Good and bad GDP: Output fall in transition economies and the dead rat effect By Vladimir Popov - April 13, 2018

Similar documents
A2 Economics. Standard of Living and Economic Progress. tutor2u Supporting Teachers: Inspiring Students. Economics Revision Focus: 2004

A Putin policy without Putin after 2008? Putin s legacy: achievements

4.2 explain indicators that can be used to measure quality of life. 4.3 explain how innovations and ideas in the past influenced quality of life

COUNTRY REPORT. by Andrei V. Sonin 1 st Secretary, Ministry of Foreign Affairs

HOLT CHAPTER 22. Section 1: Capitalism Section 2: Socialism Section 3: Communism HOLT, RINEHART AND WINSTON

Arms Control in the Context of Current US-Russian Relations

World Bank Releases World Development Indicators Seeking Alpha

The Wealth of Nations and Economic Growth PRINCIPLES OF ECONOMICS (ECON 210) BEN VAN KAMMEN, PHD

Has Globalization Helped or Hindered Economic Development? (EA)

African Economic Development, IIB. Economic and Human Development: Concepts and Measurement

Potential Use of Well-being Indicators for Community Development in Japan

Globalization: It Doesn t Just Happen

Explanations of Slow Growth in Productivity and Real Wages

Chapter 1 Introduction

The Threat Continues. Medicaid, the Budget, and Deficit Reduction: The Bottom Line: Our Message on Medicaid and the Super Committee Process

2. The State Department asked the American Embassy in Moscow to explain Soviet behavior.

Lecture 2: The Capitalist Revolution

Test Bank for Economic Development. 12th Edition by Todaro and Smith

Political Economy of. Post-Communism

Overview: The World Community from

HOW ECONOMIES GROW AND DEVELOP Macroeconomics In Context (Goodwin, et al.)

Chapter 1 The Cold War Era Political Science Class 12

Testimony before Senate Budget Subcommittee 4 on Implementation of the Federal Real ID Act of 2005

Problems Involved in Improving the Quality of Life in Albania in the Years

Recognizing the problem/agenda setting: ormulating the policy: Adopting the policy: Implementing the policy: Evaluating the policy: ECONOMIC POLICY

The Brookings Institution Dollar and Sense Ernesto Zedillo on globalization, NAFTA and the wall March 15, 2019

The Three Great Thinkers Who Changed Economics

Was Ronald Reagan s Vice-President for eight years Pledged to continue much of Reagan s economic, domestic, and foreign policy commitments Famous

NON-OBSERVED ECONOMY IN NATIONAL ACCOUNTS

(Re)creating a market economy: the case of the Czech Republic

I Have Rights?! Name: Rights Activity p.1


IMPACT OF GLOBALIZATION ON POVERTY: CASE STUDY OF PAKISTAN

MAPS. Environmental Issues. Economics Government History Pictures

Fewer, but still with us

The End of Bipolarity

1. Define GDP. The market value of all final goods and services produced within a nation in a given time period

The Truman Doctrine: Preventing the Spread of Communism. Andy Ziemer. Historical Paper. Junior Division. Word Count: 2095

CHAPTER 12: The Problem of Global Inequality

Introduction to the Cold War

WILPF RESOLUTIONS. 18th Congress New Delhi, India 28 December January 1971

Full file at

Trade led Growth in Times of Crisis Asia Pacific Trade Economists Conference 2 3 November 2009, Bangkok. Session 10

Since the Vietnam War ended in 1975, the

WHY THE CONFLICT IN UKRAINE IS A REAL WAR, AND HOW IT RELATES TO INTERNATIONAL LAW.

Revising NATO s nuclear deterrence posture: prospects for change

UNDERSTANDING TRADE, DEVELOPMENT, AND POVERTY REDUCTION

The impact of political instability on economic growth (Case of Albania)

Social Dimension S o ci al D im en si o n 141

International Trade Union Confederation Statement to UNCTAD XIII

Planning Activity. Theme 1

Statement by. Ms. Fekitamoeloa Katoa Utoikamanu

CIVIL SOCIETY VERSUS POLITICAL SOCIETY

SCARCITY, CHOICE AND THE ALLOCATION OF RESOURCES

The True GDP and Foreign Debt of Cuba

Other End Use Market Segment Outlook Rubber Gloves

Our World: Paradoxes, Problems and the Need to Change. José Narro Robles Rector of UNAM Woodrow Wilson Center Washington, USA June 2012

The Jus Semper Global Alliance Living Wages North and South

ECONOMIC SYSTEMS AND DECISION MAKING. Understanding Economics - Chapter 2

Why is the United States So Tough on Russia? The Answer May Be in Lenin s Brochure of 1920

UNIT 10 The Russian Revolution (1917)

Adam Smith, The Wealth of Nations, 1776 The Flow of Money and Goods in a Market Economy

Burning Coal in Tangshan Energy Resources as Commons

Advanced Citizenship Interview Based on the USCIS N-400

THE ANTI-FEDERALIST MOVEMENT

Luiz Augusto de CASTRO NEVES Ambassador of Brazil

What is Public Opinion?

