Trade Note September 10, 2003

Similar documents
The North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) has raised Mexico s

U.S.-Latin America Trade: Recent Trends

U.S.-Latin America Trade: Recent Trends

Can free-trade policies help to reduce gender inequalities in employment and wages?

3) The European Union is an example of integration. A) regional B) relative C) global D) bilateral

Non-Tariff Measures to Trade Economic and Policy Issues for Developing countries.

TRADE STRUCTURE, TRADE POLICY AND ECONOMIC POLICY OPTIONS IN CENTRAL AMERICA

COMMENTS ON L. ALAN WINTERS, TRADE LIBERALISATION, ECONOMIC GROWTH AND POVERTY

A. Growing dissatisfaction with hyperglobalization

Economic integration: an agreement between

China s Rise and Leaving the Middle- Income Trap in Latin America A New Structural Economics Approach

Globalisation and Open Markets

Trade liberalization and gender inequality

Abdurohman Ali Hussien,,et.al.,Int. J. Eco. Res., 2012, v3i3, 44-51

Poverty Reduction and Economic Management The World Bank

Lessons from NAFTA for Latin American and Caribbean (LAC) Countries: A Summary of Research Findings

How does international trade affect household welfare?

Test Bank for Economic Development. 12th Edition by Todaro and Smith

Full file at

Recent RSIE Discussion Papers are available on the World Wide Web at:

LSE Global South Unit Policy Brief Series

Size of Regional Trade Agreements and Regional Trade Bias

UNION COLLEGE DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, FALL 2004 ECO 146 SEMINAR IN GLOBAL ECONOMIC ISSUES GLOBALIZATION AND LABOR MARKETS

Presentation prepared for the event:

Latin America in the New Global Order. Vittorio Corbo Governor Central Bank of Chile

Trading Competitively: A Study of Trade Capacity Building in Sub-Saharan Africa

Chapter 13: NAFTA and Mexican Industrial Development

Can Africa Catch Up?

A GLOBALIZED MARKET OPPORTUNITIES AND RISKS FOR THE POOR

Strengthening Integration of the Economies in Transition into the World Economy through Economic Diversification

Mexico: How to Tap Progress. Remarks by. Manuel Sánchez. Member of the Governing Board of the Bank of Mexico. at the. Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas

Benefits and costs of free trade for less developed countries

GLOBAL EUROPE. competing in the world. For more information: EXTERNAL TRADE. European Commission

Economics of the Trans- Pacific Partnership (TPP)

Wage Inequality in Latin America: Understanding the Past to Prepare for the Future Julian Messina and Joana Silva

U.S.-Latin America Trade: Recent Trends and Policy Issues

International Monetary Fund Washington, D.C.

ARTNeT Trade Economists Conference Trade in the Asian century - delivering on the promise of economic prosperity rd September 2014

Liberalization of Trade in Services: Issues Raised by LAC s Experience

INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS, FINANCE AND TRADE Vol. II - Globalization and the Evolution of Trade - Pasquale M. Sgro

WORLD ECONOMIC EXPANSION in the first half of the 1960's has

Ghana Lower-middle income Sub-Saharan Africa (developing only) Source: World Development Indicators (WDI) database.

title, Routledge, September 2008: 234x156:

TRADE IN THE GLOBAL ECONOMY

Beyond Aid and Concessional Borrowing: New Ways of Financing Development in Africa and Its Implications

The EU-ASEAN FTA: Gender Issues and Advocacy. Naty Bernardino International Gender & Trade Network - Asia

Globalization and Poverty Forthcoming, University of

Explanations of Slow Growth in Productivity and Real Wages

The Political Challenges of Economic Reforms in Latin America. Overview of the Political Status of Market-Oriented Reform

Macroeconomic and distributional effects of globalisation

Export Growth and Industrial Policy: Lessons from the East Asian Miracle Experience

So far we have analyzed the instruments of trade policy and its objectives

Summary of key points

International Trade and Inequality

The Effects of Trade Policy: A Global Perspective

Volume Title: NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2000, Volume 15. Volume URL:

Symposium on Preferential Trade Agreements and Inclusive Trade: Latin American cases

The Challenge of Inclusive Growth: Making Growth Work for the Poor

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES OPENNESS AND GROWTH: WHAT S THE EMPIRICAL RELATIONSHIP? Robert E. Baldwin

Research Report. How Does Trade Liberalization Affect Racial and Gender Identity in Employment? Evidence from PostApartheid South Africa

The Development of FTA Rules of Origin Functions

Study Questions (with Answers) Lecture 18 Preferential Trading Arrangements

Globalization, economic growth, employment and poverty. The experiences of Chile and Mexico

POLI 12D: International Relations Sections 1, 6

Chapter Three Global Trade and Integration. Copyright 2012, SAGE Publications, Inc.

