hifzi

GARRY PURSELL CURRICULUM VITAE (13 February 2010)

Musinamy Gopinath and Hanho Kim, (eds.) Globalization and the Rural-Urban Divide: Seoul National University Press (2009)

GRAVITY EQUATIONS IN INTERNATIONAL TRADE. based on Chapter 5 of Advanced international trade: theory and evidence by R. C. Feenstra (2004, PUP)

PREFACE. 1. Objectives and Structure of this Report

Introduction to the WTO. Will Martin World Bank 10 May 2006

I. Chapter Overview. Roots of Public Opinion Research. A. Learning Objectives

Trade, Growth and Poverty in the context of Lao PDR

October 2006 APB Globalization: Benefits and Costs

Speech to SOLACE National Elections Conference 16 January 2014 Peter Wardle

Transcription:

Special Interests and the Trade Policy in the BRICs * Kishore S. Gawande # My co-author, Bernard Hoekman at the World Bank, and I are trying to push the Grossman-Helpman model as far as possible. 1 Basically, this is a very data-oriented paper. What we want to show, let s say, what we want to focus on, are the emerging BRICs (Brazil, Russia, India, China and South Africa). We want to see whether these countries are welfare oriented as well as the extent of their welfare orientedness, and then review some unanswered questions, which are the really interesting ones. We see some of the issues and some of the problems and we re giving some very realistic estimates, but these estimates raise more questions than answers, and I want to take you through our view, showing you how we re trying to answer these questions. So, are BRICs welfare maximizers? That s the first big question that we want to answer. This is an important question because these are countries that are transitioning in several ways. Their political institutions are not those of liberal democracies, as we know the term from using it to describe the United States and Western Europe, and their institutions are young, emerging, so this is a very important question. Also, I want to show you that the welfare mindedness of these countries is not fixed at a point in time; that they actually vary over time, so all these things about them being young democracies and new institutions coming up all play into that very issue, and will be important for the next step that we want to take. This next step is very open-ended, so I welcome everybody in this room to try to solve some of the patterns we see in the data. About the literature on this subject, the most important thing to keep in mind is that it s very different when talking about manufacturing and when talking about agriculture. Because it s so distinct and the concerning issues are very different, we choose for a completely different approach for both industries and we are going to do a separate analysis of them. For example, I m from India, where the population is very price-sensitive regarding agriculture products (for example onions), and the median voter spends a lot of their money on food; so, when food prices goes up, the government gets voted out. For this reason, these countries really take care of their median voter. They need to, otherwise they re finished. But again, when analyzing the economies we have to take into account that agriculture and manufacturing have two completely separate * Extracto de la sesión de comercio internacional organizada conjuntamente por la Universidad de Montevideo, la Universidad de la República, y el Banco Central del Uruguay, en el marco de las XXV Jornadas Anuales de Economía del Banco Central del Uruguay, 25 de Octubre de 2010. # Professor and Roy and Helen Ryu Chair of Economics and Government, Bush School of Government and Public Service, Texas A&M University. 1. Note from the editor: Grossman, G. and Helpman, E. (1994), Protection for Sale, American Economic Review, 84(4), 833-850. 13

