Promoting Financial Stability in the Transition Economies of Central and Eastern Europe

Similar documents
Va'clav Klaus. Vdclav Klaus is the minister of finance of the Czech and Slovak Federal Republic.

Gertrude Tumpel-Gugerell: The euro benefits and challenges

COUNTRY REPORT. by Andrei V. Sonin 1 st Secretary, Ministry of Foreign Affairs

The first eleven years of Finland's EU-membership

A 13-PART COURSE IN POPULAR ECONOMICS SAMPLE COURSE OUTLINE

Chapter 21 (10) Optimum Currency Areas and the Euro

China s Response to the Global Slowdown: The Best Macro is Good Micro

THE CZECH REPUBLIC AND THE EURO. Policy paper Europeum European Policy Forum May 2002

EXPORT-ORIENTED ECONOMY - A NEW MODEL OF DEVELOPMENT FOR THE REPUBLIC OF MOLDOVA

Chapter 20. Optimum Currency Areas and the European Experience. Slides prepared by Thomas Bishop

Chapter 20. Preview. What Is the EU? Optimum Currency Areas and the European Experience

TRENDS AND PROSPECTS OF KOREAN ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT: FROM AN INTELLECTUAL POINTS OF VIEW

The economic crisis in the low income CIS: fiscal consequences and policy responses. Sudharshan Canagarajah World Bank June 2010

Is Economic Development Good for Gender Equality? Income Growth and Poverty

Latin America and the Caribbean

Since the Vietnam War ended in 1975, the

Inclusive growth and development founded on decent work for all

Chapter 7 Institutions and economics growth

Thomas Piketty Capital in the 21st Century

Venezuelan President Maduro s Sweeping Economic Policy Announcements

Republic of Estonia. Action Plan for Growth and Jobs for the implementation of the Lisbon Strategy

VENEZUELA: Oil, Inflation and Prospects for Long-Term Growth

What has changed about the global economic structure

Discovering the signs of Dutch disease in Russia Mironov, Petronevich 2013 National Research University Higher School of Economics Institute

Challenges and Opportunities for Colombia s Social Justice and Economy. Joseph E. Stiglitz Bogota February 16, 2017

The Black Sea region: Challenges and Lessons of the Global Financial Crisis

Development Strategy. for. Myanmar

Glasnost and the Intelligentsia

Issued by the PECC Standing Committee at the close of. The 13th General Meeting of the Pacific Economic Cooperation Council

Selected macro-economic indicators relating to structural changes in agricultural employment in the Slovak Republic

Erkki Liikanen: Finland, the EMU and the introduction of the euro

remain in favor of the moves made to help Mexico for three reasons.

Western Balkans Countries In Focus Of Global Economic Crisis

ASIAN CURRENCY CRISES IMPACT ON THAILAND, INDONESIA& SOUTH KOREA

Speech given by Mervyn King, Governor of the Bank of England. At Salts Mills, Bradford, Yorkshire 13 June 2005

Hungary s Economic Performance Following EU Accession: Lessons for the new EU Members Bulgaria and Romania

AFRICAN DEVELOPMENT BANK GROUP

(Re)creating a market economy: the case of the Czech Republic

Part IV Population, Labour and Urbanisation

Charles I Plosser: A progress report on our monetary policy framework

and with support from BRIEFING NOTE 1

UNCTAD Public Symposium June, A Paper on Macroeconomic Dimensions of Inequality. Contribution by

Thinkwell s Homeschool Economics Course Lesson Plan: 36 weeks

TRANSACTIONS NORD-SUD Sarl Strategy & Marketing Consultants

China s New Political Economy

Rising inequality in China

Labour market of the new Central and Eastern European member states of the EU in the first decade of membership 125

Summary of Democratic Commissioners Views

THE GLOBAL ECONOMIC CRISIS DEVELOPING ECONOMIES AND THE ROLE OF MULTILATERAL DEVELOPMENT BANKS

A Perspective on the Economy and Monetary Policy

HUMAN ECONOMIC SECURITY

Labour Market Reform, Rural Migration and Income Inequality in China -- A Dynamic General Equilibrium Analysis

Copyrighted Material

Economic Globalization: Trends, Risks and Risk Prevention

Fragile by Design: The Political Origins of Banking Crises*

The Human Resources and Financing for Science in Latvia,

The 2016 Survey on Business Conditions of Japanese Companies in Latin America

Executive summary. Strong records of economic growth in the Asia-Pacific region have benefited many workers.