THE RECENT TREND OF ROMANIA S INTERNATIONAL TRADE IN GOODS

India in the World Trading System. Romain Wacziarg 1. Stanford University and NBER. Second Draft - July 2002

Latin America was already a region of sharp

Understanding the dynamics of labor income inequality in Latin America (WB PRWP 7795)

Growth in Open Economies, Schumpeterian Models

Jobs, labour markets & shared growth Trends and issues

Latin America and the Caribbean s s Response to the Growth of China and India: Overview of Research Findings and Policy Implications

PRIVATE CAPITAL FLOWS RETURN TO A FEW DEVELOPING COUNTRIES AS AID FLOWS TO POOREST RISE ONLY SLIGHTLY

Executive summary. Strong records of economic growth in the Asia-Pacific region have benefited many workers.

Latin American growth fuels need for talent, but from where?

Emerging Market Consumers: A comparative study of Latin America and Asia-Pacific

THE GLOBAL ECONOMIC CRISIS DEVELOPING ECONOMIES AND THE ROLE OF MULTILATERAL DEVELOPMENT BANKS

"Capacity-Building in the Face of the Emerging Challenges of Doha and the FTAA" 27 February 2002

The China Syndrome. Local Labor Market Effects of Import Competition in the United States. David H. Autor, David Dorn, and Gordon H.

vi. rising InequalIty with high growth and falling Poverty

INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND LABOUR MARKET PERFORMANCE: MAJOR FINDINGS AND OPEN QUESTIONS

GCC Countries. Chapter 3. Development Economics GCC Dr. Mohammed Alwosabi. Dr. Mohammed Alwosabi. Characteristics of GCC States

A COMPARISON OF ARIZONA TO NATIONS OF COMPARABLE SIZE

The structure of the South African economy and its implications for social cohesion

Support Materials. GCE Economics H061/H461: Exemplar Materials. AS/A Level Economics

COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT, THE COUNCIL, THE EUROPEAN ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL COMMITTEE AND THE COMMITTEE OF THE REGIONS

COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES. The European Union and Latin America: Global Players in Partnership {SEC(2009) 1227}

Trade theory and regional integration

INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION IN THE AMERICAS

ECON MACROECONOMIC PRINCIPLES Instructor: Dr. Juergen Jung Towson University. J.Jung Chapter 18 - Trade Towson University 1 / 42

Chapter 1. NAFTA and Convergence in North America: High Expectations, Big Events, Little Time. First Draft: October 2, 2002

Volume 35, Issue 1. An examination of the effect of immigration on income inequality: A Gini index approach

26 TH ANNUAL MEETING ASIA-PACIFIC PARLIAMENTARY FORUM

Full clear download (no formatting errors) at:

Global Employment Trends for Women

Trapped. The low- or middle-income trap phenomenon. Few Developing Countries Can Climb the Economic Ladder or Stay There. By Maria A.

Pattern of Intraregional Trade:Unbundling a South Asian Conundrum

Chapter 11. Trade Policy in Developing Countries

The globalization of inequality

INTERNAL INCONSISTENCIES: LINKING THE WASHINGTON CONSENSUS AND POVERTY IN LATIN AMERICA. Rory Creedon LSE MPA (ID) GV444

Transcription:

Trade Note September 10, 2003 The World Bank Group www.worldbank.org International Trade Department By David de Ferranti, Daniel Lederman, Guillermo Perry, and Rodrigo Suescứn These notes summarize recent research on global trade issues. They reflect solely the views of the author, and do not necessarily reflect the views of the World Bank Group or its Executive Directors, or the countries they represent. Trade Note 9 Introduction Trade for Development in Latin America and the Caribbean Beginning in the 1980s, but especially during the 1990s, Latin American and Caribbean (LAC) countries launched trade policy reforms that remain controversial partly due to the mixed overall economic performance of the region. Economic growth has been sluggish, particularly after 1998, and unemployment, the incidence of informal employment, and income inequality have risen after the reforms. Reform critics associate these outcomes with international trade; we examine some of their claims in this article. After describing trade policies in the region, we review the relationship between openness and a variety of economic outcomes. We conclude by drawing attention to forgotten complements required to maximize the benefits of trade. Trade Liberalization in LAC The past two decades saw major changes in trade policies in the region. Figure 1 shows the evolution of the average level of import tariffs. Between 1980 and 1999 the region reduced tariffs from an average of 30% to 10%, very close to OECD standards. The set of protectionist policies included a variety of nontariff trade barriers. Licensing requirements, prohibitions, quotas, tariff quotas and administered pricing used to be very popular in the region. Table 1 shows the coverage of nontariff barriers (NTBs) in 1989-94 and 1995-98.With the exception of South Asia, the coverage of NTBs fell worldwide, but LAC already had a lower incidence of NTBs than other regions by the early 1990s. Table 1 Frequency of core NTBs (percentage) 1989-94 1995-98 East Asia and Pacific Latin America MiddleEast/North Africa South Asia Sub-Saharan Africa 30.1 18.3 43.8 57.0 26.00 16.3 8.0 16.6 58.3 10.4 The 1990s also witnessed the revival of regional and bilateral trade agreements. This global phenomenon was a by-product of unilateral liberalization of trade and investment. Initiatives to create common markets gave rise to the overhaul of existing agreements (Central American Common Market CACM, Andean Community AC, and Caribbean Community - CARICOM) and the creation of a new one (MERCOSUR). Also, free trade agreements (FTAs) flourished in the region. There are now more than twenty FTAs among LAC countries and with industrialized countries (NAFTA), and LAC remains committed to the proposed Free Trade Area of the Americas (IDB 2002). Despite regional and unilateral trade liberalization, the extent of liberalization was not the same across countries or sectors. The region still lags behind other regions in the liberalization of trade in financial and other services and agriculture. This heterogeneity of experiences is reflected in the wide range of trade-to-gdp ratios observed in the region (Figures 2a-b). The relatively low average trade share of LAC is partly explained by geography, transport costs, and other factors unrelated to trade policy. However, as the use of tariff and non-tariff restrictions fell over time,

many countries turned to antidumping laws to restrict trade. Antidumping laws allow import duties when material injury to domestic firms and pricing at less than-fair-value have been proven in antidumping investigations. The abuse of antidumping laws has turned this instrument into a source of international disputes. Figure 3 shows antidumping investigations per dollar of imports around the world in the late 1990s, when LAC was a leader in the use of this protectionist instrument. In countries, such as Argentina, these duties were imposed in times of economic downturn (Figure 4). This trend is thus the Achilles heel of LAC s trade reforms. Trade and Growth Trade liberalization in LAC was accompanied by macroeconomic and other structural reforms. The success of the reform package has been questioned by critics of globalization because the region s post-reform growth did not replicate the East Asian or past LAC growth miracles as promised by some reformers. Disentangling the effect of trade liberalization from other policies is challenging, especially because the region was hit by volatile capital flows, often exacerbated by weak macrofinancial policies. Loayza, Fajnzylber, and Calderón (2002), however, found that after controlling for cyclical and global factors, variables that measure outcomes of the reform package had a positive effect on growth. The reforms thus explain the modest improvement in growth in the 1990s relative to the 1980s, although there are some exceptions. There are many plausible channels through which trade can spur development. Some highlight static 2