Special Interests and the Trade Policy in the BRICs literatures and we should respect that. So, let me tell you the negative aspect of the Grossman-Helpman model: it s not good at explaining things like the ones I just explained. For example, why do governments of industrializing countries, like Brazil, maybe India, want to keep food prices down at all costs, and therefore, tax exports? You don t see export taxes in manufacturing, not even in developing countries, except maybe for some resource goods, but generally not in manufacturing. As far as imports of agriculture are concerned, there are imports subsidies that follow the same kind of logic, but you won t see them in manufacturing. The Grossman-Helpman model is no good at trying to explain those things. Actually, it has an explanation which is extremely weak. That s what I see as a negative aspect of the Grossman- Helpman model: it s a special interest model, so obviously it s not going to explain things that are motivated by citizen concerns. The idea behind the Grossman-Helpman model is a 94 paper, called Protection for Sale. It s a nice paper, and if you forget about the money option, it s a very simple paper, very intuitive; a bargaining model basically. It emphasizes the influence that special interests have on trade policy and, although it s specific to trade policies, you can generalize it to other policies. So, the big question when you re applying this model to BRIC countries is whether it applies to China or whether it applies to Russia, and what kind of special interest behaviors exists in these countries. If you re really a scholar on China or Russia, you will hear that the nature of lobbying is different from that in Western democracies, but for sure there s more and more literature coming out that says that there is a lot of lobbying going on in these countries. China and Russia have their own grassroots kind of organizations for lobbying, and they re very, very effective. So, in China, much of the lobbying happens at the provincial level. Very briefly speaking, the federal government, or the central government, leaves the provinces alone if the provincial governments don t mess around with their politics. Let me clarify that I m not a China scholar, I m just making these observations after having talked to people and read about it in the literature: at the provincial level there is a lot of lobbying going on because the provincial leaders and the governors of provinces have tremendous amount of economic power and they are the ones who actually interact with the central government. The Grossman-Helpman model is about money changing hands as much as another kind of lobbying, and we can suppose that there s also money changing hands in this non-democracies, so we claim that the model can be applied to this economies, which is unfamiliar terrain for the Grossman-Helpman model. The whole point of this paper is to come up with estimates of this model for agriculture and manufacturing, trying to keeping it simple, using it to shed light on the welfare of citizens at large. The more the government is not welfare oriented, then the a parameter in the government s objective function of the Grossman-Helpman s model is going to be lower, and the lobbies are really going to love it. In some countries it is very cheap to achieve that. The main equation of the econometric model includes: (i) a measure of protection such as the tariff, (ii) the import penetration ratio (imports over output), (iii) the absolute elasticity (if it s imports, it s absolute import elasticity and if it s exports, it s absolute export elasticity), and finally the degree of welfare mindedness of the government (parameter a ). Tariffs (and so protection) will be higher in a particular industry, the less the government is welfare oriented (the lower the parameter a is), the lower its import elasticity, and the lower the import penetration ratio of the industry. For manufacturing, we can also include the pressure that downstream users of goods place on the government. For example, automobile producers will place pressure on the US government to have low tariffs on steel, because steel is an input for this industry. Then we have the same model in agriculture, but a separate data set for agricultural goods. There s this fantastic data set by Kym Anderson at the time he was at the [World] Bank for a couple of years 14

Kishore S. Gawande working in this project. His book has just come out, so we are using pretty state-of-the-art data most of the barriers in the agricultural data are older measures; there are no subsidies, nor domestic price measures or domestic output restriction measures; these are mostly border measures. On the other hand, our manufacturing data is from Nicita and Olarreaga. This database has probably been the most cited of Marcelo [Olarreaga] s papers. It s a very famous database, a major service that Marcelo has done. We are also using I/O tables, which have about 55 countries, but I m just going to show you the BRIC countries. Finally, for agriculture we used an Anderson et. al.. database, and I really encourage you, if you re working in the agricultural area, to use it. This database contains very good data on Uruguay, or at least that s what Kym Anderson thinks. You might want to change his mind about that. I m not going to go any further with the model, so I m going right to the results file. I m going to show you about 4 or 5 graphs of my first set of results, that s all we have time for, but if anybody wants this presentation I can send it to you, no problem. This graph shows data from China, India, Brazil, and South Africa. My Uruguay graph is missing, and that s entirely my fault because Uruguay graphs are very interesting, especially on the agricultural side. Figure 1: Parameter a (degree of welfare mindedness) from Grossman-Helpman model in Manufacturing Note: BRA=Brazil; CHN=China; IND=India; ZAF=South Africa. Source: ISIC level tariffs, 1988-2001, World Bank Trade and Production database (Nicita and Olarreaga, 2004). For Brazil, each data point is an a measure of the year, so each year is a cross section on Brazil in manufacturing, that I used for my estimations. And you can see some variation, but the database goes on for 2004, so it s possible to find even higher values for a. Still, 50, 40, 30 this is quite prone to special interests. If you apply the Grossman-Helpman model to China blindly, then you would say that Chinese policy-makers actually sell off their representative consumer interest for fairly cheap. Nevertheless, it s still not that cheap, their number it s about 10, and always between 5 and 10. If you go to India, it s about 10, and sometimes around 7, or 9, and that s after 1990. If you look at the data before the Indian liberalization in 1990, it s less than 1. So this is saying that liberalization is good for consumer welfare. And then South Africa has liberalized after 1993 - there s a couple excellent papers on South Africa, I have some recommendations if you re interested in that countryand it has stabilized around 30 or 35, but that s without taking into consideration the lobbying by intermediates, as I ve mentioned before. 15