Jens Thomsen: The global economy in the years ahead

The State, the Market, And Development. Joseph E. Stiglitz World Institute for Development Economics Research September 2015

Bluster Notwithstanding, China s Bargaining Position Will Weaken

Globalization, economic growth, employment and poverty. The experiences of Chile and Mexico

LECTURE 23: A SUMMARY OF CAPITAL IN THE 21 ST CENTURY

WESTERN BALKANS COUNTRIES IN FOCUS OF GLOBAL ECONOMIC CRISIS

The Overselling of Globalization: Truth and Consequences. Joseph Stiglitz Volcker Award Lecture Washington, D.C. March 6, 2017

The case of Poland. Michał Górzyński CASE

GavekalDragonomics. March The Long Hangover. China and the world after the commodity boom. Arthur Kroeber

Interview. Austerity Is Useless. Interviewed by Mauro Lacentini. Epoca (Milan), 27 October 1976), pp English translation by Maria Torchio.

Asia's giants take different routes By Martin Wolf Published: February :36 Last updated: February :36

Rewriting the Rules of the Market Economy to Achieve Shared Prosperity. Joseph E. Stiglitz New York June 2016

Lessons from a Decade of Transition in Eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union Pradeep K. Mitra and Marcelo Selowsky

WHAT S ON THE HORIZON?

HOW ECONOMIES GROW AND DEVELOP Macroeconomics In Context (Goodwin, et al.)

Volume Title: The Korean War and United States Economic Activity, Volume URL:

Address given by Lars Heikensten on the euro (Stockholm, 4 September 2003)

China After the East Asian Crisis

A more dynamic welfare state for a more dynamic Europe

Sonja Steßl. State Secretary Federal Ministry of Finance

MEXICO: ECONOMIC COUNTRY REPORT

Globalization and its Impact on Poverty in Pakistan. Sohail J. Malik Ph.D. Islamabad May 10, 2006

Conference Against Imperialist Globalisation and War

The Political Challenges of Economic Reforms in Latin America. Overview of the Political Status of Market-Oriented Reform

ECONOMICS 115: THE WORLD ECONOMY IN THE 20 TH CENTURY PAST PROBLEM SETS Fall (First Set)

Debt market turmoil : impact on Central Europe?

1. Define GDP. The market value of all final goods and services produced within a nation in a given time period

Global trade in the aftermath of the global crisis

Real Convergence of Central and Eastern Europe Economic and Monetary Union

Impact of Globalization on Economic Growth in India

Testimony to the United States Senate Budget Committee Hearing on Opportunity, Mobility, and Inequality in Today's Economy April 1, 2014

INSTITUTIONAL REFORM IN ALBANIA. Gjergj Konda IFC

SIEPR policy brief. Turkish Economic Successes and Challenges. By Anne O. Krueger. Stanford University September 2014.

Overcoming Labor Shortages: Prospects for Sustainable Economic Growth

Conference on What Africa Can Do Now To Accelerate Youth Employment. Organized by

The United States Trade Deficit Issue with China and its Economic Effects in 2016

Adam Smith and Government Intervention in the Economy Sima Siami-Namini Graduate Research Assistant and Ph.D. Student Texas Tech University

A2 Economics. Enlargement Countries and the Euro. tutor2u Supporting Teachers: Inspiring Students. Economics Revision Focus: 2004

A Putin policy without Putin after 2008? Putin s legacy: achievements

Labor markets in the Tenth District are

Economic Assistance to Russia: Ineffectual, Politicized, and Corrupt?

THE EVOLUTION OF WORKER S REMITTANCES IN MEXICO IN RECENT YEARS

Transcription:

Promoting Financial Stability in the Transition Economies of Central and Eastern Europe It is a great pleasure to be here after seven years, to have the chance to meet old friends, and to report both about non-negligible and undeniable positive results which have been achieved in the transition economies of Central and Eastern Europe between my two visits to Jackson Hole, and about not less undeniable problems connected with such a unique historical maneuver. The seven years time span makes it possible to base our discussion on the existence and understanding of many important similarities among the transforming countries which are, however, sometimes difficult to discover behind evident differences. I will use mostly Czech data and Czech experience, but my ambition is to at least implicitly generalize and outline broader tendencies or principles. I happened to be here in 1990, at the moment of overall optimistic forecasts and expectations and of preparations toward radical moves forward in the near future. As we see it now, the future was not identical for all the countries in question. It is not difficult to say why. Some countries spent that critical period in nonproductive political debates without the ability to formulate clear visions and transformation strategies and because of that, they made costly concessions to all, loosened fiscal and monetary controls, intensified economic imbalances inherited from the communist past and, by doing it further, destabilized the economy as a whole. It could have been expected that to liberalize prices and foreign trade in such an 183