efficiency gains arising from the reallocation of labor and capital from protected and inefficient to export-oriented industries. Other avenues provide dynamic gains through technological spillovers and learning when knowledge is embodied in traded goods, particularly capital goods. In LAC, trade reforms were associated with an increase in the value of imports of capital goods per worker as shown in Figure 5. maintains that growth prospects in a natural resource economy are limited by the secular deterioration of its terms of trade. Others argue that natural resource specialization increases vulnerability due to export concentration on a limited basket of commodities, or that rent-seeking activities associated with resource extraction lead to weak institutions. Most cross-country studies have found a positive relationship between trade openness and income growth. 1 This view was challenged by Rodríguez and Rodrik (2000) on the grounds that empirical measures of openness capture the effect of omitted variables. However,Wacziarg (2001) improved upon existing work by identifying a positive direct effect of liberal trade policies on economic growth. Furthermore, the econometric study by Lederman and Maloney (2003) suggests that the concentration of export revenue hampers growth, whereas trade liberalization policies have a positive effect on growth. As shown in Figure 6, LAC exports diversified in the 1990s, probably due to the reduction of the anti-export bias of import barriers. This bodes well for long-term growth. Trade and Natural Resources A criticism of trade liberalization is that the ensuing pattern of development is restricted by dependence in natural resources. There are various versions of the theory. One strand says that resource-based development is associated with lower human and physical capital accumulation, productivity growth, and spillovers. Another Sachs and Warner (1999, 2001a,b) provide econometric results in favor of the resource curse theory by including natural resource exports as a share of GDP in an otherwise standard crosscountry growth regression. Lederman and Maloney (2003) found that this result is not robust to alternative measures of resource abundance or estimation technique and that, if anything, the effect of natural resources on growth is positive. De Ferranti, Perry, Lederman and Maloney (2002) find that resource-based activities historically have been a source of economic dynamism, as demonstrated by the experience of countries such as Australia or Finland, where resource activities turned into knowledge activities exhibiting high productivity growth. Martin and Mitra (2001) show that productivity growth in agriculture outperformed that of manufacturing in both developed and developing countries. In LAC, Chile is the most salient example of a successful development experience based on natural resources, both in mining and agriculture. Even if policymakers are concerned about specialization in agriculture or mining, it is misleading to argue that protectionism is the road to economic diversification. Modern trade theories highlight the importance of geography (distance to 3

large markets), technical knowledge, human capital, public infrastructure, the quality of institutions in determining, combined with labor, land, capital and natural resources, production decisions, specialization patterns, and the direction of trade flows. De Ferranti, Perry, Lederman, and Maloney (2002) thus concluded that economies can diversify their trade structures through policies that favor the accumulation of new endowments. Figure 7 shows Mexico s experience. This country was able to diversify its export base and change its trade structure, which was originally concentrated on natural resources (petroleum). Now it is a net exporter of machinery. Another case of structural change in an agricultural economy is Costa Rica, which became an exporter of computer chips and medical equipment thanks to foreign investment attracted by its well trained labor force, institutional stability, and geographic proximity to the United States. In sum, natural resources are neither a curse nor destiny. worldwide (Figure 8) or regional (Table 2) levels. Unemployment rates in many liberalizing economies are not systematically higher after reforms. For instance, Chile, the LAC country with most liberal trade policy, experienced high unemployment rates in the years immediately following its reforms. More recently (prior to the downturn of 1999) Chile s unemployment returned to low levels. Similarly, in Mexico after eight years of living under NAFTA rules the unemployment rate is currently similar to its historical average. Trade, Wages, and Inequality During the 1990s several LAC countries experienced high unemployment, wage losses, and increased informality. A source of controversy is the role played by trade. Part of the efficiency gains from trade occurred via resource reallocations. Since labor does not automatically migrate from declining to emerging sectors, this adjustment process could have created temporary unemployment. In the long-run, supply and demand for labor, for example, will adjust to ensure a natural rate of unemployment, which depends more on labor market regulations than on trade policy. There is no evidence of any systematic relation between openness and unemployment at either The increase in wage inequality in Mexico and Chile, as in most countries in LAC, was the consequence of skill-biased technological change brought by international trade and investment (De Ferranti, Perry, Gill, Guasch, Maloney, Sánchez- Páramo, and Schady, 2003).Most countries in the region experienced a significant increase in relative demand and skill premiums for more educated workers. Moreover, Figure 9 shows that exposure to global competition is associated with higher 4