Special Interests and the Trade Policy in the BRICs Figure 2: Parameter a (degree of welfare mindedness) from intermediates lobbying model in Manufacturing Note: BRA=Brazil; CHN=China; IND=India; ZAF=South Africa. Source: ISIC level tariffs, 1988-2001, World Bank Trade and Production database (Nicita and Olarreaga, 2004). But if you take into consideration the intermediates, you can see that there s lobbying by all sectors throughout the economy and some final good sectors too. Comparing the results with the Grossman-Helpman model, the estimation of the parameter a has dramatically declined. For example, if you look at China the number is around 5; for India is about 3 or 4, and South Africa is most of the time around 20, but it s still much lower than that. As you can see, it depends on what you want to believe; I ll go with these numbers, that s my preferred estimate of what the a s for the BRIC countries are. So, one of the things that you might want to ask is why is there this kind of variation? What happened that there was this variation? There s not that much variation for India; there s liberalization and that s it. So India would go like this: it would go up, but then stabilizes. Different countries have different experiences, and that s a question: why is that there is much variation? Now, let me go through the estimations for agriculture. This sector is very interesting and for agriculture we also have data from Russia, though imports only. We ve got imports and exports data for the other countries, and there is no negative protection; so there s no export taxes and no import subsidies, because this model can t handle that. So this is one possible extension for the future; to me, that s the big gap in this literature. It s how do we answer questions like that. For example, as you can see in the graphs, one way of looking at Brazil is that it really protects its agriculture, or you can say that it sells out its consumer interest for pretty cheap. I found this very interesting because that s not India s experience. 16

Kishore S. Gawande Figure 3: Parameter a (degree of welfare mindedness) from Nominal Rates of Assistance (NRAs) in Agriculture Imports Note: rsa=south Africa. Source: Anderson, K., M. Kurzweil, W. Martin, D. Sandri and E. Valenzuela (2008), Measuring Distortions to Agricultural Incentives, Revisited, World Trade Review 7(4): 1-30. In this sense, India is much more welfare oriented and it doesn t protect agriculture as much as Brazil does, so the NRA in agriculture is not a nominal rate of assistance in agriculture, but is a broader measure. Notice also that the a s from agriculture are pretty high for India. So India can be seen as a welfare maximizing government, as far as agriculture policy is concerned. On the other hand, Brazil, China, and Russia cannot be seen as welfare maximizers. Uruguay is very welfare oriented, but not in all goods, so if you did this for some goods, it s very surprising in this data that it would be about 5. So it s not like 100 or 20 or 30, but it s about 5, and there is variation over time; so I wish I had that graph to show you. It s a very interesting graph. Finally, we can see that South Africa has become over time very susceptible to lobbying interests. So, as countries become richer, they become more susceptible to lobbying interests. For example, if I d put a USA graph over here, we could see that it s very susceptible to lobbying interests in agriculture comparing to what happens in manufacturing. The reason is that the average American consumer doesn t spend too much money on food, right? So they have no electoral issues with these things. They protect their sugar, their corn; they protect cheese, dairy products, and they re not particularly good in these industries, but they can protect them without any danger to their electoral chances. A very similar thing is happening in South Africa, which is becoming richer, but it has the particular feature that its median voter isn t, so it would be interesting to keep a close eye in what s happening there. If you take a look at exports -and again, this is only exports subsidization, there is no exports taxation data here- you can t explain this phenomenon. Again, India doesn t subsidize exports and it s pretty welfare oriented, or so it seems. Instead, Brazil, South Africa, and Russia do subsidize their exports to a large extent, so we can say that these three countries are very prone to satisfying the interests of the exports lobbies. At least, that s what the numbers show, and they re fairly constant over time. 17