184 unstable situation meant to bring about rapid and persistent inflation, sharp economic decline, huge shifts in income and wealth distribution as well as the deterioration of living conditions of large segments of the population. As a consequence, the vital reform measures were blocked or postponed to a much less favorable situation. Other countries, however, used the preparatory stage for generating essential preconditions for the implementation of subsequent radical reforms. When I was here in 1990, my talk 1 was mostly devoted to the discussion of these preconditions. I stressed the importance of restrictive macroeconomic policies for example, cautious monetary policies and surplus state budgets as the only way to escape from falling into what I used to call the reform trap. History proved that the implementation of such a restrictive macropolicy, together with simultaneous merciless devaluation, made the opening of domestic and foreign markets possible at relatively low costs for society. I will briefly discuss the situation in both the internal and external sphere in the last years as an argument in this respect. The rate of inflation after price liberalization moved in my country very rapidly to a more or less acceptable level, as can be seen from the following table. (Price liberalization was carried out January 1, 1991.) Months of 1991 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Rate of inflation (month-to-month in percent) 25.8 6.1 4.3 2.4 1.9 1.8-0.3 0.0 0.3 0.2 I agree with economists who argue that to reduce it further and faster would have been very costly. With the exception of the deliberate price shift in January 1993 (as a result of the introduction of the value-added tax system), the seasonally adjusted monthly inflation did not exceed the 1 percent level very often and was

Promoting Financial Stability in the Transition Economies of Central and Eastern Europe 185 always below 2 percent. (The synergistic effect of currency depreciation, of a radical shift in deregulation of rents and energy prices, and of floods, in July 1997 is, however, a different story.) The annual rate of inflation has been since 1992 rather stubborn at about a 10 percent level, with the lowest annual rate achieved in April 1997 at 6.3 percent. The explanation of the relative persistency of such an inflation rate cannot be, in my view, explained by monetary or macroeconomic factors only or dominantly, because there were important structural factors (and impulses) at play, connected with the extraordinary high frequency of changes in relative prices. It was an integral and necessary part of the restructuring of both nominal and real variables in the transforming economy. My conclusion is that the inflation slowdown to such a moderate level could have been arrived at provided cautious macroeconomic policies were pursued with sufficient consistency. It was more difficult to achieve external equilibrium. In the first stage, in the moment of substantial economic decline (1991-1993) which was caused by an unavoidable transformation-shakeoff of nonviable economic activities associated with the old economic system, not by an excessive macroeconomic restriction (as was sometimes suggested) the domestic aggregate demand did not reach the level of the aggregate supply. There was, evidently, a shortage of domestic demand. As a result, exports were bigger than imports which together with strong capital inflows preserved balance of payments equilibrium and led to the growing stock of hard currency reserves. In the second stage, in the moment of economic recovery (1994-1996), rapid growth of investment (and a very high investment ratio, significantly exceeding the domestic saving ratio), together with our rather innocent opening of the whole economy toward more protected trade partners, produced a radically different outcome. The aggregate demand exceeded the domestic aggregate supply and imports exceeded exports. At first, the balance of trade, then the current account of the balance of payments, and finally the capital

186 account turned into deficit. As is well-known, the final stage of the drama was played by massive speculation against the Czech crown in May 1997, by its unintended depreciation, and by its free floating since that time. This recent accident was undoubtedly the most important phenomenon of instability in our whole post-communist era, of financial instability in a broader sense. We have to admit that we did not succeed in finding an easy and straightforward way to prevent it. Was it possible to avoid it at all? It is too early to give a final answer but I have some reservations about it given all the political and economic domestic and international constraints and will, therefore, try here today to briefly discuss some relevant arguments in this respect as I see them. The exchange rate regime and the exchange rate level The collapse of communism happened in the moment when the economic profession believed in fixed exchange rates and in the advantage of anchoring the economy by means of one fixed point especially in a situation when all other variables undergo large changes and fluctuations. I have to confess that I was originally afraid of introducing such a rigid regime but the first impressions were positive because we succeeded in choosing an exchange rate which functioned well for a very long seventy-six months. By sufficiently devaluing the crown on the eve of price liberalization we formed something what I later called the transformation cushion. The exchange rate cushion (as well as the parallel wage cushion) appeared to be crucial for the whole subsequent transformation process. The inflation differential was, in our case, not as big as in some other transforming countries but the appreciation in real terms reached in seventy-six months was almost 80 percent, which was too much. Although we have been constantly checking the remaining thickness of our exchange rate cushion, as we see it now, we probably in the middle of 1996 missed the most suitable moment for the abolition of the fixed exchange rate regime. The question is, however, whether the subsequent movements of the rate