wages for a given level of education. 2 International competition is thus associated with the adoption of new technologies that utilize skilled labor and an increasing gap with respect to wages of low-skilled workers. But this skill premium offers an opportunity for long-run development as families and the public sector can thus focus on improving the quality and coverage of education demanded by technological change. If LAC countries increase the supply of skills, they can accommodate high real wages and an equitable wage distribution. Figure 10 shows a decline in wage inequality in Chile and Mexico as the demand for skills was met by rising supply of skills. duties, non-tariff barriers, and even domestic support policies are often used to limit import competition. Multilateral negotiations under the WTO and regional agreements can guarantee market access, and the latter also offer preferential access. Their efficacy depends on their enforcement mechanisms, which may be more effective in regional or bilateral agreements than under the WTO. Figure 10. Wage Spreads in Chile and Mexico before and After Trade Reforms (ratios of wages of top decile over bottom decile) 6 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 6 5 5 Chilean spr ead 4 3 2 4 3 2 Mexican spre ad 1 1 0 1970 1972 1974 1976 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 0 Chile (1970-1996) Mexico (1987-1999) Figure 11. Share of Informal Salaried Workers in Greater Buenos Aires, 1980-1990 40% The incidence of informality is a concern for LAC. Stallings and Peres (2000) found that six of 10 jobs in seven LAC countries were created in the informal sector during the 1990s. However, it is not clear how liberalization can erode job quality. In the case of Argentina, informality began to rise before the first trade reforms of 1988 (Figure 11). De Ferranti, Perry, Lederman and Maloney (2002) argue that informal employment is not explained by trade, but rather by booming nontradable activities driven by overvalued exchange rates resulting from capital inflows after the macro stabilizations of the early nineties. Unilateral and Regional Liberalization Unilateral liberalization came in tandem with the proliferation of regional trade agreements. Why is unilateral trade liberalization not enough to reap the benefits of freer trade as suggested by theory? The simple answer is that unilateral liberalization does not guarantee market access. Tariffs, antidumping 35% 30% 25% 20% 15% 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 Perhaps more importantly, regional agreements cover issues beyond trade and can have important developmental impacts. For example, comprehensive trade agreements with developed countries such as the United States or the European Union can enhance the credibility of the economic reforms, because reversals can be costly in terms of potential retaliations. Moreover these agreements cover issues related to investor protection and intellectual property rights, which for most middleincome countries of LCR can have significant positive effects by reducing country risk and stimulating national research and development (R&D) efforts that accelerate the pace of 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 5

technological progress. Finally, FTAs can be have a powerful effects on the domestic politics of trade by mobilizing export interests in favor of the trade reforms. These benefits have to be weighed against potential trade diversion effects from regional agreements, which can be minimized through simultaneous unilateral and multilateral A liberalization. Forgotten Complements to Trade Neoclassical trade theory predicts that income levels across liberalized economies will converge over time. From a theoretical perspective there are many reasons to be cautious about this prediction. Productivity levels may not converge in the presence of labor skill gaps between poor countries and innovator countries (Acemoglu and Zilibotti 2001). Similar arguments can be made for other factors that impair the capacity of a country to adopt new technologies and innovate, such as differences in infrastructure, domestic institutions, and R&D expenditures and policies. Clear examples of incomplete convergence can be found within countries, where there are persistent pockets of poverty, in spite of extensive economic integration across regions. Lederman and Maloney (2003) conclude that trade liberalization and NAFTA are not enough to help Mexico catch-up in innovation and productivity levels to the levels observed in its North American partners. Mexico suffers from low levels of R&D expenditures, low levels of patenting activity, and a weak and inefficient national innovation system. De Ferranti, Perry, Gill, Guasch, Maloney, Sánchez-Páramo, and Schady (2003) show that LAC in general suffers from significant deficits in both skills and innovation. All these factors explain why productivity growth is sluggish in the region and why productivity differences are so persistent even when contrasted with some East Asian economies. Given the complementarity between skills and technology reflected in the global skillbiased technological change, trade reforms alone are not enough: Without a well trained labor force and greater R&D effort, these reforms will soon face skill bottlenecks and persistent inequality in earnings and the process of acquisition and production of knowledge will be severely limited. It might be naïve to expect that trade and stability lone will enable LAC to catch up to the world s technological leaders. References cemoglu, D. and F. Zilibotti (2001): Productivity Differences, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116(2), p. 563-606. Alesina, A., E. Spolaore and R.Wacziarg (2000): Economic, Integration and Political Disintegration, American Economic Review, 90, p. 1276-96. Ben-David, D. (1993): Equalizing Exchange: Trade Liberalization and Income Convergence, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108, p. 653-679. De Ferranti, D., G. Perry, D. Lederman and W.Maloney (2002): From Natural Resources to the Knowledge Economy. Trade and Job Quality, The World Bank (Washington D.C.: The World Bank). De Ferranti, D., G. Perry, I. Gill, L. Guasch,W.F.Maloney, C. Sánchez-Páramo and N. Schady (2003): Closing the Gap in Education and Technology, The World Bank (Washington D.C.: The World Bank). Dol lar, D. (1992): Outward Oriented Developing Economies Really Do Growth More Rapidly: Evidence from 95 LDCs 1976-1985, Economic Development and Cultural Change, 40, p. 523-544. Dollar, D. and A. Kraay (2000): Trade, Growth and Poverty, The World Bank Development Research Group, Washington (mimeo). Edwards, S. (1992): Trade Orientation, Distortions and Growth in Developing Countries, Journal of Development Economics, 39, p. 31-57. Edwards, S. (1998): Openness, Productivity and Growth: What Do We Really Know? Economic Journal, 108, p. 383-398. Frankel, J. and D. Romer (1999): Does Trade Cause Growth? American Economic Review, 89, p. 379-399. Lederman D. and W.Maloney (2003a): Trade Structure and Growth, Office of the Chief Economist, LCR, The World Bank (mimeo). 6