The Industrial Revolution Beginnings. Ways of the World Strayer Chapter 18

Aftermath of WWII: The Iron Curtain/Cold War

Towards disarmament: Spreading weapons spreading violence

Final exam: Political Economy of Development. Question 2:

"Food Aid: Are we Reaching the Hungry?"

HSX: GROWTH OF GLOBAL MIDDLE CLASS

Weapons of Mass Deception. Part One

Our objective is to evaluate the U.S. Policy of containment in response to the causes and effects of the Korean and Vietnam Wars.

Big Data and Super-Computers: foundations of Cyber Communism

The Nazi Retreat from the East

Chapter 14--Mr. Bargen

HUMAN ECONOMIC SECURITY

President Reagan ran as a conservative alternative to President Carter. Reagan, a former actor, had previously served as the governor of California.

Name: Class: Date: Contemporary Global Issues: Reading Essentials and Study Guide: Lesson 2

Testimony to the United States Senate Budget Committee Hearing on Opportunity, Mobility, and Inequality in Today's Economy April 1, 2014

Lecture 2: Capitalism

Chapter 2: The U.S. Economy: A Global View

September 11, 1964 Letter from the Korean Workers Party Central Committee to the Central Committee of the CPSU

The Three Great Thinkers Who Changed Economics

Macro CH 21 sample questions

How s Life in the United States?

Transition: Changes after Socialism (25 Years Transition from Socialism to a Market Economy)

BELARUS ETF COUNTRY PLAN Socioeconomic background

Strategic Intelligence Analysis Spring Russia: Reasserting Power in Regions of the Former Soviet Union

A Regional Manufacturing Platform

The Economic Impact of Oaklawn Hospital on the Marshall Area

OCR Geography A-level. Human Rights. PMT Education. Written by Jeevan Singh. PMT Education

ANDREW MARR SHOW APRIL 9 TH 2017 PRITI PATEL

How s Life in New Zealand?

Human Development Indices and Indicators: 2018 Statistical Update. Eritrea

AN IMPOSSIBLE TRINITY?: RESOURCES, SPACE AND PEOPLE

CHAPTER 20 NATIONAL SECURITY POLICYMAKING CHAPTER OUTLINE

DEMOGRAPHIC SHOCKS: THE VIEW FROM HISTORY. DISCUSSION

Transcription:

Good and bad GDP: Output fall in transition economies and the dead rat effect By Vladimir Popov - April 13, 2018 The Worker and Kolkhoz Woman, Moscow. Photo credit: Bigstock, filin72, Good jokes should be funny, but more importantly, should carry a message. The following is one of the most famous jokes in economics, and helps to comprehend the important economic controversy over GDP: Two economic professors one seasoned, another young had exhausted all topics for conversation while walking over a deserted road. The older

one sees a dead rat on the road and makes an offer to his young colleague: if you eat it, he says, I ll pay you $10,000. The younger professor makes a quick cost-benefit analysis, figures that he is better off with $10,000 than without and eats the rat. As they walk further, the young professor suffers from the bad aftertaste and wants his senior colleague to experience the same. When he sees another dead rat on the road, he dares his older colleague to eat it, promising to pay him back the $10,000. The senior professor decides to get his back money and eats the rat. After several more hours of walking in silence and experiencing the bad aftertaste, the younger professor finally speaks his mind: Well, it looks like we were eating dead rats for free! The older professor replies, yes, my young colleague, but do not forget that the GDP increased by $20,000 dollars. So, did the GDP really increase? Some would say that this example fits the definition of GDP precisely new goods and services produced and sold on the market. In this case a rat-eating performance for the benefit of the viewer. If taxes were paid from these two transactions, it is an increase in official GDP, if not an increase in output of the shadow economy (unofficial GDP). Others would say that it is foolish to include these types of transactions into the calculation of GDP. Do not rush to conclusions, though. Consider the real debates that are going on today. In the recent Report of the Club of Rome (2017) the authors point out the paradoxical cases : GDP increase due to oil spills because there is spending associated with the clean up, GDP increase due

to diseases, disasters, and accidents, even though these events evidently reduce the welfare of the populous. About two decades ago this argument was applied to the case of the transformational recession : a deep and protracted decline in output that occurred in the 1990s during the transition from a centrally planned economy to market economy in former communist countries. This decline was unprecedented in peacetime history; the recession lasted for several years and output fell by more than 50% in some countries. The popular explanation at a time was that there was a reduction of redundant output, such as tanks or statues of Lenin, which did not affect the real welfare. If this redundant output is excluded from GDP, there was no decline at all. Åslund (2001) argued that the actual decline in output has been much smaller than perceived. Socialism, he wrote, was a system of waste. Soviet production usually needed three times more inputs than a Western factory since costs were irrelevant to managers. Some of these losses represented inefficiency, others theft The investment that was sheer waste should preferably be deducted from GDP. He also claimed that the fall in output during the transformational recession was a myth in part due to the unusually high share of defense spending in many socialist countries (about 15% to 17% of GDP in the USSR in the 1980s) and the reduction of this share afterwards. After the transition period this share fell to an internationally normal level of about 3 percent of GDP. So, he suggested to deduct 10% of GDP from the