Special Interests and the Trade Policy in the BRICs Figure 4: Parameter a (degree of welfare mindedness) from Nominal Rates of Assistance (NRAs) in Agriculture Exports Note: rsa=south Africa. Source: Anderson, K., M. Kurzweil, W. Martin, D. Sandri and E. Valenzuela (2008), Measuring Distortions to Agricultural Incentives, Revisited, World Trade Review 7(4): 1-30. I d like to make one final remark about the relationship between the changes we can observe in the estimations of the a s parameters and the political regime. It would be interesting to analyze not only the BRIC countries, but also it would be interesting to analyze all Mercosur and all the South-East Asian countries, countries that are remarkable. What s common in these countries is that they re not fully established liberal democracies with contract mitigating institutions. They are not like the US and Western Europe, which have different institutions, and you can tell what s going on these days in those countries. Apart from the French experience, you won t see too many demonstrations in the streets, but I think that s rather a cultural issue, I mean, going to a demonstration is no big deal, right? But the fact is that those kind of things had happened, let s say, in India, and then the government would be out easily. So these not fledgling but emerging democracies, not necessarily emerging democracies but emerging countries in their political institutions, in their economic institutions, don t have all the answers to conflicts, and when they don t have all the answers, the politicians go for policies that try to maximize their electoral chances or to repress. Well, the worst or more extreme scenario would be the Chinese one. Figure 5: Empirical Distribution of Parameter a (degree of welfare mindedness), Imports-Exports, distinguishing between Democracy and Non-Democracy 18 Note: Democracies: Brazil, India, South Africa. Non-democracies: China, Russia. Source: Anderson, K., M. Kurzweil, W. Martin, D. Sandri and E. Valenzuela (2008), Measuring Distortions to Agricultural Incentives, Revisited, World Trade Review 7(4): 1-30. 2. Note from the editor: Grossman, G. and Helpman, E. (1996) Electoral Competition and Special Interest Politics, Review of Economic Studies, 63:265-286.

Kishore S. Gawande The figure [Figure 5] basically shows that democracies and non-democracies have same distributions of a s. So the question that really interests me is about institutions as delivering policy outcomes. One way to see it, is starting from the fact that politicians in all these countries are alike. I mean, you know, apart from their looks that are different, they all do what the institutions let them do. In other words, if in the United States the institutions were as fragile as in India, American politicians would behave like Indian politicians. What I m trying to say is that they invest a lot of resources on campaigns for the elections, which I m sure it s really important at the end, but ultimately what ties down the politicians are the institutions, and that s just it. Then, later on, the politicians behave like they have the power to influence, and they will or will not respond according to the current institutions, which may or may not constrain their power to do things, and depending on that constraint, good or bad things can take place. So we re trying to go beyond the Grossman-Helpman model, but the only other answer that I ve seen, really theoretically cleanly, is another Grossman-Helpman paper, a 1996 paper about democratic institutions. 4 Basically, it says that inside a legislature there s legislative bargaining, there s electoral competition. The political science literature has done some very good work, but still very seminal; it s not developed very well and there s still unresolved issues. As a matter of fact, the solution of a legislature problem with bargaining inside the legislature is a very hard problem. So, political scientists have given answers like Ok, we put an agenda setter and that solves the problem. I think it s artificial, but it solves that old issue that people have spent 20 years trying to solve. There s a whole electoral competition literature which emphasizes that if you want to get lobbying into the picture, then lobbying money has to help solve the electoral incentives issue, and therefore you need that some part of the population has to be not informed; so throwing ads at them will change their minds. You spend money on ads, you spend money on them, and they ll work according to this money, and that s the uninformed voting literature. The Grossman-Helpman paper in the Review of Economic Studies is an uninformed voting paper, and there are very interesting empirical implications of this paper. For example, out of it you can actually connect institutions, like majoritarian voting systems, parliamentary voting systems, parliamentary voting, presidential voting systems, and map it to the amount of protection. So, we want to take this BRIC data and just try to see what we can come up with, because uninformed voting is very prevalent in these non-liberal democracies. And I m sure uninformed voting is also predominant in the United States. So, you know, it s probably relevant elsewhere too, but I think that s the more fun step for us. Thank you very much! 19