Lederman, D. and W.Maloney (2003b): Innovation in Mexico: NAFTA is not Enough, World Bank, mimeo. Loayza, N., P. Fajnzylber and C. Calderón (2002): Economic Growth in Latin America and the Caribbean. Stylized Facts, Explanations, and Forecasts, Office of the Chief Economist, LCR, The World Bank (mimeo). Martin,W. and D.Mitra (2001): Productivity Growth and Convergence in Agriculture and Manufacturing, Economic Development and Cultural Change, 49(2), p. 403-22. Sachs, J. and A.Warner (1995): Economic Reforms and the Process of Global Integration, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1, p. 1-118. Sachs J. and A.Warner (1999): The Big Push, Natural Resource Booms and Growth, Journal of Development Economics, 59, p. 43-76. Sachs J. and A.Warner (2001a): Fundamental Sources of Long-Run Growth, American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, 87, p. 184-88. Sachs J. and A.Warner (2001b): Natural Resources and Economic Development. The Curse of Natural Resources, European Economic Review, 45, p. 827-38. Stallings, B. and W. Peres (2000): Growth, Employment and Inequality. The Impact of Economic Reforms in Latin America and the Caribbean. Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean, (Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution Press). Rodrik,D. and F. Rodríguez (2000): Trade Policy and Economic Growth: A Skeptic s Guide to the Cross- National Evidence. In B. Bernanke and K. Rogoff, eds., NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2000, (Cambridge,Mass.: MIT Press). Wacziarg, R. (2001): Measuring the Dynamic Gains from Trade, The World Bank Economic Review, 15,p. 393-429. World Bank (2001): Globalization, Growth, and Poverty: Building an Inclusive World Economy, Washington (mimeo). This note was prepared by David de Ferranti, Vice President for Latin America and the Caribbean, Guillermo Perry is the Bank s Chief Economist for Latin America and the Caribbean. Daniel Lederman and Rodrigo Suescứn are both senior economists at the Bank. This Trade Note can be download at http://www.worldbank.org/trade/. 1 See Dollar (1992), Ben-David (1993), Sachs and Warner (1995), Edwards (1992, 1998), Frankel and Romer (1999), Dollar and Kraay (2000), Alesina, Spolaore and Wacziarg (2000), and World Bank (2001) among others. 2 In this figure NT stands for non-traded industries. qx1, qx2 and qx3 represent terciles of workers in industries with highest, second highest and lowest shares of exports in total production, respectively. qm1, qm2 and qm3 represent a similar ordering for imports shares. 7