statistically recorded output loss during the transformational recession (Åslund 2001, p. 11). Gaddy and Ickes (2001) insisted that we need to know whether measured GDP is accurately reflecting true value produced in the economy and that value added can rise in the economy even as domestic consumption, investment, and standards of living appear to decline. They also made an argument that a fall in output caused by a reduction of defense expenditure is in fact a welfare gain: This is an output fall, but welfare is certainly higher with lower defense production given that the CPSU [Communist Party of the Soviet Union] is no longer the measure of value. Today GDP as a measure of economic and social progress is criticised by virtually everyone on many grounds: it does not take into account other dimensions of development (education, health, crime, inequality, human rights, etc.), it does not capture the depletion of resources and damage to the environment that needs to be compensated to ensure sustainable development. This criticism is often constructive and leads to the development of other indicators of economic and social progress that are increasingly accepted in research and the statistical practices of national governments and international organisations. Examples include the Human Development Index, computed since 1990 by UNDP, and the Genuine Progress Indicator developed by researchers and certain national and regional governments. But the attempts to exclude some economic activities from a country s GDP are counterproductive. Unfortunately, we cannot agree on what type

of economic activity is good for welfare and what type is bad. Statues of Lenin that were produced in the former Soviet Union are regarded as value subtraction by some, but as value added by others. Communist memorabilia and weapons designed and produced during the Soviet period turned out to be among the few internationally competitive goods of new independent states and clearly have market value. If we start to exclude particular economic activities when calculating GDP, it would be impossible to determine the criteria for what to include or exclude. Defence spending was always counted as part of GDP, no matter whether the country was an aggressor or a victim. The share of defence expenditure included the GDP of the US was 40% in 1945 (World War II), 15% in 1953 (Korean War) and 10% in 1968 (Vietnam War). Shall we exclude the excess over the internationally normal level of about 3 percent of GDP (Åslund 2001) from total output or shall we accept the newly recommended threshold of 2% of GDP for NATO countries? What about the slave trade that created a considerable portion of GDP in many countries? And what about the whites only or coloured signs that were still produced in the US during the segregation era just over 50 years ago, and in South Africa just 30 years ago? And the public burnings during the Inquisition, the electrical chairs and the injections of sweet death used in countries that still exercise capital punishments? Some would have a problem recognising activities of clerics and fortunetellers as value adding, others would question whether criminal activities create value in the shadow economy (even more so that drugs,

prostitution, pornography, and other similar activities are legal in some countries, but not in others). In short, it is impossible to agree on good and bad activities, so the economic definition of GDP avoids this issue by counting all activities, good and bad, as GDP creation. This approach has an important economic rationale. GDP is the measurement of production capacity, or economic potential of the country; it allows for the evaluation of the ability of a nation to produce a particular amount of goods and services. If a country produces all the bad goods, like opium and armaments, valued at $1 billion, this is quite informative. It actually tells us that with the same amount of capital, land, labour, and levels of technology, it can produce roughly the same amount of good outputs, like food and machinery. It will take some time and effort to carry out the conversion of bad production activities into good ones, and there is likely to be a transformational recession during this transition, but eventually the country will restore its previous level of output. Evaluation of GDP, no matter what goods and services a country produces, makes a lot of sense because it can tell you how the country will perform internationally. Higher GDP per capita may not bring more happiness or justice, but it leads to a greater economic competitiveness. Countries with higher GDPs per capita are more competitive in the short run and can drive other countries out of business (make them economically bankrupt). The result is that countries with greater justice and happiness (and higher life expectancy, literacy, better ecology and environment, lower crime, better use of resources, etc.) will

disappear in economic competition with the irresponsible countries that care only about GDP. To make a comparison, imagine a pedestrian crossing an intersection on a green light and being hit by a truck that passed on a red light, breaking the law. The moral and legal rights are with the pedestrian of course, but the truck driver is the one who survives the accident. If there is rule of law the truck driver is jailed. But in the international arena there is still no authority (world government) that could punish rich, but immoral countries, not to mention protecting the poor and weak, but morally superior countries from disappearing in the competitive struggle. Of course, in the 21 st century we should hope that we could limit the ruinous consequences of economic competition and ensure that the survival and development of societies and civilisations is not determined by their economic, political, and military might. But unfortunately GDP and GDP per capita do matter a great deal at the moment. References Åslund, A. (2001). The Myth of Output Collapse after Communism Post- Soviet Economies Project RUSSIAN AND EURASIAN PROGRAM Number 18 March 2001. Retrieved from: https://carnegieendowment.org/files/18aslund.pdf

Club of Rome (2017). Come On!: Capitalism, Short-termism, Population and the Destruction of the Planet. 2017. Retrieved from: https://www.clubofrome.org/2017/10/25/new-report-to-the-clubof-rome-come-on/ Gaddy, Clifford G., Barry W. Ickes (2001). HOW TO THINK ABOUT THE POST-SOVIET OUTPUT FALL. The Brookings Institution. The Pennsylvania State University, Draft: March 28, 2001. Retrieved from: http://www.personal.psu.edu/i04/camellia.pdf