Promoting Financial Stability in the Transition Economies of Central and Eastern Europe 187 of exchange would have been less dramatic than they were in reality in recent months. The vulnerability of an emerging market economy is, in this respect, very high and, probably, unavoidable. The tentative lesson No. 1: A fixed exchange rate regime should not last too long. Investment-savings imbalance The economic recovery has been, since 1993, relatively rapid (in European terms). It was pulled by strong investment demand (with only modestly growing private consumption and exports and with stagnating or declining government expenditures). The rapid growth of investments seems to be unavoidable. The problem is in the structure of investments. The overwhelming feeling of obsolescence of infrastructure (of all kinds) after four decades of communism, together with overambitious green attempts to rapidly undo the well-documented environmental damage caused by the absence of private property and a market economy, led to an extremely high investment ratio (33 percent in 1996). Only a smaller part of investments was productive in the narrow sense, and contributed to industrial restructuring and modernization. To reconcile strong investment demand with domestic savings was almost impossible because we did not succeed in creating the atmosphere of belt-tightening as the only way to overcome the heavy burden of the communist heritage. The problem is clear, the solution not. The tentative lesson No. 2: It is necessary to restrain the catching-up ambitions and the impatience of society as much as possible. Wage-productivity nexus and the degree of competitiveness Price liberalization, accompanied with rather restrictive macroeconomic policy, generated another significant transformation phenomenon the wage cushion. Wages went up much slower than prices and, as a result, real wages could, for some time, grow faster than GDP or productivity without undermining competitiveness of

188 the whole economy. It gave our enterprise sector a breathing time which only a part of it was effectively used for radical restructuring. We were, however, not able to prolong the process of emptying the cushion. The government could not control the private sector and was not able (or strong enough) to block the growth of salaries and wages in the public sector. The relatively rapid growth of wages in the private sector was made possible by soft (or insufficiently hard) granting of credits by the banking sector and by the slow process of bankruptcies on one hand and by strong demand for labor and very low unemployment on the other. None of these factors could be directly controlled by the government. The tentative lesson No. 3: The rate of growth of wages is not a free policy variable (as is sometimes implicitly suggested by external observers and advisers). Quality of markets, economic strength, and high degree of foreign trade liberalization With the benefit of hindsight it can be argued that the scope and rapidity with which former communist countries opened their economies and adopted currency convertibility was much larger and faster than in similar historical moments in the past. As we all know, it took a much longer time to do it in Western Europe and Japan after World War II. And, in addition, it was done in a situation of enormous structural shifts in the financial system itself as well as in a moment of sophisticated protectionism in developed countries (in Europe especially). We do not know whether it was a blessing or a curse. The entry of strong firms from developed countries into our unprotected markets was much easier than the entry of our technologically, financially, and organizationally much weaker firms into their occupied and protected markets. When I dare to say that, I do not mean it as an advocacy of the policy of sheltering the markets of young, immature industries. I use it, however, as a part of my explanation of our trade deficit.

Promoting Financial Stability in the Transition Economies of Central and Eastern Europe 189 The tentative lesson No. 4: A small, open, industrial ex-communist economy pays, in the short run, more for trade and currency liberalization than a big, less open, and less industrial economy. Fiscal and monetary policy mix Until very recently, we succeeded in having either surplus or balanced budgets and a relatively cautious monetary policy (with unknown shifts in the velocity of money). 2 It seems natural to argue that the growing external imbalance required some degree of macroeconomic tightening. But the politicians had the feeling that to have budgets without deficits for seven consecutive years is the maximum they could offer. To criticize them (in this respect) seems to me inappropriate. Some degree of money supply deceleration was necessary as well. It did happen in our case but to slow down the annual rate of money supply growth from 18-20 percent (in the first half of 1996) to 10-12 percent (in the second half of 1996) and to 6-7 percent (in the first half of 1997) by the not preannounced step of the central bank was something which, at least, asks for a discussion of the real meaning of the central bank independence. It had, as expected, faster impact upon aggregate supply than demand and contributed to the apparent economic slowdown (if not decline), to unexpected budgetary problems (on the income side), to heavy political conflicts and uncertainty and, finally, to the increased financial instability as well as to the recent currency weakness. The tentative lesson No. 5: Efforts to make sharp changes in monetary policy prove to be very dangerous. Fragility of financial institutions Financial institutions (banks and other financial intermediaries) in the post-communist countries have many childhood problems and cannot be relied upon to contribute sufficiently to the stability of the whole economy. Whether we wanted it or not, the banks and

190 other financial institutions were an integral part of the transformation process and could not get the status of a clean outsider as was sometimes suggested. They inherited difficult loan portfolios; with their transformation and privatization involvements, they added not much less controversial assets; they have complicated ownership structures, and so on. The masterminding of their evolution is, however, impossible. There is no doubt that the fragility of our financial markets was an additional complicating factor. Their lack of transparency and stability contributed to the slowdown of capital inflows and thus aggravated the balance of payments problem. The only relevant question is what could have been done ex ante. Capital markets are different from ordinary markets and they probably need more government intervention or regulation than ordinary markets. The problem is how to intervene, how to regulate them without constraining them unnecessarily and without expecting too much from the regulator who is a human being as the rest of us (with his welldefined utility function which he tries to maximize) and who operates in a world of intensive rent-seeking and in a world of the well-known fallacies of regulation. I am not very optimistic about regulation in general and about regulation of capital markets in particular. 3 Our capital market has grown much faster than anyone expected, especially when we gave it a strong accelerating impulse by our voucher privatization. In the early nineties I fully shared Joseph Stiglitz s view 4 that to a large extent, equity markets are an interesting and amusing sideshow, but they are not at the heart of the action (p. 32) because we started our economic transformation with heavy reliance on the banking system. While trying to expand it rapidly we probably underestimated the need to impose sufficiently high capital requirements and, at the same time, we did not succeed in strictly dividing the financial and production sectors of the economy. We more or less accepted the German (or continental) type of banking with its strong interrelationships between banks and firms in the production sector. We see many problems with it now but I am not sure we could have started differently.

Promoting Financial Stability in the Transition Economies of Central and Eastern Europe 191 With the spontaneous evolution of our financial markets, with literally millions of shareholders and hundreds of investment companies and funds, mostly as a byproduct of voucher privatization, we failed in generating the sufficient degree of information about the financial position of individual firms. It is connected with the lack of intensity of transactions in our today s markets which is unavoidable (the markets are shallow and, therefore, not efficient), and it may be, at the same time, the result of delayed legislative measures on the side of the government. The question of lags in public policy is, however, not simple. Joseph Stiglitz mentioned in his study that much of the return in capital markets consists of rent-seeking (p.15) and I have to admit that in the past some of us did not immediately believe all the critics of our capital markets because they usually played their own card and did not take into consideration the existing stage of the evolution of the whole economic system. Their criticism was very often indistinguishable from the complaints of those who just incurred a loss by making a wrong investment. The main problem is not the legislation itself. The problem is law enforcement, efficient control, and rational regulation. There is a clear need to speed up the judicial procedures and to establish specialized financial courts dealing with bankruptcies and matters related to capital markets. The tentative lesson No. 6: The capital markets begin to function faster than you expect and before you try to regulate them. To conclude, I have to repeat that my answers to the existing problems are tentative but I hope that they clearly suggest that my doubts about the possibility of a smooth and stable transition path in politically and socially difficult, but highly democratic, pluralistic and open economies and societies of Central and Eastern Europe continue to exist because we are not in a brave new world of perfect markets and of perfect governments. It remains our task, however, to minimize the inevitable instability.

192 Endnotes 1, Policy Dilemmas of Eastern European Reforms: Notes of an Insider, address published in Central Banking Issues in Emerging Market-Oriented Economies, proceedings from a symposium sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, Jackson Hole, Wyo., August 23-25, 1990, pp. 51-6. 2. Creating a Stable Monetary Order, in The Rebirth of Liberty in the Heart of Europe, (Washington, D.C.: The CATO Institute, 1997). 3 Similar arguments were raised by Thomas M. Hoenig, president of the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, in his recent speech, published in the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Economic Review, March 1997. 4 Joseph Stiglitz, Financial Systems for Eastern Europe s Emerging Democracies. San Francisco: The International Center for Economic Growth, Occasional Paper, No. 38, 1993.